MINORITY REPORT
CHAPTER 2
THE ECONOMIC CASE FOR PART PRIVATISATION OF TELSTRA
2.1 A logical next step as competition increases
We believe that the part privatisation of Telstra is a logical continuation
of a series of reforms over the last 20 years. The first occurred in
1975 when the Australian Telecommunications Commission was created out
of the old Post-Master General's Department to give a more commercial
focus to the organisation. A second step was taken in 1989, with the
creation of AUSTEL and the introduction of competition in value-added
services. Then in 1991, a third set of reforms saw Telecom made into
a company under Australia's Corporations Law, the introduction of a
transitional competitive duopoly involving Telecom and Optus (and, in
mobile telephony, three way competition between Telecom, Optus and Vodafone),
and the prospect of full and open competition from 1 July 1997.
At each stage of these reforms there have been critics, and strident
claims have been made about adverse effects on universal service delivery,
service quality and efficiency. However, the outcome has been a strengthening
of universal services, improved service delivery and a more efficient
and profitable Telstra. Contrary to the expectations of the critics,
increased pressures on Telstra to produce services in competitive markets
and to provide better financial returns to the Government in the last
decade has helped forge Telstra into a stronger and more competitive
company.
We note with interest that the last two of these important reforms
occurred under a Labor Government. We think that they were right to
take the steps they took then. It is a great pity that Labor now appears
to have lost the energy and courage to introduce needed reforms into
the telecommunications market - reforms which are supported by a logic
which is compelling, and a logic which must be just as clear to Labor
in Opposition as it was to Labor in Government.
2.1.1 Telstra operates in an increasingly competitive environment
The evidence shows that there is a world wide trend to competition
in telecommunications, and that Governments everywhere are seeking to
ensure their carriers are fit for the challenge. Telstra in its submission
to the Inquiry said:
Significant structural changes are occurring within the global
communications industry as technologies converge and new global players
enter the communications market. The environment in which Telstra operates
is becoming increasingly competitive and more dynamic as historical
barriers to competition are being eroded by technology and by Government's
drive towards greater competitiveness and efficiency. [1]
The evidence from Telstra and other witnesses also shows that Telstra's
ability to continue to survive and prosper in this market environment
as a wholly government owned company is questionable. For example, the
Business Council of Australia said:
If Telstra is to continue to operate and prosper in such a rapidly
changing environment, it will have to respond quickly to changes in
the market place and to technology. Privatisation, even when this is
limited to a one third minority stake as envisaged by the Commonwealth
Government, can play a significant role in developing a more responsive
and competitive enterprise. [2]
A similar view was expressed by the WA State Government:
So, for Telstra to remain healthy in more heated competition,
now is the time to undertake a partial privatisation. [3]
Australians should not be misled into thinking that Telstra's size
and strength in the Australian market could guarantee it success in
a converging and increasingly competitive world market. Telstra's own
submission stated:
By comparison with the 50 largest world telecommunications companies,
Telstra is currently a middle sized company (ranks 22 on 1994/95 revenue).
However, if Telstra is unable to improve its efficiency and compete
effectively in this changing market, then the company's positioning
and Australian industry's leverage in regional markets will diminish.
[4]
In the Australian communications market, there are several ways in
which competition is becoming manifest. National telecommunications
carriers (often referred to in the industry as telcos),
including completely or partially privatised national telecommunications
companies, have formed powerful international alliances for providing
global services to large multinationals operating in Australia, as well
as Australian-based firms. This is making national borders ever less
relevant to regulation. Non-traditional telcos, including global information
technology and media companies, are also moving into the telephony market.
Some of these non traditional telcos, such as Internet providers, are
offering core telephony services. The growth of service providers and
resellers operating in the market since 1991 provides an important basis
for the emergence of yet another tier of carriers once the current duopoly
ends.
We believe that the portents for Telstra in this increasingly competitive
market if it remains 100% publicly owned are not encouraging. With the
telecommunications market being opened to full competition as of July
1, 1997, Telstra's environment will become ever more complex and demanding.
Already, Telstra has lost substantial market share, notably in the highly
profitable long distance service, and the development of competition
in the market for local access and calling will strike at the core of
Telstra's revenue streams.
To survive and prosper in this environment, Telstra will need a high
degree of commercial flexibility - but it is by no means apparent how
this can be reconciled with the kind of control by the Government which
has characterised full public ownership. At the same time, it will need
from its investors, and should legitimately be able to secure, advice
and guidance about complex, competitive decisions - yet these involve
issues increasingly far removed from the expertise of the Government
and its advisers. Finally, it will need more flexible access to capital,
but this is hardly a realistic option at a time of severe fiscal constraint,
affecting governments of all political persuasions.
2.1.2 The world wide regulatory trend in telecommunications: competition,
appropriate regulation, & privatisation.
Telecommunications world-wide is undergoing dramatic change. The evidence
we received was abundantly clear on this point. Markets long structured
as monopolies are being opened to full competition; government-owned
carriers are being privatised; barriers to international trade and investment
are being reviewed and reduced.
Combined, these changes create enormous benefits for consumers, through
sharp falls in service prices and in improvements in the range and quality
of service.
At the same time, we believe that these changes place great pressures
on existing suppliers - and especially on the former monopolists such
as Telstra now being exposed to the gales of competition. The inefficiencies
which could be tolerated in a monopoly environment are no longer sustainable;
mistaken investment decisions can no longer simply be passed on to consumers;
and the bureaucratic culture inherited from the public service is entirely
inappropriate to meeting the demands of a fast-changing market-place.
Like its counterparts overseas, Telstra must now face the challenge
of adapting to this new environment. If it fails to do so, Australian
consumers will inevitably suffer, as prices remain higher and service
quality lower than they should be. We will also bear a loss as tax-payers,
as the value of the national investment in Telstra is eroded. And Telstra's
employees will lose out, as failure to win in the competitive stakes
forces ever deeper cuts in employment and in the quality of working
life.
The inquiry has heard that there is a global trend to liberalise telecommunications
markets. Liberalisation generally involves three facets: competition,
appropriate regulation and privatisation. The aim of such a policy is
to deliver substantial efficiency gains on the part of telecommunications
carriers, which feed through into benefits for consumers.
A good summary of the worldwide trend was contained in Telstra's submission:
...regulatory trends around the world are towards more open
telecommunications market structures. Telecommunications markets in
the United States, United Kingdom and New Zealand have been important
test-houses for market liberalisation. Governments in these countries
have been among the first to remove regulatory barriers as technological
obstacles to competition have been eroded.
All major telecommunications markets have moved towards open
competition. The European Union has determined that each government
and telecommunications authority of its member states must open telephony
markets to competition in 1998 (Portugal, Greece and Ireland are subject
to later dates for liberalisation). The United States Congress has
passed legislation to remove all constraints on competition in local
telephony and other markets. Governments in Latin America and the
Asia Pacific region have moved to allow varying degrees of competition.
Privatisation is also not an isolated phenomenon, but has been
associated with telecommunications market liberalisation. In Europe,
the national carriers of Belgium, the Czech Republic, Denmark, France,
Germany, Greece, Hungary, Latvia, the Netherlands, Ireland, Italy, Portugal,
Spain, Sweden, Turkey and the United Kingdom have been, or are proposed
to be, privatised or partially privatised. The major Latin American
telecommunications companies in Argentina, Chile and Peru have been
privatised. Within the Asia-Pacific region, the governments of Singapore,
Malaysia, Japan, Korea and New Zealand have privatised or partially
privatised State-owned carriers..... [5]
Many witnesses who appeared before the inquiry pointed out that competition
is the most important aspect in achieving efficiency gains in the telecommunications
market. The Western Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry (WACCI)
said:
Both economic theory and empirical evidence suggest that the
key to efficient markets is effective competition.
Analysis by the Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and
Development (OECD) and the Bureau of Industry Economics indicates
that the degree of competition in telecommunications markets is a
key determinant of the market's efficiency. Any reforms undertaken
by the new government must be made in a manner which promotes competition....
...both within Australian markets and between countries, there
appears to be a clear link between the degree of competition and the
extent to which prices are falling. Competition is probably the single
most important determinant of market efficiency [6].
