PRIVATISATION-FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC CONSIDERATIONS

Consideration of the Telstra (Dilution of Public Ownership) Bill 1996
CONTENTS

CHAPTER 4

PRIVATISATION-FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC CONSIDERATIONS

There are significant economic and financial benefits from retaining Telstra in full public ownership. Expert economic evidence presented to the Committee suggested that the proposed sale would significantly reduce the net worth of the public sector. Moreover, international studies failed to establish a link between the proposed change to ownership and efficiency gains. The Committee considers that efficiency gains will flow under public ownership from ongoing technological advances, good management, effective regulation and competition. Finally, privatisation would have adverse impacts on Australia's telecommunications research and development effort and the development of our telecommunications equipment and services industry.

4.1 This Chapter focuses on the economic implications of privatisation. The Government has argued that partial privatisation should be pursued because this would result in efficiency gains, and because there is a current international trend towards the privatisation of telecommunications corporations. However, simply because a policy is widely adopted does not mean it is necessarily beneficial, socially or economically. Having examined the empirical evidence provided to it, the Committee remains unconvinced that efficiency gains will flow from the proposed change in ownership.

4.2 The Committee is concerned the Government has not given adequate consideration to the budgetary implications of the proposed sale. Expert evidence was provided which strongly suggested that the sale would result in a significant reduction in the net worth of the public sector.

4.3 Finally, the Committee is gravely concerned about the likely impacts of privatisation on employment levels, particularly in rural and regional Australia. This would be exacerbated by the potentially detrimental impacts of privatisation on the future of the Australian telecommunications equipment industry and on Australia's research and development capacity.

 

The World Bank position

4.4 Submissions in favour of partial privatisation of Telstra relied heavily on a World Bank report published in 1992 entitled Privatization: The Lessons of Experience, by Sunita Kikeri, John Nellis and Mary Shirley. These submissions included:

4.5 The Department of Communications and the Arts referred to the World Bank report as 'perhaps the most compelling overall review of the effects of privatisation and its relationship with liberalisation'. [5] In its supplementary submission, the Department noted that:

4.6 The Department of Finance also placed great significance on this report, referring to it as a 'major study' and quoting at length from the authors' conclusions [7]. In addition, Telstra's submission relies on this report in support of its submission that a change of ownership is necessary—'that privatisation related efficiencies can[not] be achieved by corporatisation [alone]'. [8]

4.7 Contrary to assertions made in many of the submissions supporting privatisation of Telstra, the 1992 World Bank report is not an empirical analysis of the benefits of privatisation. As acknowledged in a 1994 World Bank publication by Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, it is a description and assessment of privatisation policies rather than an analysis of what happened, why it happened, and what it was worth. [9] Parts of the 1992 report summarise the outcomes of another World Bank study, the study which is discussed in the 1994 report by Galal et al. Other parts of the report are little more than a series of assertions.

4.8 One part of the report discusses 'recent trends [that] show that close to 7,000 enterprises have been privatised worldwide since the early 1980s.' [10] The report does not analyse the circumstances of each of these privatisations in any detail. It does not even list all of the enterprises which were privatised or each of the industries in which privatisation occurred.

4.9 The Committee notes that of the 6 800-plus sales referred to in Chapter 2 of the report, 4 500 were in the former German Democratic Republic over the period of 18 months prior to the report. [11]

4.10 The Committee also notes that 6 100 of the privatisations referred to in Chapter 2 of the report occurred in Eastern Europe, Latin America and the Caribbean. Just 170 of the privatisations occurred in OECD countries. The Committee agrees with the Communications Law Centre that:

4.11 As the Communications Law Centre noted, the overwhelming majority of the cases referred to in this part of the Study are in countries which were undergoing complete revolutions in the way their economies and societies were organised, a far cry from Australia's position. [13]

4.12 In another part of the report, the authors summarise the outcomes of World Bank research into the welfare consequences of the privatisation of twelve firms in Chile, Malaysia, Mexico and the United Kingdom. The cases cover telecommunications (three firms), airlines (four firms), electricity (two firms), a lottery company, a port and a transport company. [14] A number of the submissions in favour of privatisation, including that of the Department of Finance, referred to this short summary rather than the far more detailed report of the twelve case studies published in 1994. [15] Other submissions selectively quoted from the summary in some places and the more detailed report in others.

4.13 The Committee obtained the World Bank's detailed empirical analysis published in 1994, over 600 pages long, and compared that analysis with the short summary in the 1992 paper by Kikeri et al. Whilst the brief summary of the case studies in the 1992 paper caused Committee members to have serious doubts about their relevance to the proposed privatisation of Telstra, a close study of the methodology, analysis of the cases and synthesis in the 1994 report confirmed that this work had little relevance to the question of whether Telstra should be privatised.

4.14 The authors of the 1994 report themselves cautioned that:

4.15 As Professor Quiggin noted in his supplementary submission, most of the analysis dealt with privatisation in less developed countries where state-owned enterprises had been chronically unprofitable. [17] The only major example of an OECD privatisation that was considered was British Telecom.

4.16 The principal reason for privatisation offered by Kikeri et al was:

The Committee believes that these comments do not apply to Telstra.

4.17 The Committee accepts the view of the Communications Law Centre that `the Study's findings on key points do not always support the stated conclusions in favour of privatisation of Telstra.' [19] In particular, the Committee notes the following comments in the summary by Kikeri et al:

4.18 The 1994 report notes: 'divestiture can induce changes in market structures, and the results of these can be positive or negative.' [21]

4.19 The Committee notes that, whilst the World Bank takes a favourable view of the outcomes of the sale of British Telecom, it is forced to concede that, '…not much changes as a result of divestiture', that 'the main winners were private buyers who paid £3,750 million (£1.19 per share) for stock worth about £7,470 million (£2.85 per share)' that 'the average residential consumer is quite possibly a net loser from divestiture', and that there was a significant decline in quality of service for several years following divestiture, which was only remedied by the reimposition of regulation. [22]

4.20 Referring to the sale of the Chilean telecommunications carrier, Compañia de Telefonos de Chile, the World Bank again noted that divestiture caused a decline in quality of service:

4.21 The 1994 report concluded that privatisation of the Mexican telecommunications carrier, Telefonos de Mexico, resulted in losses to consumers amounting to $ Mex92 trillion ($ US33 billion). [24] This was because metered calls increased by 620 per cent as a result of a deliberate act by the Mexican Government in the year leading up to the privatisation to enhance the value of the company:

4.22 The report concluded that five of the 12 cases resulted in overall losses to consumers, and in three cases these losses were substantial. [26]

4.23 As the Communications Law Centre noted in its submission, the World Bank repeatedly asserts that 'ownership matters' but, in fact, the case studies highlight the importance of other factors in achieving sound policy outcomes. [27] As the 1992 report noted:

The 1994 report reinforces this, saying:

4.24 The Committee notes that when the Department of Communications and the Arts was asked to provide empirical evidence of the benefits of privatisation separated out from the effects of competition, the Department conceded that:

4.25 The only two cases to which the Department was able to refer the Committee were two privatisations referred to in the 1994 World Bank study. Neither of these privatisations involved a telecommunications carrier. The first example which the Department provided was the example of ENERSIS, a Santiago electricity distribution company. The Committee considers that this case study is of minimal relevance to the proposed privatisation of Telstra because ENERSIS is a monopolist operating in an entirely different market setting to that in which Telstra carries out business. ENERSIS was privatised during the period of the Pinochet dictatorship. Further, one of the main welfare gains noted in the World Bank's study of ENERSIS was a reduction in losses from theft and unbilled use. The Committee received no evidence that Telstra suffered from inefficiencies of this nature.

