Chapter 5
Direct Action Plan
5.1
This chapter outlines the Direct Action Plan, and the proposed Emissions
Reduction Fund (ERF), and examines the evidence received as to whether they
have the capacity to reduce Australia's greenhouse gas emissions adequately and
cost‑effectively.
Background: What is the Direct Action Plan?
5.2
The 'Direct Action Plan' refers to a climate change policy to reduce
Australia's greenhouse gas emissions released in 2010 while the Coalition was
in Opposition.[1]
The Direct Action Plan states that:
Australia needs a scheme that will provide the incentive for
firms to reduce their carbon emissions and, at the same time, minimise the
costs to industry and the Australian economy.[2]
5.3
The Direct Action Plan has a number of components. The ERF is the
'centrepiece' of the Direct Action Plan. The Direct Action Plan states that the
ERF will 'directly support CO2 emissions reduction activities by
business and industry'.[3]
The original idea behind the ERF was that the Government will pay for projects
that will reduce CO2 emissions 'at least cost'. Funding allocations
from the ERF would be made through a reverse auction[4]
starting with the lowest-cost projects. The Direct Action Plan identifies a
range of possible opportunities for CO2 abatement,[5]
such as energy efficiency projects, cleaning up power stations, reafforestation
and revegetation projects or improvement of soil carbon.[6]
5.4
The Direct Action Plan also contained a number of other components and
commitments, including 'One Million Solar Roofs', 'Solar Towns and Solar
Schools', 'Twenty Million Trees', 'Clean Energy Employments Hubs', 'Geothermal
and Tidal Towns', 'Renewable Fuels' and 'Greenhouse Friendly Program'. The table
in Appendix 4 sets out the original commitments under the Direct Action Plan in
further detail and the current status of each commitment.
Targets
5.5
The stated aim of the original 2010 Direct Action Plan was to reduce
Australia's emissions by 5% by 2020 compared to the 1990 levels. This target
has been reiterated by the Government in the recent ERF Green Paper, which
states that the Government has committed to reduce Australia's greenhouse gas
emissions by 5% below 2000 levels by 2020 and to:
...review our position in 2015 as part of the global
negotiations regarding international commitments both pre- and post-2020.[7]
5.6
The committee notes that whether a 5% target is adequate has been
discussed earlier in this report. At the time of writing, on current emissions
projections, a 5% target represents a reduction amount of 131 million tonnes of
CO2-e[8]
in 2020 and a cumulative amount between 2014 and 2020 of 431 million tonnes.[9]
Clean Air Plan
5.7
Since coming into Government, the Coalition has released the Plan for
a Cleaner Environment.[10]
The 'Clean Air' component of this plan contains some of the commitments made in
the Direct Action Plan, and confirms the target of reducing Australia's
emissions by 5% below 2000 levels by 2020.[11]
The Clean Air Plan indicates that this target will primarily be reached through
the ERF, described as the 'centrepiece of the Government's climate action
policy'.[12]
The Clean Air Plan also contains three other initiatives: 'One Million Solar Roofs',
'Solar Towns and Solar Schools' and 'Twenty Million Trees'. These are discussed
further in Chapter 7 of this report.
Budget
5.8
In 2010, the proposed budget for the Direct Action Plan was a total of $3.2 billion
over four years. The ERF was allocated $2.55 billion of this total. The ERF had
an initial allocation of $300 million in its first year, $500 million in the
second year, $750 million in its third year, and $1 billion in its fourth year.[13]
5.9
The more recent Plan for a Cleaner Environment commits $300
million, $500 million and $750 million for the ERF over the forward estimates
(a total of $1.5 billion). The fourth year commitment has no longer been
specified.[14]
The Government has indicated that once the budget for the Direct Action Plan is
exhausted, no further monies will be spent, whether or not emissions reduction
targets have been achieved.[15]
5.10
The table in Appendix 4 sets out original funding commitments under the
Direct Action Plan and the current status of that funding and/or commitment.
Background: the Emissions Reduction Fund
5.11
Although described as the 'centrepiece' of the Government's climate policy,
the final design of the ERF is still unclear and is currently the subject of a
consultation process. On 16 October 2013, the Government released the terms of
reference for the ERF. Submissions to the terms of reference closed on Monday,
18 November 2013, and were used to inform the development of the Green
Paper.[16]
5.12
The ERF Green Paper (the Green Paper)[17]
was released on 20 December 2013, with submissions due by 21 February
2014. The Green Paper sets out the Government's 'preferred options' for design
of the ERF including key features such as auctions, baselines and contract
arrangements. Submissions to the Green Paper will be considered leading up to
the release of a white paper in 'early 2014'. The Department advised that, as
part of the white paper process, exposure legislation would be released along
with the white paper. The stated goal is for the ERF to commence on
1 July 2014.[18]
However, the Department clarified that the ERF will actually commence in two
stages: the purchasing and crediting processes would commence on 1 July 2014,
whereas the aim is for the safeguard mechanism to commence on 1 July 2015.[19]
5.13
A review of the ERF will commence 'towards the end of 2015'.[20]
A review of 'Australia's climate change policy' will also be conducted in 2015.[21]
Design of the ERF: Summary of Green Paper
5.14
The Green Paper proposes to retain some existing programs and entities: the
Clean Energy Regulator; the CFI; and the National Greenhouse and Energy Reporting
Scheme (NGERS).[22]
5.15
The Clean Energy Regulator will administer the ERF and will run the
auction process and enter into contracts with successful applicants.[23]
The Green Paper notes that 'legislative changes would be made to expand the
role of the Clean Energy Regulator'.[24]
5.16
The ERF will also 'build on the existing arrangements' under the Carbon
Farming Initiative for crediting emissions reductions.[25]
However, the Green Paper did seek views on options for 'streamlining' the CFI.[26]
5.17
The Green Paper states that three principles will guide the design of
the ERF:
- Lowest-cost emissions reductions. The Emissions Reduction Fund
will identify and purchase emissions reductions at the lowest cost.