A similar view was put by the Business Council of Australia:
After 1997 the telecommunications industry will be further deregulated
and the march of technology will continue to impose new realities in
the communications market place. The Business Council believes that
a competitive environment will enable the development of more efficient
service providers and better, more innovative and competitively priced
products and services to their customers. [7]
Interestingly, it was not just business groups which acknowledged the
benefits of competition. The Australian Consumers Association said in
its submission:
...ACA believes effective competition rather than privatisation
per se, is the key to delivering improved efficiencies... [8]
Senator Schacht and other Opposition Senators participating in the
Inquiry at times attempted to suggest that while competition has brought
benefits to the telecommunications industry and consumers, privatisation
is a separate and different matter. We think this argument does not
take account of the interaction between competition, privatisation and
market liberalisation. The Government's policy will allow for powerful
interactions between these forces, resulting in a greater benefit than
would come from any of them occurring alone. It is true that the principal
benefit comes from competitive forces operating on companies as they
make their decisions; but the key point is that wholly or partly privatised
companies respond much better to those competitive forces. This point
was made by Mr Ian Martin, telecommunications analyst with investment
bank BZW:
Certainly the greater benefits come from competition...There
is a joint benefit. You get far more out of competition if you have
also got private sector influence. [9]
We therefore believe that the weight of evidence suggests that as the
telecommunications market becomes more competitive, and less regulated,
the part privatisation of Telstra is an appropriate and sensible policy
for the Government to introduce.
2.2 Part privatisation will improve Telstra's performance
We are satisfied, based on the abundant evidence we have received,
that part privatisation of Telstra will improve the company's performance,
for several reasons:
- it will make Telstra more efficient
- it will give Telstra greater freedom of action
- it will give Telstra greater clarity of purpose.
2.2.1 Part privatisation will make Telstra more efficient
2.2.1.1 Telstra is relatively inefficient
We have been provided with extensive evidence which leaves us with
a very clear conclusion: Telstra is still relatively inefficient compared
to other carriers around the world. Submissions to the Inquiry indicate
that Telstra is currently 25-40 percent behind worlds' best practice
on common measures of operational performance:
Telstra has scope to improve its performance. Although commercialisation
and the introduction of competition have brought a more commercial focus
to Telstra management in recent years, comparisons of Telstra's performance
relative to other international telecommunications carriers indicates
that it is still operating below optimal efficiency, for example against
the widely used operating benchmark "access lines per employee",
Telstra's ratio of 135 compares with a ratio of 200 for both BT and
Telecommunications Corporation New Zealand (TCNZ). [10]
A number of research bodies have investigated Telstra's performance,
and reached the view that there is considerable scope for improvement.
The BIE, for example, in Research Report 65, International Performance
Indicators Telecommunications 1995, pointed to growth in Total Factor
Productivity (TFP) for Telstra between 1980 and 1994, with strongest growth
since 1991-92. The Report found improvements in TFP and the return on
assets encouraging but expressed concern about the distance between telecommunications
operating performance and international best practice. It concluded that
by international standards, productivity in telecommunications in Australia
remained low up to and including 1992-93. [11]
Table 1 below was prepared by investment bank BZW. It suggests that
on a number of key measures, Telstra needs to make substantial improvements
in several areas if it is to attain world's best practice.
Table 1 - Telstra's comparative performance
Company |
Enterprise value per access line (US$) |
Enterprise value/sales (US$) |
Enterprise value/EBITDA (US$) |
Access Lines per employee |
Telstra |
2,654 |
2.3 |
5.1x |
135 |
RBOC Avg |
2,120 |
2.7 |
6.6x |
250 |
BT |
1,426 |
1.8 |
5.0x |
200 |
HK Telecom |
6,734 |
6.1 |
14.3x |
200 |
Singapore Tel |
27,746 |
14.9 |
25.2x |
125 |
KPN |
2,662 |
1.9 |
5.2x |
235 |
Telecom Italia |
866 |
1.5 |
3.0x |
270 |
TCNZ |
5,495 |
4.8 |
8.9x |
200 |
Source: BZW, March 1996.
The Department of Communications and the Arts also drew the Inquiry's
attention to work done by the Bureau of Industry Economics in comparing
access lines per employee in selected countries. Table 2 below is based
on this work (note that it draws on slightly earlier data than that
contained in table 1).
Table 2 - Access lines per employee in selected OECD countries
|
Lines per employee |
Australia |
124 |
Canada |
187 |
Denmark |
186 |
Finland |
194 |
Germany |
158 |
Italy |
271 |
Japan |
235 |
Netherlands |
234 |
Switzerland |
206 |
United Kingdom |
160 |
United States |
223 |
Source: BIE International Performance Indicators Telecommunications
1995, p.121
Clearly, no single measure can fully capture the dimensions of Telstra's
productivity gap. But as the Department of Communications and the Arts
noted, there is wide acceptance of Telstra's relatively poor performance
against a range of overseas benchmarks.
The BIE's broad conclusion has been recently supported by Xavier
and Graham who prepared an international benchmarking report for AUSTEL.
They conclude that `Telstra's efficiency performance remains mediocre
when compared against the world's benchmark carriers. While ... Telstra's
exact positioning [is] open to protracted disagreement, there will be
less disagreement that a performance gap exists. Indeed, Telstra itself
does not dispute such a gap'. [12]
The Department of Communications and the Arts informed the inquiry
that the Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics (BTCE) has
recently estimated Telstra's lines per employee for 1993-94 and 1994-95,
compared with the period 1979-80 to 1992-93. A graph drawn from the
BTCE work is at Figure 1 below. It shows that the lines per employee
ratio improved from the late 1980s to 1993-94, but it also suggests
that overall the rate of improvement is declining, and that the rate
of this decline would be greater if not for the strong growth in the
number of mobile subscribers. Since mobile subscribers are typically
excluded from the international data set out above, it is the fixed
lines/employee ratio which is relevant - and which points to a
serious and persistent problem.
Source: BTCE estimates
Evidence about Telstra's inefficiency was also provided by Mr Brian
Perkins of the Service Providers' Action Network:
As a broad comparison, SPAN member, AAP Telecommunications (AAPT),
currently generates around $770,000 per employee per annum compared
with Telstra at around $160,000...Telstra's efficiency is significantly
less than AAPT's. [13]
The combined weight of this evidence leaves us no choice but to conclude
that there is significant scope for improving Telstra's performance.
This was acknowledged by Mr Paul Rizzo, Group Managing Director, Telstra:
...for 1994-95 we assess that we are approximately 25% below
the floor on world's best practice compared to the peer group in this
particular methodology. As the peer group continues to improve - we
are not in a static world - we could be up to 40% below best practice
within the life of our next three year corporate plan. [14]
It is particularly interesting that there is acceptance across a wide
range of ideologies and interests that Telstra is inefficient. For example,
the point has been acknowledged by the Australian Consumers' Association:
Indeed, even the Telstra unions accept that Telstra is behind world's
best practice. The following exchange between Senator O'Chee and Mr
McLean of the CEPU demonstrates the point:
Senator O'Chee: Do you accept the fact
that it [Telstra] is behind world's best practice?
Mr McLean: It can be improved. I do not think
there is any argument about that. [16]
Some witnesses argued that Telstra's poor performance relative to international
best practice can be accounted for by the different operating conditions
in Australia, such as Australia's large relatively lowly populated land
mass. However, we are satisfied that the evidence shows that these conditions
do not account for Telstra's relative inefficiency. The evidence on
this point was summarised by the Department of Communications and the
Arts:
The contribution of a geographically-dispersed population to
the productivity gap between Australia and other carriers has been examined
(Henry Ergas and BIE) and the conclusion drawn that only a small amount
of this gap can be attributed to geographical factors. While Australia
does have sparsely-settled areas to service, the additional cost of
these is small relative to total cost (BTCE). Also, Telstra has the
advantage of highly-urbanised areas connected by the so-called `golden
boomerang' communications corridor. Comparisons with carriers operating
in sparsely populated areas - such as US West (BZW) and the Canadian
carriers (BIE) - indicate that Telstra's productivity is substantially
lower. [17]
Of course, the Opposition Parties know full well Telstra is relatively
inefficient. They do not want to admit it, though, because this fact
is one of the foundation stones for the Government's policy of part
privatising Telstra. So the Majority Report contains this delightful
piece of equivocation:
The Committee concluded that the evidence submitted to it on
Telstra's performance allowed for a wide range of interpretations. [18]
This is the kind of thing you would expect to hear if you returned
home to find someone rifling through your bedside table: It might
look like a burglar, but the evidence allows for a wide range of interpretations.