4.26 The second example offered by the Department was another Chilean company, CHILGENER. CHILGENER was an electricity generating enterprise which was privatised in 1987. The Committee's comments in the previous paragraph about the irrelevance of the Chilean market setting apply equally to this example. The Committee notes that the World Bank study arbitrarily attributed just 1.5 per cent out of a total 6.5 per cent productivity increase to a change in ownership. The Committee considers that such a modest productivity increase in the case of a privatisation occurring in circumstances wholly different to Telstra's operating environment provides very little justification for privatising Australia's second largest company.

4.27 In conclusion, the Committee considers that both the 1992 World Bank report and the more detailed 1994 report fall a very long way short of a ringing endorsement of the arguments being mounted in favour of the privatisation of Telstra. Given the apparent lack of relevant empirical analysis, the Committee considers the following observations by the Communications Law Centre to be apt:

Other empirical studies

4.28 Apart from the World Bank report, submissions in support of privatisation of Telstra relied on just two studies, published as:

4.29 The study by Megginson, Nash and van Randenborgh was relied on by both the Department of Communications and the Arts and Telstra. Only Telstra relied on the study by Donaldson.

4.30 The Committee considers that the study by Megginson, Nash and van Randenborgh is of little relevance to the proposed privatisation of Telstra. As the Department of Communications and the Arts conceded in its supplementary submission, the study does not attempt to separate out the alleged welfare gains from privatisation from welfare gains resulting from competition. [35]

4.31 The Donaldson study appears to the Committee to be even less relevant. That study, also carried out for the World Bank, is no more than a cursory look at a large number of privatisations. The case studies include:

4.32 Telstra did not attempt to explain the relevance of these case studies to the proposed sale of one third of its shares. The Committee rejects Telstra's description of the study as 'a major recent study which focussed on the performance of seven international telcos'.

 

The British Telecom example

4.33 Many advocates of the privatisation of Telstra point to the example of the privatisation of British Telecom as an example of a privatisation of a telecommunications carrier in an industrialised nation that produced benefits to consumers. These people often refer to a document entitled, Pricing of Telecommunications Services From 1997, [36] published by Oftel, the British regulator, in support of the proposition that privatisation has resulted in lower prices. The Oftel document notes that since 1984, the year the first 51 per cent of the shares in British Telecom were sold to the public, prices have decreased by 40 per cent. [37]

4.34 The Committee considers that such comparisons are misleading for several reasons.

4.35 The Public Sector Research Centre at the University of New South Wales referred in its submission to a report of the National Consumer Council in the United Kingdom which reported that:

The same report noted:

4.36 The Committee notes that these statements are consistent with the conclusion of the 1994 World Bank report, referred to earlier in this chapter, that:

4.37 The Committee concludes that the evidence of benefits to consumers as a result of the privatisation of British Telecom is far from compelling. The Committee concurs with the comments of the Communications Law Centre:

The dangers of privatising a monopoly

4.38 There is little doubt that Telstra has a very high degree of market power in many markets. The Minister has referred to Telstra as 'the Australian equivalent of the 600 pound gorilla.' [44] This market power appears to the Committee to be a significant feature the proposed privatisation, yet very little consideration was given in any of the submissions in favour of privatisation to this fact. No witness gave any evidence to suggest that Telstra's market dominance would disappear in the foreseeable future. The Committee notes that BZW Australia is of the view that new carriers after July 1997 and the larger service providers will obtain increases in market share graduallyin the order of 5-10% of the corporate, business, long distance and international markets over five years. Telstra's own growth is likely to continue to exceed that of these players in aggregate. [45]

4.39 As the 1994 World Bank report notes, in competitive industries privatisations are likely to result in small welfare gains. But in monopoly industries welfare gains are more variable, with large gains possible but also the possibility of large negative outcomes. [46] The World Bank report cautioned that a key feature of privatisation of monopolies was what they termed the 'fundamental trade-off' of divestiture: that against any efficiency improvements must be weighed the possibility of increased exercise of monopoly power.

4.40 These cautions against privatising monopolies are echoed in the Hilmer Report on National Competition Policy. [47] The Hilmer Report noted that privatisation is less likely to offer significant public benefit if appropriate structural reforms are not carried out before or concomitant with the privatisation, possibly entrenching the monopolistic structure of the industry. [48] The Government may argue that it is in fact undertaking appropriate structural reforms prior to the sale. However, as the Committee has not yet seen the Government's package of legislation to operate from 1 July 1997, it is not in a position to judge whether that is correct. As discussed in Chapters 2 and 8, the Minister's May 1996 Discussion Paper on Post 1997 Telecommunications Legislation shows there is still considerable uncertainty on a range of important issues.

4.41 The Committee considers the following observations of the Hilmer Committee to be of particular significance to the current Inquiry:

Efficiency of public enterprises

4.42 In light of the evidence examined above, the Committee rejects the assertion that there is a direct and inevitable link between economic performance and type of ownership. This is reinforced by the fact that the performance and efficiency of Government owned enterprises can and has been extensively improved under public ownership. The significant efficiency improvements attained by Telstra to date were outlined in Chapter 3.

4.43 The Committee further notes that the former Economic Planning Advisory Council (EPAC) found that in the twelve years up to 1990-91, the annual average growth in total factor productivity for all Australian government business enterprises was 4.1 per cent compared with only 0.2 per cent for the private sector. In the communications sector of the total factor productivity of government business enterprises, TFP rose by 18.9 per cent between 1991-92 and 1992-93. [50]

 

Beneficiaries of privatisation

4.44 The Committee is of the view that the beneficiaries of a partial privatisation of Telstra would be a few private individuals, and not the people of Australia who are the current beneficiaries. While the Government argues that the 'broader Australian community' will be able to buy shares in Telstra [51], the Committee notes that only 18 per cent of Australians own any shares and that the majority of shareowners reside in the three eastern states of New South Wales, Victoria and Queensland. This localised, and metropolitan, minority will be one of the beneficiaries of the proposed Telstra sale.

