Minority Report - Australian Democrats
Broadcasting
Services Amendment (Media Ownership) Bill 2006
Broadcasting Legislation Amendment
(Digital Television) Bill 2006
Communications Legislation Amendment
(Enforcement Powers) Bill 2006
Television
Licence Fees Amendment Bill 2006
OUR DEMOCRACY IS NOT PROTECTED
Key illustrations of the point
The Minister for Communications[1]
and other Government figures have tried in various ways to answer the charge
that the Coalition’s proposed new weak cross-media rules will result in an
excessive and dangerous concentration of media power in a few hands, by
pointing to the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) as the
safeguard. Under the existing provisions of the Trade Practices Act (TPA)
preserving or enhancing the democratic institution of the fourth estate is not
a matter that the ACCC will concern itself with:
Senator MURRAY— ... As you would be aware, a great deal of
commentary, particularly political commentary, concerns the issue of whether
further media concentration, or indeed these changes, would advance the health
of our Australian democracy. Just so that we have it on the record, when you
consider a merger proposition in the media industry in future you will not
consider the issue of whether it will contribute to the health of our
Australian democracy, will you?
Mr Samuel—No, we will not.[2]
And for any members of the public foolish enough to think
that corporate self-interest and manipulated information and opinion might be
uncommon in the Australian media – here is a reality check:
Senator MURRAY— ... I want to know whether your
alliance has done any research to establish to what extent media proprietors
direct their editors and reporting staff to a particular line on matters which
are of interest to those proprietors.
Mr Warren—One of the interesting things that came out of
the Roy Morgan Crikey! survey of journalists that we did ... was on that subject.
One of the questions asked people whether they had ever been requested to
report in a way that favoured the political line of their employer, and then
there was a second question about whether they had ever been required to report
in a way that favoured the corporate line of their employer. About 50 per cent
of people said that they had been required to report in a way that favoured the
corporate line of their employer, and that does not surprise me. A much smaller
group—less than 20 per cent, I think—said that they had been required to report
in a way that favoured the political line of their employer, and that does not
surprise me either.[3]
Journalists are simply employees
There is a conflict between journalism and media, between a
profession and a job, between a calling as a member of the fourth estate and
the usual requirements of employment.
The community at large might sometimes expect too much from
journalists, expecting them to behave in a manner consistent with a higher
calling, the freedom of the press, and a willingness to pursue truth regardless
of personal cost; and to behave in accordance with the ethics values and
principles of the fourth estate. In contrast, the reality of life is that
journalists have to make a living, and are required as employees to do the job
required of them in an industry like any other, where business has to make a
profit.
Of course not all media is a for-profit business, far from
it, as the ABC, SBS and community media attest, but most journalists and
editors are employees, subject to the usual pressures to make a living and to
meet their family obligations. Such pressures constrain independence and
freedom of action. That is why journalists’ unions and codes of conduct are
important safeguards. No one should be surprised either, that employees do as
they are told. In any enterprise not to do as you are instructed risks your
job. The following interchange was instructive, and amplifies the earlier quote
I highlighted:
Senator MURRAY—It can be said that journalists are simply
employees and that employees do what they are told. It has been said to me by
some journalists privately that they have been told to write and run a
particular line with respect to interests that matter to the proprietors, which
does not surprise me. I want to know whether your alliance has done any
research to establish to what extent media proprietors direct their editors and
reporting staff to a particular line on matters which are of interest to those
proprietors.
Mr Warren—One of the interesting things that came out of
the Roy Morgan Crikey! survey of journalists that we did, that Senator Wortley
talked about, was on that subject. One of the questions asked people whether
they had ever been requested to report in a way that favoured the political
line of their employer, and then there was a second question about whether they
had ever been required to report in a way that favoured the corporate line of
their employer. About 50 per cent of people said that they had been required to
report in a way that favoured the corporate line of their employer, and that
does not surprise me. A much smaller group—less than 20 per cent, I think—said
that they had been required to report in a way that favoured the political line
of their employer, and that does not surprise me either. But it is very
concrete evidence that there is a sense in the industry that people are expected
to take particularly the corporate line—and it tends to be more the corporate
line than a political line, except sometimes when the two overlap. So that is
pretty compelling evidence, I think, that there is a deep belief within the
industry that there is an expectation that people will understand what the
corporate line is and will report accordingly.[4]
So about half of the journalists said that they had been
required to report in a way that favoured the corporate line of their employer,
and one in five had been required to report in a way that favoured the
political line of their employer. I would give odds that the pressure on
editors and management to ‘toe the line’ is much higher.
You only have to have observed the generally carefully
managed media response to these Bills, with a few exceptions that do not reach
the mass market, to realise that the media corporates overall are determined
not to give this issue much play to mass audiences by alerting Australians to
the importance of what is happening and how it will affect them.
It seems very hard to find ways to combat all this. So from
the vital democratic ‘fourth estate’ perspective the only way to protect a
diversity of opinion, news-gathering, information and influence, is to ensure a
diversity of meaningful or real voices, a diversity of media types, and a
diversity of journalists and owners, and by maximising competition and
restricting, even reducing, cross-media ownership.