Just as you would be sceptical in this situation, so we are unpersuaded
by this remark in the Majority Report. We believe that the evidence
overwhelmingly shows that Telstra is relatively inefficient by world
standards.
2.2.1.2 Experience shows that privatisation tends to bring increased
efficiencies
Experience of privatisation elsewhere in the world shows that privatisation
leads companies to improve their performance. For example, the Department
of Finance cited a study of 41 firms fully or partially privatised between
1981 and 1989 in fifteen (primarily industrial) countries, which showed
those firms achieved substantial efficiency gains. Once privatised,
the firms:
- increased returns on sales, assets, and equity;
- improved internal efficiency through better utilisation of physical
and human resources;
- improved their capital structure - becoming less leveraged;
- increased capital expenditures; and
- marginally increased their work forces as a result of higher investment
and faster growth. [19]
Referring to the same study, Telstra said:
In a separate empirical comparison of the pre and post privatisation
financial and operating performance of the fully and partially privatised
companies, Megginson et al found that the mean and median profitability,
real sales, operating efficiency and capital investment spending increased
(in statistical and economic terms) after privatisation. Sales per employee
increased from an average 95.6% of the year 0 value during the 3 year
pre privatisation period to 106.2% of the year 0 in the post privatisation
period. Net income per employee increased even more, by a mean 25.1%.
According to this study, efficiency improvements were the norm for most
of the sample companies. [20]
Summarising the outcome of the major economic studies on the effects
of privatisation Telstra submitted:
The authoritative empirical studies summarised here support the
conclusion that private ownership is likely to result in higher levels
of company profitability and performance. These studies and the weight
of numbers of other studies, support this conclusion. We have not identified
a body of studies which indicate that public ownership is likely to
result in superior commercial performance. [21]
Telstra also cited research on a related point: the relative economic
performance of firms in public and private ownership.
Vining and Boardman (1992), in their major study Ownership
Versus Competition: Efficiency in Public Enterprises,
provide an overview of empirical research on the efficiency of private
and public firms. Their review...shows that most studies of the comparative
performance of private and public companies conclude that private companies
are more efficient than public companies. [22]
We expect that the benefits of privatisation experienced by other countries
will be achieved in Australia. After all, the experience from other industries
in the Australian context has been similar. For example, the Department
of Finance pointed out that the operating efficiency of the Commonwealth
Bank of Australia (CBA) has improved significantly since the Initial Public
Offering (IPO) of shares in 1991. The CBA's cost / income ratio has fallen
from 67.7% in 1991-92 to 60.9% for the half year ended 31 December 1995.
CBA staff numbers (measured as full-time equivalents) have fallen from
45,790 in 1991-92 to 35,822 in 1994-95. [23]
The likely efficiency gains which Telstra might achieve were summarised
thus:
If Telstra was to realise efficiency gains of 30% (based on operating
expenses per access line) bringing the company closer to world's best
practice, it is estimated that this would realise savings in the order
of $1.6 billion. Privatisation, with accountability to private investors,
would accelerate the necessity to achieve such efficiency improvements.
Ultimately, shareholders and consumers benefit from such efficiency
improvements. [24]
2.2.1.3 The Commonwealth will share in efficiency gains as two thirds
shareholder
We believe it is significant that the Government is proposing to retain
two thirds ownership of Telstra. The constant references, during the
course of the Inquiry, by the Opposition Senators and some witnesses
to total privatisation were misleading and untrue. The same untruth
is repeated throughout the Majority Report. Many witnesses who made
such claims were asked by Government Senators who they believed would
take the decision to permit 100% privatisation, given that the Government
does not have a majority in the Senate. They were quite unable to provide
a satisfactory answer to this question.
Unlike some full privatisations overseas where a significant proportion
of the efficiency gains went to the new private sector owners, the Commonwealth,
as the major shareholder of Telstra, will share in the efficiency gains
produced from privatisation. On this point, the Department of Finance
submitted:
While the Government will forego future dividend payments in
proportion to the shareholding it sells, Telstra's current and expected
dividend payments are significantly less than the expected interest
savings associated with the likely reduction in Commonwealth debt (equivalent
to the estimated value of the Company). If the potential for increased
profitability is realised following the stimulus of private investment,
this would further increase the value of the Commonwealth's residual
two thirds equity in later years, and may be expected to increase dividend
payments on a pro-rata basis. [25]
We note that paragraph 4.44 of the Majority Report makes the extraordinary
claim that the only beneficiaries of a partial privatisation of Telstra
would be a few private individuals, and not the people of Australia.
This claim reveals a fundamental misunderstanding of the rationale for
the Government's policy: to increase Telstra's efficiency so as to bring
consumer benefits.
In addition to consumer benefits, of course, there will be significant
benefits to the Government as majority shareholder, due to the increased
profitability which Telstra would achieve as a result of its exposure
to the private sector. An extensive study conducted by Parker and Martin
(1996) on the profit levels of 11 privatised firms in the United Kingdom
confirmed that 'privatisation does seem to have been associated with higher
profitability.' [26] As the partial
privatisation increases Telstra's efficiency and hence its ability to
prosper in a competitive environment, the government, and the people of
Australia, as the majority shareholders, will more than likely stand to
gain from the enhanced value of their investment in Telstra. Conversely,
should Telstra remain in full public ownership, with the handicaps which
that will impose on its ability to respond to competition, the value of
that investment will inevitably shrink.
2.2.1.4 Exposure to capital markets discipline and scrutiny
That partial privatisation will improve Telstra's performance is not
a matter of theory. Rather, the evidence presented to the Inquiry points
to a range of ways through which these effects will occur.
We are persuaded by the evidence that we heard that privatisation will
drive Telstra to be more efficient because its managers' performance
will be subject to the disciplines and scrutiny of the capital market.
When Telstra's shares are listed, the prices at which they trade will
provide a benchmark for assessing management performance and determining
the value of investments and marketing initiatives. In listed companies,
shareholders dissatisfied with corporate performance are able to sell
shares in the enterprise, driving down share prices and exposing management
performance. The threat of sell-down, and the continuous assessment
of performance, disciplines management to operate efficiently and meet
market expectations. The market's changing valuation of Telstra will
also provide an important indicator to the Commonwealth, assisting in
its own scrutiny of Telstra's performance.
Part-privatisation will not only impose greater disciplines on Telstra
management by exposing them to the disciplines of the capital market;
it will also provide additional public accountability as Telstra is
subjected to the scrutiny of the capital market. This point was made
by the Business Council of Australia:
The exposure of a company's commercial performance and structure
to the capital market, both in terms of price trends and scrutiny by market
analysts, will provide a sharper focus for management and prove to be
a strong driver to improve products and efficiency. [27]
Similar views were expressed by other witnesses, including investment
bank BZW, the Department of Finance and the WA Chamber of Commerce and
Industry.
We therefore believe that the listing of Telstra, following its part
privatisation, will increase the scrutiny on and accountability of Telstra
management. We further believe that this increased scrutiny and accountability
will force greater efficiency and create room for sustainable benefits
to consumers.
2.2.1.5 Alignment of staff, company and shareholder objectives through
employee incentives
A number of submissions to the Inquiry explained that through the provision
of special incentives for employee share ownership, the Government is
helping to ensure that a partially privatised Telstra will improve its
performance. Schemes which encourage share ownership among employees
allow the closer alignment of objectives within a company. As owners,
employees will have an even more direct incentive to improve company
performance.
Of course, the Opposition Senators argue that employees of Telstra
already have an ownership interest along with all other Australians,
as the company is publicly owned. This is mere sophistry, and does not
engage with the key issue: that there is plenty of evidence that companies
whose employees own shares in the company in their own right do better
than companies where this is not the case. This occurs because employees
who own shares have a direct financial incentive to see the company
performing optimally. This, in turn, leads to superior company performance,
as the Telstra submission pointed out:
Surveys by the Remuneration Corporation 1992/95 show that for
Australian listed companies over a recorded half decade, those companies
with an employee share plan delivered 88% higher total realisable returns
to shareholders. Comparable studies in Canada by the Canadian Stock
Exchange reveal 123% higher profit growth for companies with employee
share plans. [28]
2.2.2 Part privatisation will give Telstra greater commercial freedom
A second set of reasons why partial privatisation will lead to improvements
in Telstra's performance comes from the fact that Telstra will enjoy
greater commercial freedom post partial privatisation, subject to monitoring
by financial markets. In many important facets of its operations, Telstra
is subject to restrictions as a result of being in public ownership
which leads to sub-optimal performance. For example, it is clear from
the evidence that under full public ownership Telstra faces special
difficulties in raising capital.