4.45 The Committee concludes that the financial losers will be the people of Australia who will no longer own a valuable public asset, and will no longer benefit from the considerable flow of profits from the asset.

4.46 It is commonly accepted that remuneration for senior executives is higher in the private than the public sector, and that top executives have done substantially better with salary packages as public utilities are privatised. Professor Quiggin noted:

4.47 This same point was made strongly by the Public Sector Research Centre:

4.48 It was noted in Chapter 3 that the Chief Executive Officer of Telstra already receives more than $ 1.2 million pa in salary as well as additional bonuses.

4.49 In conclusion, the Committee is concerned that efficiency will be measured almost exclusively in terms of the number of jobs that can be removed and that this will be accompanied by steep rises in terms of the salaries of senior management. The Committee notes that even if efficiency gains are made under private ownership, there is no reason to assume that the benefits of such gains would be passed on to consumers in the form of lower prices. Nor does the public have any assurance that such gains will be reinvested into the enterprise for the purposes of job creation or fostering research and development. As Telstra possesses a strong degree of market power, competitive pressures will not be sufficient to ensure an optimal outcome.

Employee share ownership

4.50 Proponents of privatisation emphasise the opportunity this provides for Telstra staff to own shares in the corporation. It is argued this will foster a higher level of performance and efficiency. However, the employees of Telstra, along with the Australian public, already "own" shares in the company. The Committee notes further that when British Telecom was privatised, all workers were issued a small number of shares. Because the float was drastically underpriced, the value of the shares increased markedly on the first day of the privatisation. Workers were able to sell their shares at a profit, completely destroying the purpose of issuing them to employees. On the other hand, senior executives are often given very large parcels of shares at such times and can afford to hold on to them, making large profits, free of capital gains tax until the time of sale.

 

Impact of privatisation on the net worth of the public sector

4.51 Aside from a belief that private enterprise is inherently more efficient, the sale is being driven by the fact that it provides an immediate source of revenue for the Government.

4.52 The Government has stated the attainable sale price to be $24 billion, [54] which means that a third of Telstra would sell for $ 8 billion. [55] (Refer Table 4.1). The Government has claimed it will use $7 billion of the revenue it expects to generate from the sale to reduce its net debt, thereby saving money on interest repayments. The remaining $ 1 billion of the sale revenue is to fund environment programs.

Table 4.1 Estimated value of Telstra Corporation

a. Attainable sale price

Value Date Reference
less than $20 billion 1993 based on Fightback policy estimates
$24 billion 1996 Government figure [56]
$28 billion 1996 BZW Australia [57]
extra $5 billion if float delayed and regulatory risk lowered Prof. J. Quiggin [58]
less ? $billion as a result of foreign ownership restrictions Prof. J. Quiggin [59]

b. Value if kept in public ownership

Value Date Reference
$54 billion 1996 Prof. J. Quiggin [60]

 

4.53 The Committee rejects the view that this proposed expenditure constitutes a justification for turning an enormously profitable public enterprise into Australia's second biggest private corporation capable of wielding tremendous market power.

4.54 Telstra currently returns significant dividends to the public sector and the Committee notes that no persuasive evidence was put to it suggesting that this would not continue into the foreseeable future. If anything Telstra's profitability is expected to continue growing. In the 1994/95 financial year, Telstra provided $944 million in dividends to the Government. This was an increase from $738 million in the previous financial year. Together with interest and taxes the Commonwealth Government received $2.732 billion from Telstra in 1994/95. With record profits foreshadowed in the press for the 1995/96 financial year, returns are expected to increase.

4.55 The Committee notes that Telstra, contrary to the majority of cases in the World Bank report referred to earlier, is not a burden on the Budget. No impetus for divestiture of Telstra can therefore be derived from the argument that this would ease any burden on taxpayers. Far from being a burden, public ownership of Telstra is returning a healthy dividend to the Government. The Government is able to utilise these funds, which are returned to consolidated revenue, to fund expenditure programs or repay interest or capital on existing public sector debt. The Community and Public Sector Union argued on this basis that Telstra should be retained in public ownership:

4.56 If, after selling a portion of Telstra as proposed, the Government is able to reduce the stream of future interest payments on the debt by the same amount as the income flow from Telstra which would have been used to pay the interest on the debt, then the net worth of the public sector would remain unaltered. The level of public debt would fall, but so would the value of public assets.

4.57 However, expert evidence was provided to the Committee which strongly suggests the proposed sale will result in a reduction of the Government's net worth. This would occur if the interest saving in public debt from selling Telstra is less than the future profit stream foregone. Professor John Quiggin and Dr Allan Brown, who submitted detailed studies to the Committee, argued this point. [62]

4.58 In his submission to the Senate Telstra Inquiry, Professor Quiggin estimates that the value of Telstra in public ownership is $ 54.4 billion. This estimate is based on Telstra's after-tax profits and comparing these with the net sale proceeds that would be required to generate similar savings in public debt interest (Refer Table 4.1). According to Professor Quiggin:

4.59 A fundamental error occasionally made by analysts attempting to estimate the value of public assets is that they focus attention on the flow of dividends remitted to the Budget sector, rather than on the flow of profits. In doing so, retained earnings which are reinvested in the enterprise are ignored. Professor Quiggin argues that this error was made by the Department of Finance:

4.60 According to Professor Quiggin, while the Department of Finance acknowledges that retained earnings will increase the value of Telstra, they do not take into account this cost when computing the loss of income associated with the share that is sold. He further argues that once the error of comparing interest flows with dividends, rather than profits, is corrected, the Department's own analysis would show a loss arising from the partial sale of Telstra:

4.61 The Committee is concerned that the Government has given insufficient consideration to the impact of the proposed sale on the net worth of the public sector. The attractiveness of the transaction depends on the full value of relative returns earned by the Government from its continued public ownership, relative to the cash flows avoided by reducing public debt interest commitments. On the basis of the evidence provided, the Committee feels there is significant cause for concern that the proposed sale will significantly reduce the net worth of the public sector.

Telstra sale revenue to fund environment programs

4.62 The Government has announced that it plans to allocate $1 billion, of the expected $8 billion in revenue from the sale, to the Natural Heritage Trust of Australia. [66] This Trust was outlined in the Coalition's policy document, "Saving our Natural Heritage", issued prior to the 1996 election, and further detailed in the Financial Impact Statement of the Telstra (Dilution of Public Ownership) Bill 1996, and of the National Heritage Trust of Australia Bill 1996.

4.63 In accordance with the provisions of the Bill, five environment "projects" (including research, policy and audit) would be funded over the five-year period 1996-97 to 2000-01, at a cost of $ 700 million (or an average of $ 140 million pa). [67] It is the belief of the Committee that these programs, which were already in place under the previous government, and are not capital expenditure projects, should be funded from general revenue and not from asset sales.