- Genuine emissions reductions. The Emissions Reduction Fund will
purchase emissions reductions that make a real and additional contribution to
reducing Australia's greenhouse gas emissions.
- Streamlined administration. The Emissions Reduction Fund will
make it easy for businesses to participate.[27]
5.18
The ERF would have two key aspects:
-
a process for purchasing and crediting emissions reductions
(which would commenced on 1 July 2014); and
-
a 'safeguard' mechanism (not scheduled to commence until 1 July
2015).[28]
Process for purchasing emissions
reductions
5.19
The Green Paper proposes that:
...businesses will submit emissions reduction projects into a
competitive bidding process run by the Clean Energy Regulator. The bids with
the lowest cost per tonne will be selected, and the Clean Energy Regulator will
enter into contracts to purchase those emissions reductions. The competitive
nature of this process will ensure that the best value for money is achieved.[29]
5.20
The Green Paper suggests the Clean Energy Regulator could:
- run 'relatively frequent auction rounds';
-
apply a confidential benchmark price—the maximum amount it will
pay per tonne of emissions reduced — with only bids costing less than the benchmark
price being considered;
-
use standard contracts with a maximum duration of five years (the
contracts could include 'make-good' provisions to address under-delivery of
emissions reductions);[30] and
-
publish details about auctions results and contracts would be
published to 'provide information to the public on the progress' of the ERF.[31]
5.21
The Green Paper states that to 'ensure the integrity of the auction',
bids and participants would need to meet certain requirements, including identity
checks; project eligibility under a relevant 'emissions reduction method';
commercial readiness of the relevant technology or practice; and the
credibility of emissions reduction estimates.[32]
Calculating and crediting emissions
reductions – 'emissions reduction methods'
5.22
The Green Paper states that the ERF will build on existing arrangements
under the CFI for crediting emissions reductions. Approved emissions reduction 'methods'
will set out the rules for calculating and verifying emissions reductions from
different activities. The arrangements for assessing those methods will be
based on those under the CFI:
The Clean Energy Regulator will issue Australian Carbon
Credit Units for emissions reductions that are measured and verified by
approved methods, as currently occurs under the Carbon Farming Initiative.[33]
5.23
Two types of emissions reduction methods are proposed in the Green
Paper:
- Activity methods for 'specific emissions reduction
actions'. These methods would expand the set of land sector methodologies
developed for the Carbon Farming Initiative. It is proposed that existing
international methods, such as the Clean Development Mechanism under the Kyoto
Protocol, could be used and adapted to Australia.[34]
-
Facility methods for aggregate emissions reductions from
multiple activities at a particular facility. These methods could be used by
businesses that already report data under the NGERS.[35]
5.24
The Green Paper proposes that the focus of the ERF would be on emissions
reductions that would not have occurred without the ERF—often referred to as 'additionality'.[36]
Activities already occurring as part of normal business practice will not be
funded. Similarly, only activities which are new, not required by law or do not
receive funding from other Government programmes (such as the Renewable Energy
Target, or state based energy efficiency schemes) will be eligible.[37]
The Green Paper states that the ERF is 'designed to complement rather than
duplicate these schemes'.[38]
'Safeguard' mechanism
5.25
The original Direct Action Plan states that businesses that reduce their
emissions below their individual baseline would be able to offer this CO2
abatement for sale to the Government. However, businesses undertaking activity
with an emissions level above their 'business as usual' levels would
incur a financial penalty.[39]
The Direct Action Plan stated that the value of penalties will be set in
consultation with industry but that:
Given the trend towards lower emissions-intensive activity,
and the economic growth projections that have been built into 'business as
usual' emissions estimates, this is only expected to apply in exceptional
circumstances.[40]
5.26
This commitment appears to have evolved in the Green Paper to a
'safeguard mechanism'. The Green Paper now states that the ERF 'is designed to
allow businesses to continue ordinary operations without penalty':
Businesses will be encouraged to decrease emissions below
their historical business-as-usual levels through the Emissions Reduction Fund.
In addition, a mechanism will be developed in conjunction with business
stakeholders to provide incentives not to exceed historical emissions
baselines.[41]
5.27
The Green Paper refers to this as the 'safeguard mechanism', and
suggests it could commence from 1 July 2015 to:
...provide lead time to consult comprehensively with businesses
on these elements and allow time for access to the Emissions Reduction Fund's
crediting and purchasing elements to help reduce emissions.[42]
5.28
The Green Paper identifies the following issues for the design of an
effective framework to discourage emissions growth above historical levels:
- the entities and emissions to be covered by the scheme
('coverage');
-
how baseline emission levels would be determined;
-
action required from businesses if baselines were exceeded; and
-
appropriate treatment of new investments and significant
expansions.