Currently, Telstra's capital requirements are met through internal
fund raising, largely from retained earnings. As a government business
enterprise, Telstra is subject to Loan Council constraints, similar
to other Federal and State owned enterprises. This places an upper
constraint on Telstra's annual borrowing capacity. The company does
not have access to capital injections, as is the case for other companies
and borrowings.
As the global environment becomes more competitive, the continuation
of such constraints may not be commercially sustainable in the future,
particularly where profitability and cashflows come under pressure from
new market entrants. [29]
Although Telstra is not currently capital constrained, ultimately it
must have greater access to capital if it is to continue to grow. Part-privatisation
will assist in this, as the WACCI pointed out:
Telstra must be free to raise capital according to its commercial
requirements. Telecommunications is a highly capital intensive industry
and its investment requirements are massive. Privatisation will free
Telstra from explicit (Loans Council) and implicit (political) pressures
which might otherwise restrict its capacity to raise capital, and
will reassure investors that capital raisings are being undertaken
on commercial grounds.
In the current tight fiscal climate, the willingness and capacity
of the Government to fund substantial investment by Telstra is, at best,
open to question. [30]
Another area where a part privatised Telstra would enjoy greater freedom
of action is in its capacity to enter into joint ventures. Indeed, the
very inclusion in the terms of reference of this Inquiry of paragraph
(g), whether joint ventures by
Telstra are `de facto' privatisation and whether they confer unfair competitive
advantages on Telstra's partners, is a good example of how public
ownership currently imposes restrictions on Telstra's capacity to enter
into joint ventures.
Telstra pointed out in its evidence before the Inquiry that joint ventures
are an important commercial tool which are routinely used by businesses
in private ownership. Telstra sees sound strategic reasons for using
joint ventures in a range of circumstances, but currently its capacity
to do this is limited.
From a commercial perspective Telstra sees sound strategic
reasons for entering into partnering arrangements. It is one of a
range of business tools that can be employed to provide more flexibility
for a company entering into new markets, capturing efficiencies through
outsourcing and protecting the company's revenue base. Partnering
with local companies can also be a regulatory requirement for entry
into overseas markets.
...From a commercial view, Telstra considers that partnering
in Australia and internationally is important to the company's future
success. Telstra's strategy should be seen in the context of a global
market, where alliances and joint ventures are becoming a normal way
of competing in the market. FOXTEL and the ISSC partnerships are two
prime examples where Telstra is using alliances to make the transition
to an information and communications services company, while also protecting
the value of the core business. [31]
We are satisfied that it is highly desirable that Telstra should be able
to enter into joint ventures. As to our view on paragraph (g)
of the terms of reference, whether joint ventures by Telstra are
de facto' privatisation and whether they confer unfair competitive
advantages on Telstra's partners, we are satisfied that joint ventures
do not represent de facto privatisation. Moreover, we have heard no evidence
to suggest that the normal laws regulating anti-competitive conduct are
in any way inadequate to prevent Telstra's joint venture partners receiving
any unfair advantage.
Finding: There is no basis for the concern that
the entry by Telstra into joint ventures constitutes de facto privatisation
or confers unfair competitive advantages on Telstra's partners.
|
2.2.3 Part privatisation will give Telstra greater clarity of purpose
A third driver of improvements to Telstra's performance which we have
identified from evidence heard by the Inquiry is that partial privatisation
will bring a greater clarity of purpose to Telstra. Full public ownership
means that Telstra management, of necessity, must have greater regard
to the possible political consequences of business decisions than a
private counterpart. Telstra's own submission indicates that it perceives
that political considerations are having an important bearing on its
decision-making:
Complying with the range of government objectives and company
law reporting obligations can impose conflicting objectives on management.
For example, objectives to maximise shareholder returns may be incompatible
with achieving other "political" objectives to provide services
to satisfy a particular constituency. [32]
A similar point was made by Mr Alan Horsley of the Australian Telecommunications
Users Group:
...the private sector ethos of commitment and achievement is
likely to bring benefit to the quality and robustness of the Telstra
network. I think, from our perspective, the quality of services provided
by Telstra is second to none. Our concern is that often you cannot
get them, that the development does not occur quickly enough, that
the way in which the services are presented ought to be more customer
focused...
We think that the drive that is offered by the private sector
ethos, the concept of some private sector people on the board of Telstra,
is a good thing. We also see that the discipline of removing ministerial
reference and interference is an eminently sensible thing to do in that
it will provide a much more focused opportunity for Telstra. [33]
This point was also endorsed by the former Labor mayor of Townsville,
Mr Mike Reynolds:
I have no doubt that with a privatised or partly privatised organisation
we would have less political interference in that particular way...In
terms of a privatised or semi-privatised board of Telstra, naturally
we see a lessening of that government influence. [34]
Witnesses commented that they saw the proposed ownership structure
as achieving a desirable outcome for Telstra:
In regard to ownership issues the ATIA fully supports the approach
foreshadowed by the Government that Telstra remain majority Australian
owned and controlled. This approach will provide the policy thrust to
ensure Telstra is more responsive to market signals whilst ensuring
that this most important strategic industry remains in Australian hands.
[35]
2.3 Part privatisation will bring benefits for consumers
Improvements in Telstra's efficiency are just a means to an end. Unless
the benefits from those improvements in efficiency are passed on to consumers,
we do not believe there is a case for privatisation. We were therefore
pleased that the Inquiry received ample and convincing evidence, based
on overseas experience, that part privatisation of Telstra will benefit
consumers through performance improvements being shared with consumers.
In our view, this evidence demonstrates compellingly that the Majority
Report is wrong in arguing that part privatisation will make the people
of Australia the financial losers. [36]
In fact, the lesson of overseas telco privatisations is that as Telstra
becomes a more efficient operator in a competitive environment, it will
pass on price reductions to the Australian people which will lead them
to enjoy, in aggregate, significant financial gains.
The Inquiry learned that consumers received substantial benefits as a
consequence of privatisation in the UK telecommunications industry. Telecommunications
consumers in the aggregate gained in every year since the announcement
of the sale of BT. Although there was some deterioration in the quality
of service in the early years after privatisation - partly because of
increased demand - subsequent improvements reversed the deterioration
and yielded an overall improvement. [37]
The submission from the Department of Communications and the Arts went
into considerable detail about the benefits for consumers arising from
privatisation of BT in Britain and TCNZ in New Zealand:
A World Bank study Welfare Consequences of Selling Public
Enterprises published in 1994 stated that the benefits to the
British consumer of the sale of British Telecom (BT) amounted to 4,150
million pounds.
The study further concluded that the substantial additional
revenues which BT generated from sales each year, both before and
after government divestiture, differed in their source in that prior
to divestiture the revenue boost came primarily from raising prices;
whereas after divestiture it came from increasing real output.
Since BT's privatisation in 1984, OFTEL figures show that the
overall weighted average of BT's prices subject to control under its
licence has declined by over 40 per cent in real terms. Business connections,
for example, decreased by 36 per cent, while reductions in peak rate
national calls were between 56 per cent and 78 per cent depending
on the category. At the same time, BT's quality of service has improved
significantly when measured against most indicators.
The costs of telecommunications have also fallen sharply for
the smaller residential customers: those who make relatively few STD
calls. In the three years since July 1993, the total bill of the typical
low user residential customer - one who makes less than
five pounds of calls per quarter - has fallen by over 20 per cent.
The privatisation of Telecom New Zealand (TCNZ) and the deregulation
of telecommunications in New Zealand has resulted in similar benefits.