4.64 The remaining $300 million of the Trust would be invested in the year 2001, and interest would be used for environmental and natural resource management projects. Interest, after inflation, would amount to between $10 million to $ 18 million pa. [68] The Committee considers this is a poor return to the Australian public compared to the $112 million pa that a $1 billion dollar "share" of Telstra currently returns to the Government. [69]

4.65 The Committee views the Government's attempt to link the sale with funding of their environment policy highly critically. The question of whether the proposed environmental package is desirable or affordable is independent of the partial sale of Telstra. Indeed, if analyses like those of Professor Quiggin and Dr Brown (referred to above) are correct, the Government will actually be less able to afford environment funding if it does sell part of Telstra:

4.66 The Committee is concerned that the broad Australian community is being misled into believing the Government will not be able to afford to meet its election commitments on the environment if it does not sell part of Telstra. However, evidence was received by the Committee pointing out that even if the sale of Telstra were profitable, earmarking revenue from the proposed sale for the proposed environment programs represents a potentially undesirable development in public policy. Professor Quiggin stated that:

4.67 The Committee firmly believes that the environment, like any other portfolio, deserves to be funded in its own right from consolidated revenue, and should not be made conditional upon exogenous policy developments, such as the partial sale of Telstra. The Committee is concerned that the sale of Telstra will reduce the public sector's net worth, and thereby reduce the Government's capacity to pay for projects of national significance, such as environmental preservation.

RECOMMENDATION 5: The Committee recommends the environment programs of the Government be funded from recurrent expenditure or a proportion of Telstra's profits, not from the partial sale of Telstra.

 

Foreign investment

4.68 The Committee agreed that it was undesirable to have Australia's national telecommunications carrier under foreign control and recognised the need to restrict foreign ownership. Ownership limits are found in Divisions 4-7 of the proposed new Part 2A of the Telstra Act. The Bill proposes that 35 per cent of the one-third share issue in Telstra can be held by foreign investors. The 35 per cent is further diluted by a restriction that an individual foreign investor is limited to 5 per cent of the one-third. Overall, this means that foreign investment is limited, at present, to 11.666 per cent of Telstra as a whole.

4.69 Two issues are of relevance here. Aggregate and individual foreign ownership of Telstra is below the foreign investment notifications limits, so foreign investors can simply acquire the publicly listed shares up to the permitted levels. Individual foreign ownership is limited to 1.666 per cent (5 per cent of one third) of Telstra and therefore well below the limit required for notification to the company of significant individual shareholding in a publicly listed company (the threshold figure for a 'substantial interest' requiring notification is 5 per cent). [72]

4.70 The Bill allows for 35 per cent of one-third of the Telstra shares to be bought by foreign nationals. There was concern that this control would be unmanageable. Various mechanisms can be deployed by investors to circumvent foreign ownership restrictions. The Communications, Electrical and Plumbing Union noted in its submission that in the case of Qantas, which has a nominal 49 per cent foreign shareholding ceiling, foreign funds have used derivatives created by local financial institutions to circumvent the restrictions. [73]

4.71 The telecommunications industry, as a result of market deregulation and competition, is increasingly being penetrated by foreign competitors. Optus Communications is at least 49 per cent foreign owned, and Optus Vision at least 47.5 per cent. [74] Vodafone is 95 per cent owned by the United Kingdom company, Vodafone plc, (although it does have a licence condition to achieve majority Australian ownership by 1 July 2003). There was concern by the Committee, which reflected that widely held by the community, that Telstra, if privatised, would follow this route.

4.72 Pressure for foreign ownership restrictions to be assessed for the industry as a whole, and not in a piecemeal fashion, with different conditions applying to each carrier, will continue to mount. In its submission, Vodafone argued:

4.73 The Committee noted that it would be very difficult for the Government to retain the proposed foreign ownership restrictions for a fully or largely privatised Telstra if the same restrictions are not imposed on its competitors. The Committee is also aware it is extremely unlikely that such onerous foreign ownership restrictions will be imposed on all carriers and service providers in the post 1997 environment.

4.74 Further pressure to increase the level of foreign ownership will arise from a recognition of the limited scale of domestic sharemarket funds. A higher sale price would therefore be attainable by allowing increased foreign ownership. Although the Government has announced it will not pursue this option at present, there will be tremendous pressure to do so in the lead up to a further dilution of ownership.

4.75 In the end, Australia is likely to find itself with largely foreign owned and controlled telecommunications carriers. This will have a serious impact on the viability of domestic research and product development and procurement activities which are vitally important to the ongoing development of Australia's telecommunications industry. Moreover, concern was raised that if Telstra were taken over by a foreign based transnational telecommunications company, this could result in great pressure from the company to keep Telstra from expanding into Asian markets and competing against it. The Public Sector Research Centre noted:

4.76 Another concern of the Committee is that foreign investment results in dividend payments to shareholders that are repatriated, and this outflow of Telstra's profits impacts on Australia's current account deficit. [77]

4.77 The Committee is unable to form an opinion on the part of term of reference (m) which deals with whether investment restrictions take account of regulation and monitoring of financial transactions and currency flows, as insufficient evidence was presented to the inquiry on this issue.

4.78 The Committee concludes that, in the long run, it is likely the foreign ownership restrictions will prove ineffective. A combination of the desire for extra revenue, rationalised by the need for uniformity across the industry, will eventually drive the Government down the path of easing foreign ownership restrictions.

 

Financial considerations - the float

Timing of float

4.79 All witnesses, irrespective of whether they were for or against privatisation, recognised the fundamental importance of establishing the post 1997 regulatory framework before the float proceeded. For example, the merchant bank, BZW Australia, emphasised the need to clearly define the new regulatory environment before potential shareholders are asked to risk capital in buying Telstra shares. [78] According to Professor Quiggin:

All witnesses who commented on this issue agreed that to do so would result in a lower sale price than could be attained if the Government had waited. The ultimate cost would be borne by the Australian public (Refer Table 4.1).

4.80 The Government's haste to sell Telstra means that long-term investment decisions within the Corporation are being compromised by pressure for short term returns that may appear attractive to investors in the prospectus. The Gungahlin Broadband project, which was to have been piloted in the ACT, appears to have been put on hold for this reason. [80]

4.81 The Committee concludes that the Government has an unworkable timetable with regard to the float, based on 'wishful thinking'. Even if the Bill were passed by the Senate, preparation of the prospectus and due process of public scrutiny would mean that the float could not be as soon as the Government proposed.

4.82 It is very unlikely that the sale could be completed by 30 June 1997, the original commitment by the Government. [81] Department of Finance pre-election estimates, provided in response to a recent question on notice to Senator Tierney, suggest that two-thirds of the sale proceeds will be received by 30 June 1997 and the remaining one-third by 30 June 1998.