Coverage
5.29
In terms of coverage, the Green Paper suggests that the simplest
approach would be to limit the scheme to corporations and greenhouse gases
already subject to the NGERS[43]—that
is, facilities which emit over 25,000 tonnes of CO2-e emissions each
year.[44]
The Green Paper suggests that:
Coverage thresholds should be set at a level that maximises
emissions coverage but minimises the number of entities that may need to
interact with these elements of the Emissions Reduction Fund.[45]
5.30
The Green Paper then suggests if coverage were restricted to facilities
which emit 100,000 tonnes of CO2-e per year, this would 'significantly
streamline coverage by covering around 50 per cent of Australia's emissions, but
limit the number of covered entities to around 190'.[46]
Setting baselines for the safeguard
mechanism
5.31
A 'baseline' is defined as 'a projected level of future emissions or a
historical level of emissions that would have occurred without policy
intervention'.[47]
The Green Paper notes that:
Baseline parameters need to be designed to help achieve the
goals of the Emissions Reduction Fund with minimal complexity. A facility's
emissions are likely to fluctuate over time due to a variety of influences such
as changes in production levels, the mix of outputs produced, plant
maintenance, and the quality of inputs used. Baselines could be set in a way
that takes account of these normal variations.[48]
5.32
Options include setting historical baselines based on emissions
intensity (the ratio of emissions per output) or on absolute emissions
levels (the absolute level of emissions from a facility during a historical
period). The Green Paper notes that baselines based on absolute emissions 'would
be simple to determine' using the existing NGERS reporting framework without
requiring any new reporting.[49]
5.33
The Green Paper suggests that initial baselines could be set 'using data
that represents a high point in historical emissions for a facility' and
explains that:
This would ensure baselines accommodate situations where a
facility increases production in the future back towards fully installed
capacity or where normal variation occurs as a result of the issues described
above. While this approach may provide sufficient flexibility in baselines to
accommodate historical variations, significant expansions in the production
capacity at a facility are likely to require specific treatment.[50]
5.34
The Green Paper states that there is no intention to raise revenue via
the ERF, and that if an entity did exceed its baseline, 'there would be
flexible compliance arrangements available'.[51]
Options suggested include 'an initial transition period during which compliance
action for exceeding baselines would not apply'; a multi-year compliance
period, where a facility could exceed a baseline in one year so long as its
average emissions over the full compliance period remained below the baseline;
and enabling businesses to purchase credits to bring their net emissions back
within baselines.[52]
5.35
Finally, the Green Paper also states that the ERF would 'put in place a
framework that supports new facilities or significant expansions at best
practice'.[53]
The Green Paper notes that the definitions of 'best practice' and 'significant
expansion' will be key issues.[54]
Capacity of the Direct Action Plan to meet Australia's targets
5.36
This section considers the evidence relating to the capacity of the
Direct Action Plan to meet Australia's targets adequately and in a
cost-effective manner. The more technical design issues relating to the ERF are
considered further in the next chapter.
5.37
An overwhelming number of submissions and witnesses expressed doubt
about whether the Direct Action Plan and the ERF could achieve Australia's
existing emissions reduction targets.[55]
This doubt was based on a number of factors which are discussed further below:
- the need for more detail to make an assessment;
-
the budget allocated to the ERF and the associated price of
abatement;
-
comparison with the performance of similar past schemes;
-
the administrative burden involved in the ERF;
-
the voluntary nature of the ERF;
-
the lack of economy-wide incentives to reduce emissions;
-
the overall cost-effectiveness of the scheme; and
-
the need for other complementary measures.
More detail required
5.38
Many identified the need for more detail in order to properly evaluate
the proposed ERF.[56]
As Professor Garnaut observed, it is difficult to make a responsible choice
between the two approaches of the ERF and the carbon pricing mechanism. He described
the choice as a 'Martian beauty contest':
... there has been an incomplete definition of the
alternative...the Senate is put in the position of a judge of a Martian beauty
contest who is invited to make the unseen candidate the winner, having seen
some imperfections in the first candidate.[57]
5.39
Professor Ross Garnaut remarked that the Green Paper is an 'unusual
document':
Normally a green paper on a very important new policy would
specify more clearly the objectives, the alternative ways of meeting them and
the government's preferred approach as a means of underpinning a productive and
constructive discussion.[58]
5.40
Professor Garnaut described the Green Paper as a 'shooting of the
breeze':
...there are many things that would need to be part of an
effective emissions reduction fund that simply are not discussed in the paper.
We are left to work out for ourselves how quite a number of things would work.
Some important issues are raised, but raised just lightly, without suggestions
of what the government has in mind to go about it.[59]
5.41
Several submissions concluded that 'it is premature to assess the impact
or potential impact' of the Direct Action Plan and the ERF until further detail
is available.[60]
For example, the Energy Supply Association of Australia told the committee
that:
Direct Action as a suite of policies still under development,
and in that context it is not possible to make definitive statements regarding
its efficacy as compared with carbon pricing.[61]
5.42
Similarly, the ADIC told the committee that:
...there is the potential that the Direct Action Plan could
assist, but it will depend on how it is designed and [whether it] has enough
funding...[62]
5.43
Several submitters put forward modelling analysing the Direct Action Plan
based on various possible designs for the ERF. For example, Mr Erwin Jackson
from The Climate Institute told the committee that:
...even using very conservative assumptions and very generous
assumptions about the direct action policy, our assessment with SKM and Monash
University suggests that Australia's emissions would increase by around
10 per cent to 2020 under the current policy framework.[63]
[emphasis added]
5.44
Mr Jackson further pointed out that the Government has not presented any
evidence or independent modelling to demonstrate that the Direct Action Plan
can achieve its target.[64]
The Climate Institute submission further remarked that:
No independent analysis to date has shown that the [Direct
Action Plan] policy framework as outlined can achieve Australia's international
obligations and emission commitments.[65]
5.45
Even those who were more optimistic that the ERF might be enough to meet
a 5% target[66]
cautioned that the ERF needed to be designed well. For example, ClimateWorks
Australia submitted that, if well designed and sufficiently resourced,
the ERF could potentially meet more than a 5% emission reduction target.[67]
5.46
Mr Tony Wood from the Grattan Institute also expressed the view that
'the Direct Action Plan can effectively and efficiently reduce emissions', but
'whether it will be efficient in reducing emissions is going to depend upon the
design of the scheme, many elements of which are yet to be determined'.[68]
5.47
Others were concerned that the Direct Action Plan and ERF fail to
provide a market‑based price signal to reduce emissions.[69]
For example, Mr David Rossiter told the committee that:
...this plan provides public funding to companies for specific
abatement purposes, but because the company may not have had to fund this abatement,
there will be no cascading price signal coming down from the company due to
additional costs of their produce, so the consumers in the wider community will
not get a price signal to reduce the abatement further.[70]
5.48
The Grattan Institute indicated that the ERF could effectively
establish at least a 'shadow' carbon price:
Although the ERF does not include a tradable commodity such
as is created by an Emissions Trading Scheme or the RET, it will establish a
carbon price, based on the marginal cost curve of emissions reduction
activities covered by the fund.[71]
5.49
However, the Grattan Institute reiterated that whether this will occur
depends on design and that more detail is needed:
An assessment of the capacity of the Direct Action Plan to
achieve cost effective greenhouse gas reductions rests on whether it will
effectively generate a carbon price across a broad range of abatement options.