On average, charges for residential toll calls decreased in nominal
terms by 14 per cent per annum over the seven years to 1995. TCNZ's
overall price per minute for national long distance calls reduced by
55 per cent in real terms between 1988 and 1994; and TCNZ increased
its total factor productivity by 9.5 to 10 per cent annually over the
same period. [38]
The Department of Communications and the Arts provided the Inquiry
with the data in table 3 below, which are drawn from an OECD comparative
study on telecommunications prices. The OECD methodology for the comparison
of national business user prices involves a basket of fixed charges
and usage charges, including fixed phone lines, local and trunk call
charges set at certain ratios (20% fixed - including installation and
rent, and 80% usage). The table demonstrates that Telstra's performance
ranking has been static, remaining at 14, whilst both BT and New Zealand
have improved their respective rankings.
Table 3 - Price movements and OECD price rank
for Australia, New Zealand and the UK, 1992 and 1994
Country |
1992(rank) |
1994 (rank) |
Australia (Telstra) |
1156.20 (14) |
1012.19 (14) |
UK(BT) |
925.77 (10) |
763.48 (7) |
New Zealand |
934.47 (11) |
778.79 (8) |
Similar evidence on this point was provided by Telstra:
The overseas evidence suggests that market liberalisation,
along with exposure to market disciplines, has created the mix of
commercial incentives for telcos to achieve efficiency gains and deliver
lower price services for consumers. Moreover, there is evidence that
the quality of service delivered by the newly privatised firm does
not decline...
....Competition, along with privatisation is expected to maximise
these consumer benefits. In the case of New Zealand, Ergas has argued
that "the trifecta of full liberalisation, privatisation and light-handed
regulation" has delivered positive consumer outcomes. New Zealand
telecommunications charges are now estimated to be around 20% less than
charges in Australia. Ergas also compared the quality of service between
TCNZ and Telstra and found no significant difference. [39]
Telstra also cite a recent study of the New Zealand experience which
finds very positive results for consumers following the TCNZ privatisation.
Boles de Boer and Evans (1996) report that New Zealand deregulation
and privatisation resulted in price reductions leading to an increase
in consumer welfare valued at NZ$575 million per year. The discounted
value of this sum exceeds the sale price of TCNZ (NZ$ 4.25 billion).
The authors state that the bulk of the gains have accrued to consumers.
[40]
It is interesting that the likelihood of price benefits for consumers
following the privatisation of Telstra appears to be accepted by many
participants in the present debate. For example, Ms Ros Eason, Senior
Industrial Research Officer with the CEPU, said:
Telecom New Zealand's prices have declined. All the telecommunications
companies' prices have declined since privatisation - that is not at
issue. [41]
As well as studies dealing with the experience of telco privatisation
in Britain and New Zealand, there is a considerable literature dealing
with the more general question of the consequences of privatisation
for consumers and other stakeholders. In a supplementary submission
to the Inquiry which reviewed this literature, Telstra noted:
The two most authoritative studies dealing directly with the
effects of privatisation are The Financial and Operating
Performance of Newly Privatized Firms: An International Empirical Analysis
(Megginson, Nash and van Randenborgh, 1994) and
International Welfare Consequences of Selling Public
Enterprises (Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang
1994). Although these are not perfect, these studies are thorough, empirical
and not contradicted by other evidence. [42]
Telstra's submission reports that the Galal, Jones et al study:
- is based on detailed case studies of 12 privatisations in the UK,
Chile, Malaysia and Mexico, including three telecommunications companies
- compares actual outcomes from privatisation to counterfactual
scenarios, ie assumptions about what would have happened had privatisation
not occurred
- finds that privatisation improved economic welfare in all 12 cases
studied
- found that the distribution of privatisation benefits varies from
case to case - for example, the benefits of privatising the Chilean
telephone company flowed largely to consumers
- found that consumer welfare increased in five cases and was unchanged
in three cases. [43]
Telstra expanded on the Chilean outcome as follows:
In the case of Chile, the majority of benefits arising from privatisation
of the national phone company accrued to consumers (90%), as a result
of increased network investment made possible by funds freed up by the
divestiture. [44]
The Majority Report devotes considerable effort to criticising the empirical
evidence which was put to the Inquiry, including the studies we have cited
above, as to the efficiency and other benefits of privatisation. [45]
The main theme of the criticism was that no empirical study exists which
exactly duplicates the circumstances of Telstra's privatisation.
This is quite true; there is only one Telstra, there is only one Australia,
and there is only one 1996. But it is equally true that the overwhelming
weight of evidence from privatisations around the world, across a range
of countries and industries, suggests that privatised companies perform
more efficiently and this leads to benefits which are shared between a
range of stakeholders including, importantly, consumers. No amount of
rhetorical extravagance about General Pinochet's regime will allow the
Opposition Parties to evade this fact.
The evidence we have cited raises the question as to how it is that
privatisation brings benefits of the kinds described above. The evidence
provided to the Inquiry suggests that benefits arise because private
sector companies, focussing on improving returns and reducing costs,
are likely to be more innovative than their public sector counterparts.
A part-privatised Telstra will have every incentive to maintain and
improve its relationship with existing customers. It will want to satisfy
their needs for new and improved services or risk losing them to competitors.
For example, one of Telstra's key commercial advantages is the ubiquity
and nearly universal use of its basic telephone network. It will want
to retain that advantage as the services available are enhanced. It
has clear incentives to try to be the low-cost provider of enhanced
services to rural and remote customers, thereby ensuring the fullest
use of its network facilities.
A good statement of the effects of part privatisation on Telstra's
motivation to provide superior customer service was made by Mr Graeme
Ward, Group Director, Regulatory and External Affairs, Telstra, when
he appeared before the Inquiry:
In an increasingly competitive environment - and we are going
to move from one period of competition between 1991 and 1997 and beyond
1997 into a very open competitive regime - competition is all about
competing for customers and customer business and our focus is very
much on fighting for customers, retaining our customer coverage and
winning new customers....What we are on about is winning the customers'
loyalty and we can really only do that by service, the duality of service
at competitive prices - the value equation. [46]
The Government of Western Australia, in its oral submission made by
Mr Phillip Skelton, indicated that it supported part privatisation of
Telstra on the grounds of the likely benefits for consumers:
...consumers will benefit if Telstra, as one of the competing
carriers, is robust, effective, customer responsive and internationally
competitive. Telstra has gone a long way towards improving its performance
over the last few years in the face of the competition that it has
actually had....Nevertheless, we see that it has now reached a barrier
where some further significant change has to take place before it
can remain healthy and competitive and deliver its good results in
the future more open and competitive environment.
Consequently, the Government of Western Australia supports the
concept of the partial privatisation of Telstra. We see a number of
benefits flowing immediately to Telstra as a result of that action.
That, in turn, would flow through as benefits to consumers. [47]
The National Farmers' Federation supports part privatisation of Telstra
on the grounds of improved service.
Look at the New Zealand experience where they privatised New
Zealand Telecom. We have spoken to New Zealand Federated Farmers and
asked them if they found the service better or worse since New Zealand
Telecom has been privatised. They have certainly said there is a better
service delivery. The sort of examples that are quoted are that the
waiting time for new lines is down from six weeks to three days. Certainly
the farmers of New Zealand feel that service delivery is a lot better.
[48]
Electronic Commerce Australia, the peak body for the electronic commerce
community, also believes privatisation will lead to improvements in
service.
ECA members support the sale of Telstra in the belief that Telstra
will be able to compete in the same market place with the same conditions
as any other service provider. Users of electronic commerce require
from their suppliers improved services, lower costs, improved quality
and on time delivery. A fully privately owned Telstra will, we believe,
create the market conditions for this to evolve. [49]
The Majority Report argues that the expected consumer benefits may be
compromised because Telstra is a monopoly. [50]
We believe this argument overlooks the fact that in many key markets,
including mobile, long distance and international, Telstra has lost substantial
market share to Optus and Vodafone. The increased competition to be introduced
under the post-1997 regime will only add to the competitive pressure on
Telstra. Additionally, the argument used in the Majority Report appears
to assume that as a part privatised company Telstra is in some way less
likely to exploit any monopoly power it enjoys than it would be as a public
company. The absurdity of this proposition is evident to anyone who recalls
the indifferent customer service and high prices which prevailed in the
days when Telecom was the sole telephone company in Australia.
We are therefore satisfied, based on a very thorough review of the
evidence, that the partial privatisation of Telstra will deliver substantial
consumer benefits.