4.83 These pre-election estimates are unrealistic. It now seems unlikely that the full proceeds of the float will be available until the 1998/99 financial year. This means that the full proceeds may not be available in this term of the Parliament—and this also means that the related environment package may not be funded in the present term of Government.

Cost of float and other privatisation costs

4.84 The Committee is concerned at the likely high transaction costs of the privatisation. The Department of Finance admitted to the figure of $160 million, at 1996 costs, at a Canberra hearing early in the inquiry:

If the sale were delayed beyond present plans, the cost would be higher as it would be if one-third of Telstra were sold in extra instalments. Of course, the cost to privatise all of Telstra would be at least three times higher or more than half a billion dollars by then.

4.85 These costs include preparation of the prospectus and share registry management. However it is unlikely that the huge cost of redundancy pay-outs, to reduce Telstra's workforce prior to privatisation, as Senator Colston pointed out, has been included. [83] The Committee considered this an important omission from Telstra's evidence. A rough estimate of redundancy pay and superannuation payouts for 30 000 retrenched workers, at an average of $40 000 each, comes to $1.2 billion.

 

Industry development and research

Telecommunications equipment industry

4.86 One of the Committee's major concerns about the proposed privatisation relates to its likely adverse effects on the telecommunications equipment industry in Australia. Telstra stands at the heart of the Australian electronics industry — an industry which, over the last decade, has massively improved on its export performance and likewise on its import replacement performance.

4.87 A wide range of telecommunications equipment is currently produced in Australia. Major categories of locally-produced equipment include:

4.88 The Allen Consulting Group calculated that in 1991 the Australian telecommunications equipment industry would produce $2.8 billion worth of equipment including $250 million for export markets. By 1993, the industry's sales in local and export markets were estimated at $3.2 billion and employment was estimated at 11 000 people.

4.89 Australian equipment suppliers fall into four main groups on the basis of ownership and revenue:

4.90 Exports of telecommunications equipment have increased rapidly in recent years. The Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics noted that data prepared by the Australian Electrical and Electronic Manufacturers' Association showed that exports rose from $80 million in 1989 to $360 million in 1992 and $550 million in 1993. Australian Bureau of Statistics figures show a rise in exports of telecommunications equipment from $287 million in 1991-92 to $483 million in 1992-93 and $643 million in 1993-94. [84]

4.91 The Committee notes the achievement of export sales by Australian telecommunications equipment manufacturers has been achieved in a number of ways including:

4.92 A range of telecommunications equipment is exported from Australia to a variety of regional markets of which Asia is the largest. Australian Bureau of Statistics data indicate that the largest individual country markets in 1993-94 were China (7 per cent of equipment exports), Hong Kong (5 per cent), the United States (3 per cent) and Sri Lanka (3 per cent). Major exports include:

4.93 While the equipment industry's growth and export capabilities are impressive, they are heavily dependent on the carriers and in particular Telstra. Telstra is committed, under its 1992 Industry Development Plan, to spending $10 billion on information technology and telecommunications equipment and services in the five years to 1997. [86] On 1 July 1994 Telstra commenced its Future Mode of Operations (FMO) project, a six year plan designed to achieve full network digitisation at a cost of $3.3 billion. Major equipment suppliers are Alcatel, Ericsson and Siemens. The factories of both Ericsson and Alcatel are working 24 hours a day to keep up with the FMO project's demands. [87] The Committee received evidence that Alcatel is receiving $1.1 billion from this project, while Ericsson is receiving $850 million and Siemens is receiving $500 million.

4.94 In a study of the Australian telecommunication commercial and regulatory environment, CIRCIT concluded:

4.95 The Committee believes that privatisation of Telstra will rapidly erode the equipment industry's achievements. It is proposed that under the post 1997 telecommunications legislation, carriers will continue to be subject to industry development obligations. Many witnesses who supported privatisation made much of this fact, suggesting that this means that industry development arrangements will remain unchanged if Telstra is privatised. These arguments overlook the nature of the carriers' 'obligations' under industry development plans.

4.96 The carriers' industry development 'obligations' derive from clause 14 of the Telecommunications (General Telecommunications Licences) Declaration (No 1) of 1991. That clause provides that a carrier must maintain and implement a plan for the development of the Australian supply and information industries in conjunction with its business and that these plans must be submitted to the Minister (Cl. 14.2). Carriers must also report to the Minister each year on progress made in implementing their plans (Cl 14.6). A carrier 'must have due regard to any views of the Government expressed to it by the Minister on its progress in implementing the plan' and must 'notify the Minister promptly of any action it takes, or proposes to take, in response to those views' (clauses 14.7 and 14.8). That is the extent of a carrier's industry development obligations.

4.97 Committee members were very concerned that the Declaration does not give rise to any enforceable obligation to purchase a specified percentage of Australian content and is little more than a 'best endeavour' requirement. However, Committee members noted that if the Australian Parliament attempted to impose more binding legislative requirements on carriers, it would run foul of the entire movement of world liberalisation of trade over the last decade or so. It could not impose such requirements without earning massive retaliation.

4.98 The Australian telecommunications equipment industry currently relies on an understanding by the directors and management of Telstra that the Government expects Telstra will acquire the bulk of its equipment and services domestically. If Telstra is privatised, its sole focus will be upon achieving its equipment requirements from the cheapest possible source. It will have no alternative, given the legal obligation of the directors of the company to have as their primary consideration the goal of optimising the value of the operations to their shareholders.

4.99 The Committee considers that it is worth reflecting on what has happened to the New Zealand equipment industry since Telecom New Zealand was privatised. That industry has withered away. Alcatel and Ericsson are now the only two telecommunications manufacturers with substantial operations in New Zealand. GEC, Philips and Mitel have gone. The Committee heard evidence that according to Statistics New Zealand, exports of telecommunications equipment fell from $ 6.6 million in December 1988 to $ 5.4 million in December 1992. Network equipment imports increased dramatically from $ 179 million in 1988 to $ 274 million in 1990. [89]

4.100 The Committee concludes that the only means of guaranteeing that Telstra will remain committed to the local equipment industry is for Telstra to remain in full public ownership.

RECOMMENDATION 6: The Committee recommends the continuation of the current industry development arrangements, noting the importance of sustaining an export oriented manufacturing sector to offset imports of telecommunications technologies. The Committee notes the likelihood that the that the value of such arrangements will be substantially eroded if Telstra is privatised.

RECOMMENDATION 7: The Committee recommends the Telecommunications Industry Development Authority be retained and its monitoring arrangements be strengthened.