In principle and with good design, the ERF could meet this criterion. There is
simply insufficient detail yet available to make this assessment, and whether
providing that detail would lead to greater administrative complexity and cost
than would be associated with a well-designed ETS.[72]
5.50
Technical design issues are discussed further in Chapter 6.
Adequacy of the Budget and the
price of abatement
5.51
Evidence to the committee indicated that a key constraint on the ability
of the ERF to meet Australia's targets is the budget for the ERF and the
associated cost of abatement opportunities.
Budget for the ERF
5.52
As noted earlier in this chapter, the Government has indicated that if
the budget for the Direct Action Plan is exhausted, no further monies will be
spent, whether or not emissions reduction targets have been achieved.[74]
5.53
Many submissions criticised this approach of a cap on funding rather
than a cap on emissions.[75]
Mr David Rossiter pointed out that the abatement target is an international
commitment and yet 'the Government has a cap set on its DAP [Direct Action
Plan] funding regardless of whether or not it can reach its abatement target'.[76]
5.54
Many queried whether the funding allocated to the ERF would be
sufficient to meet Australia's targets.[77]
The Grattan Institute submitted that 'the funding allocation, rather than the
inherent design, of the Direct Action Plan will be the major determinant of its
adequacy'.[78]
The Grattan Institute pointed to published analyses which suggest that 'the
target cannot be achieved with the allocated funds, given assumptions of
emissions projections, abatement costs and budgetary allocation'.[79]
5.55
It was suggested that to be effective, the ERF would need increased
funding.[80]
Various estimates were put forward of exactly how much more funding might be
needed up to 2020, ranging from $4 billion to up to $100 billion.[81]
The estimates varied depending on the design of the ERF and the estimated price
of abatement. WWF‑Australia warned that:
...the cost per tonne of abatement is expected to be
significantly higher than has been budgeted for under the ERF. As a result the
fund is expected to run out before the required level of abatement has been
purchased.[82]
5.56
Some submitters therefore concluded:
...if funding for the ERF/DAP won't be increased, it seems
clear that the Coalition have no real intention of even meeting the emission
reduction targets they have promised.[83]
5.57
At the same time, it was pointed out that, if the ERF suffers from the
same problem as previous grant-based schemes like the former Greenhouse Gas
Abatement Program, as discussed later in this chapter, this is a strong
possibility that the ERF will actually be underspent.[84]
Estimated price of abatement
5.58
It was generally suggested that the price available for abatement under
the ERF, given its current budget, would be too low for many abatement
opportunities.[85]
The committee also heard various estimates of the possible price of abatement
that would be available per tonne of emissions under the ERF. Many submitters
and witnesses calculated their estimates based on the funding allocation for
the ERF (of $1.55 billion) and the abatement target of 431Mt to 2020. Estimates
varied from $3.60 per tonne to $12 per tonne, with most around the average
of $8 per tonne.[86]
5.59
For example, the Sustainable Energy Association calculated that:
To achieve abatement of 431 million t CO2-e by
2020 with a budget of $1.55 billion, as is currently proposed, the average
price of carbon would need to be $3.60/t CO2-e to achieve the
emissions target.[87]
5.60
The CEFC submitted that 'the hypothetical price per tonne of emissions
purchased for abatement' would need to be 'very low' – possibly in the order of
$4‑7/tonne if the ERF was expected to deliver the majority of this
abatement target.[88]
5.61
Greenbank Environmental similarly warned that:
...the Government's 'estimated' $8-10 price of GHG Emission
reductions is too low to fund renewable energy projects and too high to meet
the emissions reduction target within the allocated funds.[89]
5.62
It was suggested that, realistically, most abatement opportunities would
cost at least $25–$30
per tonne, and possibly up to $114 per tonne, and as a result the budget for
the ERF would need to be increased to achieve an emissions reduction target of
5%.[90]
For example, the CEFC submitted that:
Independent modelling has shown, consistent with CEFC's
experience, that an abatement cost of between AU$20–$40 per tonne is the likely settlement price
needed to achieve the goals of the Emission Reduction Fund.[91]
5.63
Mr Jackson from The Climate Institute agreed that:
...the government's estimates—that it could achieve the target
with emission reductions in the order of six or seven dollars a tonne—are not
realistic and not supported by any evidence. We are talking in the order of $25
or $30 a tonne required in order to get most of these projects off the ground.[92]
5.64
Sustainable Energy Now calculated that, if the average cost of abatement
were $30 per tonne, the ERF would buy around 85 million tonnes of abatement.