2.4 The case for withdrawing Government funds from Telstra
As many submissions demonstrated, there are considerable benefits to
introducing private ownership in Telstra. But - as a separate issue
- there is also a strong case for reducing Government ownership of
Telstra. As the Department of Finance argued, at one time there
was a good case for putting Government money into what was then a fledgling
industry; but that time has long since passed:
The need for Government investment in the telecommunications
industry is reducing and public resources may better be redirected
to other uses. While in previous generations it may have been necessary
for Government to invest to develop the national telecommunications
industry, it is now clear that three forces are reducing the case
for public intervention in private capital decisions:
- the commercial capital markets now have the depth, sophistication
and readiness, not only to provide the further capital needed
for development, but also to replace the Government's own sunk
capital; the industry is now sustainable in the private equity
market;
- pressure for scarce public sector resources to be deployed
to national goals that are inappropriate for private sector investment
(such as public sector debt reduction and environmental safeguards
and restitution) means that public capital, where possible, should
be withdrawn from investments which can now be appropriately funded
by private capital and placed more appropriately in these higher
priority areas - privatisation achieves this; and
- the telecommunications industry is in an era of fast growth,
diversification and technological change; this increases the risk
associated with continuing to hold a substantial investment in the
industry. While governments do have a substantial capacity to spread
risks, taxpayers have a clear reluctance to accept high levels of
risk. The need for taxpayers to assume a higher level of risk is
much reduced compared to a decade or so ago because the capital
markets now allow investors to choose the level of risk that they
are prepared to accept - with commensurate expected returns. This
allows individuals - either directly or through institutions and
fund managers - to exercise greater individual choice than if they
were all required to assume a specific risk because of public ownership
of assets that may be riskier than they would freely select. Adequate
private risk capital is available in an efficient market, with investors
participating in the market doing so with full knowledge of the
risk-return trade-off involved. [51]
2.4.1 Release funds for other purposes
One set of reasons for withdrawing public money from Telstra is that
resources are limited and must be allocated where they are most needed.
Public ownership of Telstra represents a very substantial public capital
investment in the provision of telecommunications infrastructure and
services. Public ownership of Telstra is no longer a necessity to ensure
that all Australians have access to adequate telecommunications services.
It makes good sense, therefore, for Government to consider whether some
of the capital tied up in Telstra might be better employed.
In our view, there is no doubt that there is a pressing need for that
capital to be applied to reduction of public debt. Following Labor's
years in government, the interest bill on public debt is a major Budget
item in its own right.
The pressing need for spending on the environment is another reason
why it makes sense to withdraw funds from Telstra. The Government has
identified a program of investment to repair and replenish our natural
capital for this and future generations of Australians. There has been
no questioning of the priority which should be accorded to this investment
- the only issue is the means by which it can be funded.
2.4.2 Reduce the Government's exposure to an increasingly risky industry
We believe that another set of reasons for reducing public ownership
in Telstra relate to the increasing risk of the telecommunications industry,
and the desirability of the Government reducing its exposure to this
risk.
Telstra highlighted the increasingly risky environment it operates
in:
Rapidly changing technology as is occurring in the telecommunications
industry brings with it greater risk, along with the possibility of
greater reward. The product range is expanding and diversifying and
the product development cycle is shorter. Lower barriers to entry enable
more competitors, generating high returns to those who can act quickly
to marshal the necessary resources. [52]
The implication of this is that Government should carefully examine
whether it is appropriate to have so much public money tied up in this
industry. The point was well made by the WA Chamber of Commerce and
Industry:
....the changing nature of the market implies that taxpayer funds
invested in the telecommunications industry are less secure than they
once were. Shareholders who risk their wealth by investing in private
businesses do so voluntarily. It is not appropriate for the Government
to risk taxpayers' funds in this way in an industry which can be demonstrated
to operate at least as efficiently in private hands as in the public
sector, unless there are strong over-riding arguments implying a public
benefit from public ownership. For telecommunications this does not
appear to be the case. [53]
The decisions which Telstra has to make - about network investment;
about provision of new services; about entering new markets - are all
commercial decisions. They are decisions which should be fully subject
to commercial assessment. Even on the issue of universal service obligations,
the decisions Telstra must make are fundamentally commercial: namely,
to determine the most economical means to provide the standard of service
which the Government has mandated. Decisions of this kind are not the
proper province of Government, because they are not public policy decisions.
2.5 Part privatisation will reduce the Government's conflict of interest
While the Government has made clear that it will be giving priority
to achieving a pro-competitive framework and maximising benefits to
consumers over obtaining the maximum sale price from Telstra, there
is a clear perception that full public ownership creates conflicts of
interest with the Government's negotiating role. A number of submissions
argued that part-privatisation will reduce the scope for such conflicts,
as it forces the Government to make regulatory arrangements transparent
and deal with Telstra at arms-length:
Privatisation would also reduce the Government's conflict of
interest in the way in which the industry operates. The Government has
responsibility for providing a national legal and regulatory framework
designed to ensure economic efficiency by encouraging competition and
preventing abuse of monopoly power. But as sole owner of Telstra and
sole recipient of its revenues it also has a substantial interest in
maximising profits and returns, and retention of regulation and anti-competitive
behaviour are likely to be profitable to the government. [54]
It is interesting that Professor Quiggin has pointed to the existence
of this same conflict of interest:
Senator Margetts: Professor Quiggin, you have indicated that
there seems to be a potential for a major conflict of interest in
relation to part-privatisation...
Professor Quiggin: The issue is basically that these decisions
are going to affect the sale price to the extent that the government
can give guarantees that the decisions after privatisation will be in
a manner favourable to the owners of the asset...Any guarantees of that
sort will increase the sale price, but they may well lead to bad public
policy. [55]
While both the Government and its opponents perceive the existence
of the same conflict of interest - between the Commonwealth as regulator
and as owner of shares in Telstra - only the Government is suggesting
a solution. The opponents seem quite happy to leave Telstra 100% publicly
owned, with the conflict starkly exposed.
2.6 Part privatisation will bring national economic benefits
The Inquiry received considerable substantive evidence concerning the
potential benefits to the wider economy. Based on that evidence, we
are of the view that part privatisation of Telstra will bring substantial
national economic benefits in two important ways:
- GDP consequences
- benefits to national savings and repayment of public sector debt.
2.6.1 A boost to GDP
Telstra's submission provided a detailed exposition of benefits in
terms of GDP growth, consumer surplus, more efficient use of the community's
resources, improved international competitiveness and reducing the relative
cost disadvantages experienced by businesses and residents in rural
and remote regions of Australia.
According to Industry Commission analysis, adoption of Hilmer-type
competition reforms in the telecommunications sector was estimated
to achieve significant improvements in GDP of the order of $2.7 billion.
Follow-up analysis by the Centre for Regional Economic Analysis showed
that all industries and every state of Australia would benefit from
these reforms. This results because virtually every business in Australia
is connected to a telephone network and therefore uses a component
of communications as an input in the production process.
...It is also important from an international competitiveness
viewpoint that Australia has an efficient and minimum cost telecommunications
infrastructure. Improving productivity within Telstra and the industry
assists exporters (and potential exporters) to compete in international
markets and domestic-focussed firms to compete with imports. Higher
exports and import substitution both operate to increase measured domestic
GDP. Furthermore, this could lessen (although difficult to quantify)
the current account deficit, historically a major cyclical constraint
to economic growth in Australia. [56]
Several submissions reinforced this point by drawing attention to the
benefits for other industries - particularly those exposed to international
competition - of achieving efficiencies in the delivery of telecommunications
services. For example the submission by the National Farmers' Federation
stated:
As business operators at the end of the chain, the farming community
have had to bear the cost of, in many respects, inefficiencies in services
provided in that way in the past. As the telecommunications industry
moves into the next century, we have to have them moving at that pace
and we definitely need Telstra to be able to keep pace with the competitors
that are now snapping at their heels. [57]
The case for widespread economic benefits deriving from a combination
of part-privatisation of Telstra and enhanced competition in the telecommunications
market was further supported by work commissioned by the Department
of Communications and the Arts.
The Inquiry heard that the Department of Communications and the Arts
had commissioned some modelling of the potential economic gains arising
from improving Telstra's labour and capital efficiency. [58]
This built on work done previously by EPAC and the Industry Commission
and suggests that there are some significant potential gains to the wider
Australian economy simply through improving Telstra's technical efficiency
(ie. without taking account of likely changes to service offerings).