 

Research and Development in the communications industry

4.101 Australia is a highly sophisticated and intensive user of communications and computing products. By and large, however, Australia has not been a major producer or exporter of such hardware. Exports of computing and telecommunications equipment increased 29 per cent between 1985-86 and 1995-95. Yet, by 1994-95, exports amounted to only about one-sixth of imports and the trade deficit in these products was about $7 million [90] The components in the HFC (Hybrid Optical Fibre Coaxial) cables currently being rolled out by both Telstra and Optus, for example, are largely provided from overseas.

4.102 Australia must develop internationally competitive industries to reduce our excessive dependence on commodity exports and counter the impact which increased import penetration of manufactured goods is having on the level of employment and on our current account. While the terms of trade in agriculture and mineral exports have effectively stagnated, in manufacturing they have risen solidly over the last few decades.

4.103 The Committee is of the view that the key to creating competitiveness lies in innovation, not in reducing wages and labour standards. Research and development plays a critical role in the innovation process and in underpinning the competitiveness and export capacity of firms:

4.104 The importance of R&D in the telecommunications industry is furthered by ever shortening product life-cycles.

4.105 Policies of the Australian Government over the last decade, such as the introduction of the 150 per cent tax concession, generated one of the fastest OECD growth rates in the level of business investment in R&D as a share of Gross Domestic Product. Yet, despite such impressive gains, by international standards Australia retains one of the lowest levels of business expenditure on R&D in the OECD. In 1992, Australia's ratio of business expenditure on research and development to gross domestic product was 0.7 per cent compared to an OECD average of 1.2 per cent. The top ranking countries, Sweden, Japan, United States, Switzerland and Germany had significantly higher ratios (2.1, 2.1, 2, 1.9 and 1.7 per cent respectively). [92]

4.106 The Committee notes with concern that in the 1995-96 Budget, the Government has announced a steep decline in assistance for business R&D, including scaling back of the 150 per cent tax concession to a rate of 125 per cent. The Committee is concerned this measure will reduce Australia's appeal as an R&D investment location in the Asia-Pacific region. At the same time, Australia's competitors are vigorously promoting investment in research as a means of building knowledge-based economies. Both Malaysia and Singapore, for example, offer a top rate of concession of 200 per cent. New Zealand, by contrast, which offers a 100 per cent concession languishes in the R&D stakes, with business spending at only 0.29 per cent of GDP on research in 1992.

4.107 The Committee is therefore concerned about the Government's commitment to improving Australian industry's research capacity. Moreover, the Committee is particularly concerned that the Government has not given sufficient consideration, if any, to the impacts which privatisation of Telstra would have on the overall research capacity of the domestic telecommunications industry.

Telstra Research Laboratories (TRL)

4.108 TRL is Australia's leading telecommunications research and engineering centre and the largest telecommunications research facility in the Southern hemisphere.

4.109 The central role performed by TRL extends beyond the production of world class research:

4.110 The Telstra Product Development Fund is designed to financially support entrepreneurs and inventors in design and development of innovative products which have the potential to advance Australia's telecommunications. The Fund has been integral to the development of a number of new technologies.

4.111 TRL represents Australia at international telecommunications standards meetings, which ensures that Australia's networks are built to world standards and that there is sufficient interconnect capacity. [95] They have formed and are in involved in cooperative research efforts with many Australian universities, such as the University of Melbourne, the Australian National University and the University of Sydney, and have provided equipment to universities such as La Trobe University.

4.112 TRL is instrumental in developing uniquely Australian technologies to enable our communications infrastructure to meet the needs of the entire continent, including rural and remote Australia. Some examples of the outcomes of such research which were provided to the Committee include:

4.113 The Committee noted the evidence of expert witnesses demonstrating that TRL is a national asset of importance which performs a significant role in developing Australia's high technology infrastructure and in nurturing Australia's future telecommunications researchers.

Impacts of privatisation on the Telstra Research Laboratories (TRL)

4.114 According to a study conducted by Coopers & Lybrand, Telstra was ranked the largest corporate investor in R&D in Australia in absolute terms. [98] Telstra's total commitment to research and development for the 1994-95 financial year was $ 203 million, however only $68.1 million of this was directed to TRL.

4.115 The Committee notes, however, that Telstra's expenditure on R&D amounts to only 0.5 per cent of revenue, which is low by world standards. For example, Nippon Telephone & Telegraph invest 4.7 per cent of revenue on R&D. [99] This suggests that if Telstra is to aspire to be a leading edge telecommunications company operating in the global economy, it needs to increase its commitment to research.

4.116 The Committee is concerned the proposed privatisation, rather than generating an increase in funds flowing to research, is actually fostering a reduction in research expenditure. It is the view of the Committee, that in the lead up to privatisation, management is intent on cutting back expenditure to make Telstra appear more attractive to future investors. As a part of this cost cutting strategy, TRL funds have been cut by about $12 million.

4.117 Following the commencement of this inquiry, Telstra announced it proposed to reduce staff numbers at TRL from the present 530 to 380 by the end of the year. This is a cut of 150 employees or 30 per cent of the total number of employees. The Committee is astonished at the size of the proposed cuts and notes that this comes on top of an additional 50 researchers and support staff who opted for either voluntary redundancy or premature retirement over the past 9 months.

4.118 It has been stated that many of those staff who opted to leave did so in response to the changing skills needed for the new directions in which TRL was heading, that is, decreasing emphasis on hardware and more on systems and applications. [100]The depth of the announced staff cuts to the TRL make Telstra's stated aim of being 'the leading provider of electronic communication and information services in Australia and the Asia-Pacific region, and a significant global provider', [101] a highly questionable aspiration.

4.119 The depth of the announced staff cuts to the TRL make Telstra's stated aim of being 'the leading provider of electronic communication and information services in Australia and the Asia-Pacific region, and a significant global provider', a highly questionable aspiration.

4.120 In their submission to the Senate Inquiry, the Institution of Engineers highlighted the dangers which downsizing can have on an organisation's capacity for research and innovation. Drawing upon the findings of their year long inquiry into the problems associated with privatisation, corporatisation and the contracting out of infrastructure services, the Institute argued that loss of skilled and experienced technical staff during downsizing can result in an excessive decline in the technical literacy of the enterprise. [102]

4.121 As a consequence of the massive cuts, it is evident to the Committee the research undertaken by Telstra will be increasingly focused upon short-term objectives geared to achieving immediate commercial outcomes. Longer term, strategic research will give way to research geared toward adapting the technology it is supplied with to meet its operational requirements (a trend which is already noticeable). [103]

4.122 Expert witnesses warned the Committee about the grave dangers involved in pursuing this path - the same path which British Telecom has followed. In his submission, Dr Kerry Hinton argued:

4.123 Following privatisation, British Telecom has adopted a policy of focusing its R&D on the design of software services and systems to operate on the hardware the market makes available. This technology strategy, if adopted by Telstra, would involve little more than the purchase and installation of equipment designed and built overseas. [105]Dr Hinton's submission contrasts this approach with the view of some, typically middle managers, within the organisation. The alternative is the claim that Australia requires a research facility which will not only ensure Telstra is an intelligent purchaser of equipment, but also capable of providing technical leadership.