That would leave at least 340 million tonnes left to abate to reach the
emissions reduction target of 5% by 2020, which would mean the budget for the
ERF would need to be increased by around $10.4 billion.[93]
5.65
The Climate Change Authority also told the committee that the modelling
in its recent report showed that under low and medium carbon price scenarios, a
5% emissions reduction target would not be able to be achieved domestically.[94]
5.66
The Australia Institute noted that the ERF Green Paper appears to have
budgeted for 'about $9 to $12 per tonne of CO2e over the forward estimates'. In
contrast:
Most competitive grant schemes have cost between $60 and $100
per tonne of CO2e, with many schemes costing in excess of $100 per tonne of
CO2e. This compares to market mechanisms...which cost between $15 and $40 per
tonne of CO2e...If we assume a more realistic, but still very optimistic cost of
abatement of $60 per tonne of CO2e then ERF would need to be increased by $7.2
billion over the forward estimates and about $21 billion out to 2020. This of
course assumes that enough projects can be found to achieve the required level
of abatement...[95]
Low cost abatement opportunities
5.67
There was discussion during the committee's inquiry as to where such low
cost abatement opportunities might arise. For example, ClimateWorks Australia suggested
that, if well designed and sufficiently resourced, the ERF could target
abatement opportunities that:
...are large in volume, technologically proven and can be
captured at reasonable cost. Among these, major focus areas include capture of
waste methane from coal mines, increased deep retrofitting of commercial
buildings and industrial facilities, and carbon farming and forestry.[96]
5.68
However, Ms Gillian Broadbent AO, CEFC Chair, cautioned that:
...if you want to find the lowest cost abatement, then the more
broad the range of transactions that you consider means you are more likely to
find it. If you cut it down to only large transactions and only large
transactions that are self-financing through large corporations, you are not
looking as broadly, you are not getting the cost down to necessarily the lowest
cost of abatement...[97]
5.69
By way of example of the costs of other forms of abatement, the CSIRO
indicated that the cost of abatement of current technologies for the capture of
fugitive emissions is around $10–20
per tonne, but that they were hoping with the next generation of technologies,
this might be reduced to $5 per tonne and be deployed 'towards the end of this
decade'.[98]
In relation to abatement opportunities relating to livestock, the CSIRO told
the committee that this would cost around $73 per tonne.[99]
The CSIRO submitted that whether Australia will capture the many abatement
opportunities 'will depend on the detailed design of the program.'[100]
5.70
The committee heard that most of the lowest cost abatement opportunities
in Australia related to energy efficiency.[101]
However, the Clean Energy Council expressed concern that:
In this context the implications of a strict 'least cost
abatement' approach to assessing projects also need to be considered. Some
activities, like energy efficiency, might come to dominate the program and
reduce the level of diversity in activity that would most likely be needed in
order to achieve a balanced approach to emission reduction across the economy.[102]
5.71
WWF-Australia warned in relation to energy efficiency projects, that
many 'would have occurred anyway as they make good financial sense'.[103]
Similarly, the Australian Manufacturing Workers' Union (AMWU) submitted that:
...there is no way for the Government to guarantee that such
non-additive abatement isn't purchased by the Government. Many capital
investment projects would lead to improved energy efficiency and thus abatement
as a bi-product of the efficiency improvement. Such projects can be presented
as abatement projects and can participate in Direct Action auctions in an
attempt to secure funding for a part of the projects cost. Indeed, it is not
unlikely that firms are holding off implementing such projects in anticipation
of having the project cost decreased through an Emission Reduction Fund grant.[104]
5.72
Others queried why government should be involved in 'picking winners' in
terms of abatement opportunities, rather than letting the market decide using a
carbon pricing mechanism.[105]
However, as Dr Paul Burke observed:
In terms of working out where the abatement could possibly
come from, as an economist I would prefer to let the market do that rather than
me sit back and pick it.[106]
5.73
Others objected generally to the involvement of government in this way:
...we need to reduce government regulation. We need to have a
light‑handed government....Why are we going to a direct action policy that
involves the government hand when we could have left it to the market to make
decisions about where these investments would be made?[107]
5.74
It was also pointed out that there are also a number of practical
obstacles to low-cost abatement, such as lack of information, shortage of
capital and the short timeframes.[108]
To overcome these obstacles, it was suggested that a higher price may actually need
to be paid. For example, Mr Paul Pollard warned that 'a $20 price/incentive may
be needed to uncover emissions reductions where theoretically a $10 figure
would suffice'. [109]
5.75
Dr Paul Burke also pointed out that the costs to business of making an
application under the ERF system could also add to the cost of abatement under
the ERF:
...subsidy approaches can involve an economic cost per unit of
emissions reduction that is more than 10 times higher than can be achieved
using price-based approaches.[110]
5.76
The AMWU agreed that the Government could end up paying a premium on
abatement under the ERF:
As polluters would not be obliged to participate, they would
require a price per tonne of abatement that was greater than the cost per tonne
of abatement in order to participate, otherwise there would be no benefit (and
therefore no reason) to participate. This would by definition guarantee that
the Government would be overpaying for every tonne of abatement (as it would be
paying a premium to every participant).[111]
Ability of grant-based schemes to
deliver abatement
5.77
A key concern was that the ERF auction process closely resembles unsuccessful
grant‑based schemes used by governments in the past and would therefore
be plagued by similar problems.[112]
For example, The Australia Institute submitted that similar schemes in the
past:
-
took significantly longer to achieve any abatement than
originally planned;
-
were unable to find enough suitable projects; and
-
achieved substantially less emissions reductions than planned.[113]
5.78
A key example put to the committee was the former Greenhouse Gas
Abatement Program (GGAP).[114]
The GGAP was a competitive grant program for emission reduction projects. It
commenced on 1 July 2000 with an initial allocated budget of $400 million over
four years, but was subsequently extended and ran until 2009.[115]
GGAP was projected to reduce greenhouse gas pollution by 51.5 Mt CO2‑e.[116]
The aims of GGAP sound somewhat familiar:
GGAP is targeting opportunities for large-scale,
cost-effective and sustained abatement across the economy. GGAP will only
support projects that will result in quantifiable and additional abatement not
expected to occur in the absence of GGAP funding...[117]
5.79
An Auditor-General review revealed that by 30 June 2003, the GGAP had
only spent $50.1 million of its original $400 million budget.[118]
A further investigation by the Auditor-General in 2010 reported that the GGAP
only managed to reduce emissions by 15.5 MT CO2-e—30% of the
original intention—and spent only 40% of its original budget allocation over a
ten year period.[119]
The $400 million allocated to GGAP was consistently underspent throughout the
life of the program. The Auditor-General found that the underspend reflected
three key factors:
- difficulties in attracting sufficient numbers of quality project
proposals;
-
termination of nine of the 23 approved projects for reasons such
as failure to meet contractual obligations and operational difficulties with
project implementation; and
-
reallocation of funds to other programs.[120]
5.80
As Mr Jamie Hanson from the ACF observed, some of these reasons for
under-delivery 'were remediable but others were structural problems that face
grant and tender schemes'.[121]
5.81
The Grattan Institute similarly cautioned that 'these schemes have a
mixed record' and there is 'a significant risk that developers will bid
extremely low in order to win the auction, but then fail to deliver the
project'.[122]
The Grattan Institute noted that this risk can be addressed and that the Government
is proposing to address the issue in the ERF design by paying only on delivery.