The work was summarised as follows:
For labour, efficiency gains of 15%, 30% and 45% were modelled
for the communications sector as a whole. These correspond to improving
Telstra's ratio of access lines per employee to about 160, 190 and
220 respectively (adjusted for Telstra's market share). For capital,
efficiency gains of 0%, 10% and 20% were modelled. Notably, the middle
case scenario (a 30% gain in labour efficiency and 10% gain in capital
efficiency spread over four years) indicates the following:
- private consumption (an indicator of living standards) would
increase by $1.7 billion (a permanent 0.6 per cent gain)
- an 11.7% fall in the long run price of communications services
- an associated gain in economy-wide GDP peaking at 0.5% ($2.4
billion) in 2002/3 moderating to 0.35% ($1.7 billion) in the long
run.
- a decline in employment in the communications sector of
17.5%, which was offset by increases in employment in other sectors
and a long run economy-wide gain of $3 per employee per week in
1995-96 prices.
Allowing for the limits of modelling of this type, there are
clearly significant benefits to the economy, businesses and consumers
from increased efficiencies in Telstra and the communications sector
generally. [59]
Clearly there are very real benefits for the community and the economy
as whole from improving Telstra's efficiency. Because of Telstra's importance
in the telecommunications sector and the significance of telecommunications
to other sectors, the benefits of efficiency gains in Telstra will permeate
virtually every area of economic and community activity.
Finding: Part privatisation will induce Telstra
to become more efficient, which will in turn improve the quality
and reduce the cost of telecommunications services, leading to significant
improvements in Australian economic activity. |
2.6.2 A boost to national savings and debt repayment
An additional national economic benefit comes from the use of the proceeds
of part privatisation to repay public sector debt. This is clearly a secondary
consideration to the benefits to the community and the economy associated
with efficiency gains in Telstra and the telecommunications sector, but
it is nevertheless important, and of course it is relevant to paragraph
(e) of the terms of reference, the
impact on public sector savings of the partial sale of Telstra.
The Department of Finance explained the economic benefits that will
follow:
The proceeds of the partial sale will provide the Government
with an opportunity to reduce the amount of Government debt which it
needs to service (with ongoing savings in debt service costs), and/or
to fund high priority tasks - such as the Natural Heritage Trust. Importantly,
lower debt levels - and correspondingly lower interest costs - reduce
the vulnerability of the Commonwealth to movements in interest rates.
It also improves the Government's capacity to pursue counter-cyclical
economic policy by varying levels of debt-funded expenditure at relevant
points in the economic cycle. [60]
The WA Chamber of Commerce and Industry addressed the same issue, drawing
attention to the constraints that high levels of public sector debt
place on the Government's ability to respond to real community needs
and the regressive and inequitable distribution effects of public debt.
Revenues from asset sales should be used only to reduce liabilities
or enhance the value of other public assets. Failure to do so by previous
governments has been a major cause of the run-down of net public assets
and accumulation of liabilities in Australia over recent years...
The level of Commonwealth Government debt has escalated dramatically
in recent years thanks to persistent deficits. According to the 1995-96
Budget papers, between June 1990 and June 1996 the level of debt was
estimated to more than treble from around $30 billion to nearly $100
billion. The interest bill alone on debt in the general government sector
was expected to be more than $10 billion in 1995-96, rather more than
defence spending and only a little less than the education budget. Had
the Government not borrowed so much over the early 1990s, the general
government sector would be nearly in surplus and the fiscal task facing
the new government would be one of prudent management rather than major
repairs to restore a structural deficit. [61]
During the course of the Inquiry, there was a good deal of controversy
about this issue of the effect of part-privatisation of Telstra on public
sector savings and on the Commonwealth Budget. It is therefore important
to get the position absolutely correctly understood, and for that reason
we closely questioned Mr Hutchinson of the Department of Finance when
he appeared before us for the second time. He made it clear that the
part privatisation will have a positive effect on the cash side of the
budget:
If we look at the situation over the last fully reported financial
year, 1994-95, the average interest rate paid on the Commonwealth's
stock of debt was around 9.4%. The dividend declared by Telstra was
$944 million. Of the sale proceeds of Telstra, $7 billion was to be
applied to the reduction of debt. So the dividend loss involved would
be one-third of the $944 million - that is, $315 million. The interest
cost on the debt repaid would have been $660 million, so the balancing
items in a cash sense are a $660 million reduction in interest payments
and $315 million in debt, a net saving to the cash side of the budget
of $345 million. [62]
He also pointed out that the sale of Telstra at its value in the Commonwealth's
notional balance sheet would make no difference to the notional capital
side of the budget. [63]
Finding: part privatisation of Telstra will provide
an increase in public sector savings by allowing the redemption
of $7 billion of public debt and removing a yearly interest bill
of around $660 million (ie $7 billion at 9.4% a year) while retaining
two thirds of Telstra dividends which last year totalled just under
$1 billion (out of a total Telstra contribution to Government by
way of taxes, interest and dividends of $2.5 billion). |
2.7 Part privatisation will benefit the supplier industry
The Inquiry was charged with considering the effect on the supplier
industry under paragraph (n) of the terms of reference:
(n) the extent to which the Bill and the post-1997 arrangements will
foster the development of Australian telecommunications services and
equipment industry, research and development, and the development
of new services.
We concluded, based on the evidence presented to the Inquiry, that:
- Telstra will continue to purchase equipment locally after part privatisation
- the present industry plan arrangements will continue
- based on the experience in New Zealand after privatisation of Telecom
New Zealand, the prospects for the local telecommunications supply
industry are encouraging.
Finding: The Telstra (Dilution of Public Ownership)
Bill 1996 and the post-1997 arrangements will stimulate the development
of the Australian telecommunications service and equipment industries.
|
2.7.1 Telstra will continue to purchase locally
We are satisfied from the evidence we have received on this point that
Telstra's role in industry development and fostering Australian suppliers
has little to do with its public ownership. Both Optus and Vodafone
are committed to industry plans by licence conditions. Under the industry
plans the carriers have been pursuing strategic alliances with efficient
and competitive Australian-based suppliers because it is in their interests
to do so. We have heard nothing to suggest that this will change.
The point is made most tellingly by the Australian Telecommunications
Industry Association, which is the peak industry association representing
local and international companies involved in the design, development
and production of telecommunications and associated products and systems.
[64] The Association commented as follows:
In brief the Association believes that on the basis of a continuation
of the present successful approach of recognising a close nexus between
communications and industry policy, the partial privatisation of Telstra
will not affect the Australian telecommunications industry. [65]
Telstra made clear to the Inquiry that it will continue to purchase
equipment from local suppliers, not out of any sense of patriotic duty
but because it is in Telstra's commercial interest to do so:
...For competitive purposes, Telstra has sought arrangements
with equipment suppliers and manufacturers. Telstra's partnership
with Australian telecommunications industry, formalised in the 5-year
Industry Development Plan, is important in meeting the company's strategic
objectives to move into new information and communications services.
Similarly, the links with Telstra may enable some supplier firms to
expand overseas and probably fosters greater innovation on their part.
Telstra does not regard its industry development role as solely
about developing local suppliers. Instead, local sourcing has a number
of practical and cost advantages for Telstra in terms of shorter supply
leadtimes are possible, reduced transport and handling costs because
of proximity to suppliers, and more timely and cost-effective after
sales service can be offered. These advantages cannot be ignored by
any company seeking efficiencies and productivity gains. Therefore,
Telstra expects that it will continue to seek out and encourage local
companies who can serve Telstra demand for telecommunications equipment
and components...
Telstra's commitment to the supply industry is demonstrated
by some key highlights of Telstra's Industry Plan (1994/95):
Telstra increased its spend on products and services in 1994/95
by $794 million to $4 252 million;
Telstra traded with more than 10 000 suppliers
- over 50 companies received orders of $10 million or more
(a 25% increase);
- over 1000 companies received orders of $400 000 or more;
Expenditure on Australian content increased by an average of
7 to 8% per annum over the past 3 years;
Over 65% of all purchases were sourced locally;
Australian based suppliers received orders of $224 million
for Telstra's off-shore;
$218 million was spent on research and development;
- Telstra's support for local telecommunications manufacturing
industry employs 13 000 Australians directly and a further 20 000
indirectly.