4.124 Dr Hinton's submission contrasts this approach with the view of some, typically middle managers, within the organisation. The alternative is the claim that Australia requires a research facility which will not only ensure Telstra is an intelligent purchaser of equipment, but also capable of providing technical leadership.4.125 These concerns were reiterated strongly by Dr Mark Sceats, CEO of the Australian Photonics CRC. Dr Sceats argued that the impact of global changes in the telecommunications industry has resulted in a greater focus on the development of services and network management software in Telstra, at the expense of in-house R&D support at the components level. He argues this trend would be exacerbated by privatisation of Telstra.

4.126 Dr Sceats stressed, however, that it is in the technology underpinning the services, ie the core network, that the real window of opportunity for Australian industry and R&D lies:

4.127 If Telstra does not undertake such research, the outcome is likely to be an overall net reduction in the level of research conducted in Australia. The reason being that the R&D capabilities of the domestic telecommunications industry may not be sufficiently developed to compensate for cutbacks in TRL research:

4.128 The Committee is highly concerned the reductions in hardware-oriented research by Telstra will be not be undertaken in Australia by other companies.

4.129 The equipment supply industry in Australia is largely dominated by subsidiaries of large transnational corporations. The Committee is concerned that the high level of foreign ownership among equipment suppliers actually contributes to lower business expenditure on R&D than would otherwise be the case. This results because subsidiaries of transnational corporations are able to source their technological requirements from their parent companies. Given that they usually have large R&D facilities located in their home base, they have little incentive to undertake similar operations, or operations of much significance, Australia. For example, Ericsson have a significant research facility in Sweden, Alcatel in France, Nokia in Finland, Nortel in Canada, Motorola in the US, and NEC in Japan.

4.130 The former Government attempted to address such concerns through the Partnerships for Development (PfD) program. Companies such as Ericsson, Alcatel, Fujitsu, Siemens and NEC are all participants in this program and are committed to achieving an R&D expenditure of at least 5 per cent of turnover within seven years of their undertaking. [108]

4.131 The Committee notes that while mechanisms such as the PfD program have some merit, they cannot satisfactorily compensate for the maintenance of Telstra in full public ownership and ensuring it acts in the national interest.

RECOMMENDATION 8: The Committee recommends the commitment of Telstra to strategic research and research sponsorship be retained.

RECOMMENDATION 9: The Committee recommends the Government closely monitor Telstra management's handling of the Telstra Research Laboratories with an eye to the fact that they are a national asset, built up through national savings, which provide a pivotal and strategic role in Australia's intellectual infrastructure.

 

Conclusion

4.132 The Committee concludes that the financial losers will be the people of Australia who will no longer own a valuable public asset, and will no longer benefit from the considerable flow of profits from this asset.

4.133 The Committee concurs with community concern that massive staff losses will have a major impact on the viability of many current Telstra services and will have disastrous effects on regional communities and rural communities.

4.134 Finally, the Committee notes that the proposed sale will have negative repercussions for the domestic telecommunications equipment and services industry and for research and development in Australia.

 

Footnotes

[1] Department of Communications and the Arts, Submission Nos.188, 181A, 188B.

[2] Department of Finance, Submission Nos.131, 131A.

[3] BZW Australia, Submission No.295, Vol. 9, p.1848.

[4] Chamber of Commerce and Industry of Western Australia, Submission No.334, Vol.12, p.2421.

[5] Department of Communications and the Arts, Submission No.131A, Vol.16, 3137.

[6] Department of Communications and the Arts, Submission No.131A, Vol.16, p.3135.

[7] Department of Finance, Submission No.188, Vol.7, p.1267.

[8] Telstra Corporation Limited, Submission No.189, Vol.7, p.1300.

[9] A. Galal, L. Jones, P. Tandon and I. Vogelsang, 1994, Welfare Consequences of Selling Public Enterprises: An Empirical Analysis, Oxford University Press, New York, p.5.

[10] S. Kikeri, J. Nellis, M. Shirley, 1992, Privatization: The Lessons of Experience, World Bank, Washington DC, p.14.

[11] S. Kikeri, J. Nellis, M. Shirley, Privatization: The Lessons of Experience, World Bank, Washington DC, 1992, p.22.

[12] Communications Law Centre, Submission No.343, Vol.13, p.2627.

[13] Communications Law Centre, Submission No.343, Vol.13, p.2627.

[14] Kikeri, Nellis, Shirley, op cit, p.27.

[15] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit.

[16] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, ibid, p.535.

[17] Professor J. Quiggin, School of Economics, James Cook University, Submission No.192a, Vol.7, p.1357.

[18] ibid, p 1362 [SOE - State-owned Enterprise].

[19] Communications Law Centre, Submission No.343, Vol.13, p.2627.

[20] Kikeri, Nellis, Shirley, op cit, pp.6, 12.

[21] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.550.

[22] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, pp.95, 530, 99, & 79.

[23] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.278.

[24] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.448.

[25] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.444.

[26] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.530.

[27] Communications Law Centre, Submission No. 343, Vol 13, p.2629.

[28] Kikeri, Nellis, Shirley, op cit, p.1.

[29] Kikeri, Nellis, Shirley, ibid, p.28.

[30] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, pp.294, 570.

[31] Department of Communications and the Arts, Submission No.131A, Vol.16, p.3143.

[32] Communications Law Centre, Submission No.343, Vol.13, p.2627.

[33] The Journal of Finance, Vol XLIX, June 1994, p.403.

[34] The World Bank and International Finance Corporation, Washington, 1995.

[35] Department of Communications and the Arts, Submission No.131A, Vol.16, p.12 (para.34).

[36] World Wide Web, Oftel, http://www.open.gov.uk/oftel/pri97/contents.htm

[37] World Wide Web, Oftel, http://www.open.gov.uk/oftel/pri97/contents.htm (para 1.42).

[38] OECD, Telecommunications Outlook, 1995, p.70 ff.

[39] World Wide Web, Oftel, http://www.open.gov.uk/oftel/pri97/contents.htm, (para 1.43).

[40] Public Sector Research Centre, Submission No.299, Vol.10, p.2022.

[41] Public Sector Research Centre, Submission No.299, Vol.10, p.2022.

[42] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, 1994, op cit, p.99.

[43] Communications Law Centre, Submission No.343, Vol.13, p.2627.

[44] Senator the Hon R. Alston, Opening Address ATUG 96, Conference of the Australian Telecommunications Users Group, Melbourne, 30 April 1996, p.3.