However, Mr Wood from the Grattan Institute pointed out that the problem then
becomes project delivery:
...if I bid a project and get a contract and then fail to
deliver that project in three years' time, you won't pay me the money—the
government won't pay me the money—but then again the government does not get
its abatement either. The problem with many of these programs is not that the
money gets purloined inappropriately, it is that it never gets spent. So the
fundamental objective to reduce emissions never gets achieved...[123]
5.82
The Australia Institute contrasted other similar grant based schemes
with market mechanisms, and concluded that competitive grant schemes had been
'relative costly' and only reduced emissions by small amounts compared to
market mechanisms.[124]
5.83
Submitters were also concerned that grant-based schemes impose a high
administrative burden on Government, and the complex processes involved could
also be a disincentive to participation for businesses.[125]
Administrative burden
5.84
Submissions were also critical of the ERF model for its administrative
complexity. This included the workload involved in assessing bids made under
auctions, as well as the considerable complexity involved in crediting
emissions reduction methods, setting baselines and determining 'additionality',
all of which will result in a high administrative burden for Government.[126]
As Dr Burke explained, the ERF is:
... administratively complex, requiring the government to guess
baselines and assess and monitor abatement projects. These are expensive tasks
that the government does not need to do and should not be doing.[127]
5.85
Dr Burke then observed that he would:
...feel very sorry for the Canberra bureaucrat or team of
bureaucrats who would need to be doing this job. It is extremely difficult to
be guessing baselines on a project or even company basis over a period of five
years or more...[128]
5.86
As will be discussed further in the next chapter, Mr Rossiter suggested
that up to 600 baselines might need to be set, which would require considerable
levels of staffing and technical expertise.[129]
5.87
In response to the committee's questioning as to the levels of staffing
that might be required to design and administer the ERF, departmental
representatives advised that decisions about staffing levels:
...will be guided by the decisions the government takes on the
nature, scope and otherwise of the program. Currently the Clean Energy
Regulator has a staff of well over 300, from memory, and then the department
advises on other aspects. So there is substantial capacity in government to
administer any arrangements. However, all budget decisions and the size and
scope of the scheme are decisions in front of the government at the moment...[130]
5.88
Other submitters and witnesses pointed out that there would be also be a
cost to bidders under the ERF, which would be a disincentive to participation.
As Professor Ross Garnaut pointed out:
It will cost money for enterprises to prepare a bid. To
prepare a credible bid, firms would actually have to have designed the
investments that were going to reduce emissions and that costs a lot of money.
There would be no return on that investment in the way of payments from the
Emissions Reduction Fund unless they were successful in the competitive
process.[131]
5.89
Dr Burke cautioned that, as a result, the ERF will not necessarily
support lowest cost abatement:
Firms will not apply for subsidies for many of the least-cost
emissions reduction possibilities. This is because: (1) Many low-cost abatement
possibilities may be small in nature or not in line with Direct Action
requirements; and (2) There are costs and uncertainties of applying for
subsidies. Many of the “lowest hanging fruit” of emissions reductions will
therefore be missed.[132]
5.90
Professor Frank Jotzo similarly observed:
...substantial transaction costs are associated with this, in
particular, for small to medium size projects. Businesses might just decide
that it is simply not worth their while entering into the process...[133]
5.91
The Australian Industry Group acknowledged that the safeguard mechanism
'has the potential to create administrative costs and compliance costs',
depending on its design. However, they argued that the 'quite simple method
tentatively proposed in the Green Paper' would not create significant
administrative costs.[134]
5.92
In response to questioning on this issue, the Department advised that
one of the design principles of the ERF is to focus on ensuring that costs are
kept to a minimum. The Department further noted that:
The transaction costs or administrative costs that might come
about under the ERF come about in two ways. The first way is around the
crediting and purchasing element. This is an entirely optional part of the
scheme. Any firm that comes forward with a project that it wants to generate
credits under and bid into the ERF does that entirely voluntarily. Any costs
that were reflected in a bidding in for that return it would presumably include
in the scope of the project in which it was bidding in, of course, because it
is expecting to win a contract to pay for undertaking the project. However,
having said that, there would be no reason not to keep those costs as low as
possible.[135]
Voluntary nature of the scheme
5.93
Many submitters and witnesses were critical of the voluntary nature of
the Direct Action Plan and ERF.[136]
For example, Reverend Pederick from the Anglican EcoCare Commission told the
committee that:
...it is an opt-in process. There is no compulsion on
businesses to compete for participation in ERF projects, and no penalty for
those who choose not to.[137]
5.94
In the same vein, WWF-Australia submitted that it is difficult to see
why companies would be inclined to participate in the ERF 'if they don't need
to'.[138]
5.95
Dr Tom Skladzien from the AMWU argued that, because it is a voluntary
choice for business whether to engage in the ERF auction process and there will
be transaction costs involved in participating, businesses 'will only engage if
it is in their financial interest to do so'. As noted earlier in this chapter,
this could result in the Government paying a premium for abatement.[139]
.... will only engage if it is in their financial interest to
do so. That means that the government will be paying a premium for every tonne
of abatement, because otherwise they would be indifferent to engage or not and
would choose not....[140]
5.96
Mr Nathan Fabian of the IGCC was of the view that 'direct action is not
an investment grade policy' and that:
...from what we know of the ERF the scale, duration and carbon
prices of deals likely to be on offer will not provide sufficient incentive for
investors to participate. We think the banks will take a similar view.[141]
5.97
Mr Rossiter pointed out that, according to NGERS data, just 12 emitters
produce 50% of Australia's emissions. He was concerned, if participation is
voluntary, the ERF scheme:
...would have no capacity to focus on the biggest emitters and
assist in reducing their emissions. The scheme neither provides an obligation
for the large emitters to reduce their emissions nor does it provide sufficient
funding to attract large emitters to make bids. This is a huge flaw in the scheme...[142]
5.98
A departmental representative responded to concerns about the voluntary
nature of the scheme as follows:
It will be voluntary to enter the scheme and generate
credits, but the opportunity to sign a contract with the Commonwealth over a
number of years for a given price, for given tonnes of abatement, is
potentially a very strong incentive for some businesses.[143]
No economy wide incentives
5.99
A key concern for many was that the Direct Action Plan and the ERF would
provide no incentives or opportunities to assist Australia in the necessary
transition to a low‑carbon economy in the long-term.[144]
The AMWU were particularly scathing in this regard:
Direct Action is neither equitable, economically efficient,
nor capable of bringing about significant economic change. It will hinder not
help the development of a global solution to climate change, and it will set a
dangerous precedent...Rather than any serious attempt at a policy to address
climate change, Direct Action is more likely an attempt to delay a real climate
change policy at taxpayer expense.[145]
5.100
Reverend Pederick from the Anglican EcoCare Commission was concerned
that the Direct Action Plan and ERF 'basically avoids making the structural
changes that the Australian economy requires'.[146]
Mr Hanson from the ACF agreed that:
The single greatest flaw of the Direct Action Plan is that it
simply cannot drive the long-term changes that are required.[147]
5.101
The AYCC agreed that while the ERF provides incentives for some
businesses to reduce their carbon pollution:
...there is no incentive for other polluting businesses to
clean up their act—and in fact some high polluting businesses may choose not to
reduce pollution of their own accord in the hope of winning future ERF grants.[148]
5.102
As Professor Jotzo warned, the approach proposed under the ERF:
...can also create incentives to hold back investments that
reduce energy use or emissions unless they are subsidised under the mechanism.