Telstra is proud of its investment record within the industry
and given the mutually advantageous nature of the arrangements, there
is little likelihood that the commercial incentives for local sourcing
would be diminished. [66]
A similar view was put by a representative of AAP Telecommunications:
Again, I speak as a practitioner. If we can buy from Australian
sources, it is absolutely our preferred approach. The greatest nightmare
is to buy from overseas sources and find that they do not have anybody
available locally... [67]
This position was supported by independent comments by investment bankers
BZW:
There is no reason to think privatisation will have a significant
effect on the development of the Australian telecommunications services
and equipment industry.
Telstra as a publicly owned company should be no more or less
benevolent than Telstra as a privately owned company to Australian
equipment manufacturers, but rather treat them on their merits. Industry
support arrangements including minimum local content rules should
be the same in both cases...
Possibly, improved efficiencies within Telstra may flow on
to a more efficient Australian telecommunications services and equipment
industry, increasing its prospects for competing with overseas companies.
BZW actively researches and advises investors on the merits of
two listed Australian equipment companies, AWA and ERG, which develop
and manufacture telecommunications services and equipment for the Australian
and overseas markets. Neither company would, in our view, be impacted
by a partial privatisation of Telstra. [68]
The Majority Report asserts that part privatisation will reduce Telstra's
local purchases. [69] In the light of
this substantial body of evidence to the contrary, that assertion looks
very hollow. We are satisfied that Telstra's purchases from local companies
will not be affected by part privatisation.
2.7.2 Industry plan arrangements will continue
We are advised that there will be no change to the current arrangement
for industry plans. Under that arrangement, Telstra and other licensed
telecommunications carriers are required by licence conditions to produce
industry development plans that outline the basis of commercially based
relationships with suppliers. This requirement is aimed at the promotion
of long term strategic relationships between carriers and suppliers. Those
plans have been responsible for encouraging the carriers to source approximately
70 per cent of their telecommunications equipment and software requirements
locally (averaging over $2.8 billion per annum from 1991-92 to 1996-97).
They have also been a factor behind assisting the telecommunications equipment
manufacturing industry to increase exports from $218 million to almost
$900 million per annum (approximately a 400 per cent increase) over the
first four years of the current industry development policies and in turn,
significantly improving the sector's export/import ratio. [70]
The Department of Communications and the Arts provided the Inquiry
with the following assurance about the continuation of industry development
arrangements:
The essential aim of sector-specific industry policy measures
after 1997 would be to provide a regulatory environment that actively
encourages the carriers, including those involved with broadband cable
networks, to continue to seek to maximise their involvement with the
domestic telecommunications supply industry on a commercial and competitive
basis and to form long-term strategic alliances that benefit all parties...
The scale and positive impact of existing carrier procurement
policies on the sustained growth and development of an internationally
competitive domestic telecommunications industry, and the wider economy
in general, argue for the continuation of sector specific policies.
In this way, a significantly larger proportion of carrier expenditure
might remain in the economy. Carriers' current annual purchases of local
equipment and services are approximately $4.5 billion. Expenditure levels
are expected to remain high in the next few years as carriers rollout
their cable networks (Foxtel and Optus Vision). Most importantly, the
local carrier market provides the base and market momentum from which
the local industry undertakes innovation, investment and, most critically,
exports. [71]
2.7.3 Lessons from New Zealand
There were comments made by some witnesses and members of the Committee
about the experience of the New Zealand telecommunications supply industry
following privatisation of TCNZ. These comments are picked up in the Majority
Report. [72] Many of these comments
were ill-informed or based on a partial assessment covering only the first
year or two following privatisation of TCNZ.
The facts are contained in the submission from the Department of Communications
and the Arts:
The experience of the New Zealand telecommunications electronics
industry post-privatisation of TCNZ provides some valuable insights
on the possible effect of privatisation for Australia's telecommunications
supply industry.
Prior to 1984 the New Zealand electronics industry was dominated
by screwdriver assembly operations - there were no exports.
After liberalisation of the New Zealand market the screwdriver
companies disappeared, but a few specialist electronics firms in niches
such as electric fences, mobile radios and medical electronics continued.
The industry has now regrouped and internationally competitive
and export oriented firms now operate in key niche markets, including
specialist telecommunications equipment. In 1990 exports of telecommunications
equipment totalled $NZ 43m. In the year to 30 June 1996 telecommunications
equipment exports are expected to total approximately $NZ 200m. Growth
in this market is now 30% pa. While growth is slowing in response to
appreciation of the NZ dollar exports are forecast to reach $NZ 400m
by the year 2000. [73]
Footnotes
[1] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7, p.
1294
[2] Business Council of Australia, Submission
No. 355, Vol 14, p 2768
[3] Official Hansard Report, 4 July,
p. 245
[4] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7, p.
1298
[5] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7, p.
1298
[6] Western Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, Submission No. 334, p. 2422
[7] Business Council of Australia, Submission
No. 355, Vol 14, p 2768
[8] Australian Consumers Association, Submission
No. 340, Vol 13, p 2516
[9] Official Hansard Report, 3 July
1996, p. 145
[10] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, p. 1271
[11] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p. 694
[12] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p. 695
[13] Service Providers Action Network, Submission
No. 313, Vol. 12, p. 2234
[14] Official Hansard Report, 3 July
1996, p. 108
[15] Australian Consumers Association, Submission
No. 340, Vol. 13, p. 2517.
[16] Official Hansard Report, 11 July
1996, p. 419
[17] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p.695
[18] Majority Report, para 3.26
[19] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, p. 1268
[20] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1300
[21] Telstra, Submission No. 366, Vol 15,
p. 2907
[22] Telstra, Submission No. 366, Vol 15,
p. 2922
[23] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, p. 1269
[24] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1308
[25] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, pp 1273-4
[26] Parker and Martin, The Impact
of UK Privatisation on Employment, Profits and the Distribution of Business
Income, Public Money and Management, Vol 16(1), January 1996,
p 38
[27] Business Council of Australia, Submission
No. 355, Vol 14, p 2768
[28] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1304
[29] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1301
[30] Western Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, Submission No. 334, p 2423
[31] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1305
[32] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1303
[33] Official Hansard Report, 12 July
1996, p. 447
[34] Official Hansard Report, 10 July,
p. 328
[35] Australian Telecommunications Industry
Association, Submission No. 194, Vol. 7, p. 1373.
[36] Majority Report, para 4.45
[37] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, p. 1268
[38] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p.699
[39] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1309
[40] Telstra, Submission No. 366, Vol 15,
p. 2907
[41] Official Hansard Report, 3 July
1996, p. 218
[42] Telstra, Submission No. 366, Vol 15,
p. 2097
[43] Telstra, Submission No. 366, Vol 15,
pp 2907-2917
[44] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1309
[45] Majority Report, para 1.11
[46] Official Hansard Report, 3 July
1996, p. 113
[47] Official Hansard Report, 4 July
1996, p. 241
[48] Official Hansard Report, 26 July
1996, p. 800
[49] Electronic Commerce Australia, Submission
No. 365, Vol. 15, p 2892
[50] Majority Report, para 4.38
[51] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, pp 1271-2
[52] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1299
[53] Western Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, Submission No. 334, p 2425
[54] Western Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, Submission No. 334, p. 2424
[55] Official Hansard Report, 10 July
1996, p. 364
[56] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1313
[57] Official Hansard Report, 26 July
1996, p. 796
[58] Econtech Report at Attachment B, Department
of Communications and the Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, pp 734-5
[59] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p. 697
[60] Department of Finance, Submission No.
188, Vol 7, p. 1273
[61] Western Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, Submission No. 334, Vol. 12, p 2430
[62] Official Hansard Report, 26 July
1996, p. 746
[63] Official Hansard Report, 26 July
1996, p. 746
[64] Australian Telecommunications Industry
Association, Submission No. 194, Vol. 7, p. 1372.
[65] Australian Telecommunications Industry
Association, Submission No. 194, Vol. 7, p. 1372.
[66] Telstra, Submission No. 189, Vol 7,
p. 1311
[67] Official Hansard Report, 12 July, p
481
[68] BZW Australia, Submission No. 295, Vol.
9, p. 1857
[69] Majority Report, para 4.97
[70] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p.723
[71] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p.724
[72] Majority Report, para 4.102
[73] Department of Communications and the
Arts, Submission No. 131, Vol. 4, p.725