[45] BZW Australia, Regarding Telstra, March 1996, p.17.

[46] Galal, Jones, Tandon and Vogelsang, op cit, p.550.

[47] National Competition Policy, Report by the Independent Committee of Inquiry, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra, August 1993, p.226.

[48] National Competition Policy, Report by the Independent Committee of Inquiry, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra, August 1993, p.226.

[49] National Competition Policy, Report by the Independent Committee of Inquiry, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra, August 1993, p.226.

[50] Communications, Electrical and Plumbing Union/ Community and Public Sector Union, Submission No.296, Vol.10, p.1868.

[51] The Hon J. Howard, Prime Minister, Howard slaps down Alston over Telstra full sale comment. Australian Associated Press, 2 September 1996 16:22.

[52] Professor J. Quiggin, Official Hansard Report, 10 July 1996, p.371.

[53] Public Sector Research Centre, University of NSW, Submission No.299, Vol.10, pp.2019-20.

[54] A figure of $ 28 billion has been proposed as potentially nearer the mark. See; BZW Australia, Submission No.139, Vol.9, p.1851.

[55] Department of Finance, Submission No.188B, Vol.14, p.2671. (Refer Table 4.1).

[56] Department of Finance, Submission No.188B, Vol.14, p.2671.

[57] BZW Australia- Submission No.295, Vol.9, p.1851.

[58] Prof. J. Quiggin, Official Hansard Report, 10 July 1996, p.365.

[59] Prof. J. Quiggin, Official Hansard Report, 10 July 1996, p.358.

[60] Prof. J. Quiggin, Official Hansard Report, 10 July 1996, p.361.

[61] Mr P. De Carlo, Acting Secretary, Telecommunications Division, Community and Public Sector Union, Official Hansard Report, 3 July 1996, p.202.

[62] Professor J. Quiggin, Professor of Economics, James Cook University; Dr Allan Brown, Economics Department, Griffith University. Submissions by other economists also made similar points. See, for example, Dr F. J. B. Stilwell, Associate Professor of Economics, University of Sydney, Submission No.164, Vol.6, p.1112 ff. The Public Sector Research Centre, Submission No.299, Vol.10, p.2008 ff., explore some of the more well known undervaluations of public assets which have occurred and the reasons for this.

[63] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No. 192, Vol.7, p.1352. Note that use of this method of evaluation is also advocated by Dr Allan Brown, Submission No.640, Vol.16, pp.3088-3112.

[64] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No. 192A Vol.16, p.3177.

[65] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No. 192A Vol.16, p.3178.

[66] To be established under the Natural Heritage Trust of Australia Bill 1996

[67] Natural Heritage Trust of Australia Bill 1996, Explanatory Memorandum.

[68] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No.192B, Vol.17, not printed.

[69] The total dividend to the Government is about $2.7 billion pa in 1994/95 of which is $900 million and a portion is $112 million.

[70] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No.192, Vol.7, p.1363.

[71] Professor J. Quiggin, Submission No.192, Vol.7, p.1363.

[72] See section 708 - 711 of the Corporations Law.

[73] Communications, Electrical and Plumbing Union/ Community and Public Sector Union, Submission No.296, Vol.10, p.1901.

[74] Ms R. Eason, Senior Research Officer, Communications, Electrical and Plumbing Union, Official Hansard Report, 3 July 1996, p.216. List ownership of Optus.

[75] Vodafone, Submission No.1, Vol.1, p.8.

[76] Public Sector Research Centre, Submission No.299, Vol.10, p.2011.

[77] See, for example, Peter Harkness, Senior Lecturer in Economics, Swinburne University of Technology, Submission No.171, Vol.6, p.1174 ff.

[78] BZW Australia, Submission No.295, Vol.9, p.1851.

[79] Professor J Quiggin, Official Hansard Report, 10 July 1996, p.349 and 350.

[80] Official Hansard Report, 30 July 1996, p.992.

[81] Sydney Morning Herald, 13 July 1996.

[82] Mr M. Hutchinson, Official Hansard Report, 26 June 1996, p.77.

[83] Senator M. Colston, Official Hansard Report, 3 July 1996, p.137.

[84] Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics, 1995, Telecommunications in Australia, Report 87, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra. pp.74-77.

[85] Bureau of Transport and Communications Economics, 1995, Telecommunications in Australia, Report 87, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra. pp.78-79.

[86] Communications and Electrical Plumbing Union, Submission No. 296, Vol.10, p.1897.

[87] R. Whittle, Telstra's New Model Network, Australian Communications, April 1996, p.80.

[88] D. Northfield, 1994, Australian Telecommunications Commercial and Regulatory Environment, CIRCIT, Melbourne, p.12.

[89] Communications and Electrical Plumbing Union, Submission no 296, Vol. 10, p.1899.

[90] Sheehan, et al, Australia and the Knowledge Economy, Melbourne: Centre for Strategic Economic Studies, 1995, p.vi.

[91] Sheehan et al, Australia and the Knowledge Economy, Melbourne: Centre for Strategic Economic Studies, 1995, p.v.

[92] Industry Commission Research and Development (Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, 1995), pp.491-6; and, Department of Industry, Science and Technology Australian Science & Innovation Resources Brief 1994 (Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, 1994), pp.19-24.

[93] Australian Photonics CRC, Submission no. 332, Vol. 12, p 2410.

[94] Dr K. Hinton, Submission no 143, Vol 5, p.886.

[95] Communications and Electrical Plumbing Union, Submission no 296, Vol 10, p.1897.

[96] Dr K. Hinton, Submission no 143, Vol 5, p.879.

[97] Dr K. Hinton, Submission no 143, Vol 5, p.879.

[98] Department of Industry, Science and Technology, 1995, Scoreboard `95: Business Expenditure on Research and Development, Canberra.

[99] The Friends of Telstra Research Laboratories Newsletter, 2 August 1996, p2.

[100] The Friends of Telstra Research Laboratories Newsletter, 2 August 1996, p.2.

[101] Telstra Annual Report 1995, p.1.

[102] The Institution of Engineers, Australia, Submission No.305, Vol.11, pp 2076-82.

[103] Department of Industry, Science and Technology, 1995, Scoreboard `95: Business Expenditure on Research and Development, Canberra, p.25.

[104] Dr K. Hinton, Submission no. 143, Vol.5, pp.878.

[105] Dr K. Hinton, Submission no. 143, Vol.5, pp.882.

[106] Dr M. Sceats, Newsletter of the Australian Photonics Co-operative Research Centre, June 1996, p.2.

[107] Australian Photonics CRC, Submission No.332, Vol.12, p.2411.

[108] Department of Industry, Science and Technology, 1995, Scoreboard `95: Business Expenditure on Research and Development, Canberra, p 25.