This in turn has economic costs through suboptimal investment and skewed
investment patterns.[149]
5.103
Ms Skarbek of ClimateWorks Australia indicated that research shows that
a 'deep decarbonisation' of the Australian and global economy is required by
2050.[150]
Many pointed out that it would be more costly and difficult to make emissions
reductions in the long term, and that the longer we wait, the harder and more
expensive it will get.[151]
For example, Mr Murray from the ACF told the committee:
We can act sooner or we can act later to start the
transformation of Australia's economy. The sooner we act...the lower the cost
will be to business, to families and to Australia's economy. If we put off that
action until later the costs are going to go up.[152]
5.104
The ACTU similarly expressed concern that:
Without an effective policy, the shift to a low carbon
economy will be delayed. This will increase the cost and create greater
uncertainty for industry and workers as the economy responds to the global
carbon constrained environment. Finally it will result in missed opportunities.
Innovation in low carbon and energy efficiency technologies presents new
opportunities for industry, creating jobs of the future.[153]
5.105
Mr Fabian of the IGCC advised that the ERF 'is not an effective
alternative to an emissions trading scheme and should not be substituted for
it'.[154]
Overall cost-effectiveness
5.106
Many submissions and witnesses expressed the view that, in general, the cost
of achieving Australia's emissions reduction targets under Direct Action would
be higher than under the current carbon price framework.[155]
As Professor Garnaut pointed out, the Green Paper does not attempt to analyse
the costs of meeting even a minus 5% target through Direct Action and the ERF.
However, Professor Garnaut reasoned that the Direct Action Plan is likely to
cost more for less reduction in emissions.[156]
5.107
Others agreed that the ERF will not be cost-effective. For example, Mr Murray
from the ACF argued that:
...an approach like direct action would come at a higher cost.
The scheme costs more to implement and it may not get the same efficiencies
that the market-based approach for the emissions trading scheme would bring
about.[157]
5.108
Mr Piers Verstegen from the CCWA stated that the Direct Action Plan is
not a cost-effective alternative to the current framework:
...it is going to be impossible to determine a baseline in
terms of the national total emissions profile and then target emissions
reduction expenditure in a way which is going to deliver the least-cost
abatement. That is what an economy-wide price does. It delivers least-cost
abatement. This policy will not deliver least-cost abatement. It will deliver
much more expensive abatement, and it will conflict and create other market
failures and other market problems which will reduce the efficiency of the
delivery of that abatement effort.[158]
5.109
The Sustainable Energy Association pointed out that, unlike the carbon
pricing mechanism, the Direct Action Plan proposal 'raises no revenue and comes
at net cost to the Budget'.[159]
5.110
In contrast, the Grattan Institute considered that the ERF could
deliver 'cost‑effective reductions in greenhouse gas emissions', but
there is 'currently inadequate detail available to assess its cost
effectiveness'.[160]
5.111
Mr Jackson from The Climate Institute observed:
...the real issue for government, at the end of the day, is
whether that is money well spent. You never really know and, unless it is
achieving our targets, which it is unlikely to do, why would we spend the
money? You are not actually delivering the outcome. You are just imposing a
cost on the community with no real benefit.[161]
Who should pay for emissions
reductions?
5.112
It was argued that Direct Action will not only be more expensive, but
there is also a fundamental principal at stake at to who should pay for
emissions reductions. For example, the Conservation Council of Western
Australia were concerned that:
The mitigation that is achieved through Direct Action will
come at a very high cost per tonne, which will be borne by taxpayers, rather
than polluters.[162]
5.113
Indeed, many submitters objected to the approach under the ERF based on
the general 'polluter pays' principle. It was pointed out that, under the
Direct Action Plan, the Government would pay polluters to reduce their
pollution, effectively subsidising those polluters with taxpayer funds.[163]
Some described the Direct Action Plan as 'fundamentally inequitable' for this
reason.[164]
5.114
Mr Hanson from the ACF told the committee that:
....a fair and effective approach to pollution reduction will
require polluters to pay for the damage they cause. Pollution comes at a cost.
If polluters do not pay, the community will, and that is not fair. Yet the
Direct Action Plan proposes subsidising polluters.[165]
5.115
The North Queensland Conservation Council submitted that:
In surprise move, the coalition government is reversing its
habitual stand on market-based, user-pays systems, by proposing an approach
that rewards polluters with the money of those that suffer from the pollution.
Instead of 'fining' polluters and giving the money to the taxpayer, the DAP
involves using taxpayer funds to 'encourage' polluters to refrain from their
dirty habits.[166]
5.116
Several submissions also noted that businesses or facilities that have
already taken action to reduce their emissions may be disadvantaged, while
entities that have taken no action have more opportunities to access subsidies.[167]
Or, as Mr John Hawkins argued, the ERF scheme 'penalises past good behaviour
and rewards bad behaviour', so that, for example:
...a company that has been operating inefficiently and
polluting a lot has much more scope to put in a tender than a responsible firm
that has already taken action to minimise its emissions.[168]
Other complementary measures needed
5.117
Many submissions suggested that they could support the ERF as an
additional measure to achieve emissions reductions, but not as a stand‑alone
solution.[169]
These submissions observed that the challenge of reducing Australia's greenhouse
gas emissions will require 'a combination of approaches'.[170]
As The Australia Institute remarked:
The idea that we should only use one strategy to combat
climate change is as strange as employing only one strategy to reduce smoking.
Multiple strategies need to be employed if we are to effectively reduce
emissions.[171]
5.118
Mr Verstegen of the CCWA similarly told the committee that the Direct
Action Plan 'may be able to make an additional useful contribution' along with
other policy instrument including an economy-wide carbon price and cap and
renewable energy targets, but:
...on its own we do not believe it is capable of delivering
anywhere near what is required to reduce our greenhouse emissions.[172]
5.119
A range of other complementary measures to reduce Australia's greenhouse
gas emissions were suggested during the committee's inquiry. These included a
carbon price scheme; renewable energy targets; stricter land clearing
regulations; carbon labelling; building and vehicle emission standards; energy
efficiency measures; and education and research funding.[173]
Several submissions also called for the reduction and removal of direct and
indirect fossil fuel subsidies.[174]
5.120
The Green Paper notes that there are 'several other government
programmes that promote emission reductions, including the Renewable Energy
Target',[175]
and other Direct Action measures such as the Twenty Million Trees program as
well as state based efficiency schemes.[176]
5.121
The committee notes that the Green Paper sought views on 'regulatory
reform opportunities that would complement the ERF'. However, the only measure
identified in that part of the Green Paper was a phase down on the use of
hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs) under the Ozone Protection and Synthetic
Greenhouse Gas Management Act 1989 (Cth).[177]
5.122
In the context of energy efficiency, submissions expressed support for
the Energy Efficiency Opportunities Program, as well as disappointment at its
abandonment.[178]
The committee notes that the Government recently announced that the program
will not continue in its current form. The Government website states that 'companies
continue to have obligations under the Energy Efficiency Opportunities Act
2006' and that 'the department will continue to verify compliance with the
program'. Finally it states that 'through the Energy White Paper process, the Government
is consulting on how to optimise energy efficiency policy as part of the
overall energy policy mix'.[179]
However, WWF-Australia submitted that:
...cost effective energy efficiency opportunities already
identified under this reporting framework should not now be eligible for ERF
funding, so as to ensure that abatement delivered by the ERF is fully
additional to business as usual.[180]
Committee comment
5.123
The committee finds that there is no evidence that the Direct Action
Plan and its Emissions Reduction Fund will achieve substantial emissions
reductions at a reasonable cost. In fact, there was considerable doubt in
evidence received by the committee as to whether the Emissions Reduction Fund
will meet a 5% emissions reduction target, let alone the higher targets that
will be required into the future that have been recommended by the Climate
Change Authority, as discussed in Chapter 2.
5.124
Based on the evidence that is available to the committee—and noting that
there is a considerable amount of detail lacking about the design of the
Emissions Reduction Fund—the committee is persuaded that the Government's
Direct Action Plan and the proposed Emissions Reduction Fund are fundamentally
flawed. They ignore the well‑established principle of 'polluter pays',
and instead propose that the Australian taxpayer should effectively subsidise
big polluters.
5.125
The committee notes that the Government has indicated that the funding
for the Direct Action Plan is capped. That is, if the budget for the Direct
Action Plan is insufficient, no further monies will be spent, regardless of
whether emissions reduction targets have been achieved. On the one hand, the
committee heard evidence that the budget allocated to Direct Action will be completely
inadequate to achieve the required levels of abatement. At the same time,
evidence to the committee was that similar grant‑based schemes in the
past have struggled to spend their money because they did not attract
sufficient numbers of quality project proposals and many of the projects failed
to deliver. While it is hard to reconcile these two issues, the committee
considers that it is an indication of a fundamentally flawed proposal.
5.126
Moreover, the committee heard evidence that the Direct Action Plan and
its Emissions Reduction Fund will not assist in the necessary transition to a
low-carbon economy. As a voluntary program, there is no guarantee that
businesses will even participate in the scheme. Even if they do, the design
requires the Government to 'pick winners' rather than letting the market decide
and as such imposes a high administrative burden on the Government.
5.127
The committee agrees with evidence that the Emissions Reduction Fund is
not an adequate substitute for the carbon pricing mechanism. The committee
considers that the Direct Action Plan and Emissions Reduction Fund are a
significant step backwards for climate policy in Australia. The only conclusion
that can be made is that the Government is paying lip service to the science of
climate change. A Government that truly accepted the science of climate change
would not put forward such a flawed, inadequate and irresponsible 'fig leaf' policy.
5.128
Nevertheless, the committee recognises the evidence that, although the
Emissions Reduction Fund is not a stand-alone solution, it could be supported
if it were part of a range of measures to reduce Australia's greenhouse gas
emissions, including a carbon pricing mechanism and the Renewable Energy Target.
However, the committee is concerned as to whether the Emissions Reduction Fund
is an appropriate and cost‑effective use of taxpayer's money and
considers that the design issues discussed in the next chapter would need to be
adequately addressed.
Recommendation 10
5.129
The committee recommends that the Emissions Reduction Fund not be
substituted for the carbon pricing mechanism.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page