That requires parliamentarians to reject those elements of
this package that are likely to reduce competition and reduce the variety of
opinion, to recognise the long-term dangers and eschew any perceived short-term
self interest.
Mr Beecher—From experience, the cross-media
rules are the only mechanism to guarantee diversity of journalism. We are
talking about a diversity in this country that is already very fragile.[5]
THE BILLS
Poor process
The Australian Democrats are and were
very supportive of this Senate Committee inquiry into the Broadcasting Services
Amendment (Media Ownership) Bill 2006 (the Media Ownership Bill) and related
Bills. Although the Committee benefited from balanced judicious and considerate
chairing from Senator Eggleston under
constrained circumstances, nevertheless the inquiry process has been poor.
Since the Coalition won control of
the Senate numbers in July 2005 the Government have moved to progressively
reduce the effectiveness of previous Senate mechanisms of accountability and
review. Knowing that it must at least satisfy some of its own backbenchers, the
Executive does just enough to allow for some Committee review, but
attitudinally, it is often quite apparent that it is just going through the
motions.
This Inquiry, like many others
under a now domineering Coalition, has been forced into too short a time frame.
The Inquiry has been characterised
by too short a time for advertising and the writing of submissions; for
Senators to read all the submissions; for the hearings themselves; for
questions on notice to be answered; and for the writing of reports. The short
time for submissions may be less of a problem for the mega-media groups that
have been lobbying the Coalition and have ready material to hand. It may be
less of a problem for witnesses with deep pockets and extensive resources, such
as the business sector, so the big end of town is probably catered for. But
this process effectively restricts the evidence that can be encouraged and
adduced from academics, other interested parties, and members of the public.
Having been part of the Senate vote that allowed this
disgraceful state of affairs, the Coalition members of the Committee came face
to face with its consequences. For instance the disagreement between Senators
Joyce and Brandis[6]
was a direct consequence of the ridiculous state of affairs whereby the six
Coalition members present shared ten or so minutes per witness.
This is complex legislation that
requires more time to assess. Secondly, the Senate deserves to be treated with
more respect, not just because it represents the whole of the Australian people
(unlike the Government, which is comprised of two political parties), but
because when it performs its proper role it is a bulwark against excessive and
self-interested Executive power.
Only two things can change this
state of affairs – either for Coalition Senators (and by extension, all
Senators) to promote the Parliament over Party, which seems unlikely, or for
the Government to lose control of the Senate numbers at the next federal
election.
The four bills as a package
Broadly speaking, the Media Ownership Bill will remove
certain broadcasting-specific restrictions on foreign investment in Australia’s
media sector, and permit cross-media mergers that are currently prohibited.
This is the Bill that is most contentious.
The Broadcasting Legislation Amendment (Digital Television)
Bill 2006 (the Digital TV Bill) is a multi-faceted bill that seeks to advance
technical and innovative aspects of the digital television and commercial
television broadcasting regime.
The Communications Legislation Amendment (Enforcement
Powers) Bill 2006 (the Enforcement Powers Bill) strengthens the enforcement and
regulatory powers of the Australian Communication and Media Authority (ACMA).
The Television Licence Fees Amendment Bill 2006 (the Fees
Bill) makes licence fee amendments consequent to the Digital TV Bill.
As the Australian Democrats have
pointed out on a number of occasions, we do not oppose media industry reform.
In fact we strongly support the modernisation and improvement of statute and
regulation with respect to the media industry, predicated on the introduction
of greater competition and meaningful diversity.
Much of the technology for media delivery in the future (and
that future is not far distant) will be on telecommunications platforms. That
being the case, it is essential that for telecommunications and media, we
establish guaranteed, affordable services available to all but the remotest
Australians and enforced through legislated customer service obligations.
For the rest, the market needs to be as free and open as
possible. We need to distinguish between consumer needs and political or
societal needs. Consumer needs are satisfied by a free rein being allowed for
new technology and a maximum variety of product types. That is best guaranteed
through few barriers to entry and through encouraging real competition.
THE MEDIA OWNERSHIP BILL AND RELATED ISSUES
Greater competition and diversity
We Democrats recognise that the
technological and market changes which have occurred in the media industry over
the past 10 years, (and in technology at increasing speed over the last five years),
make it imperative that media law and regulation keep pace with the market and
technology, and create a sensible and effective forward-looking regulatory
environment for the future.
If we are to have media markets freed from oligopoly, this
Government must pursue policies to increase diversity of views and voices. If we are to have a fair and open society, this Government
must pursue policies to increase diversity of views and voices. It must improve
the use of and access to new technology, such as digital and broadband; it must
ensure open access to media content; it must ensure that there is an adequate
level of local and Australian content; and it must protect the independence and
freedom of journalists and the media. Failure to protect diversity of
viewpoints is a failure to protect the necessary public debate that makes our
democracy function.
There is the question of whether
these bills should be phased in. The Democrats believe there is a good
case for arguing that the cross media laws should not be changed until full
digitisation has been achieved and more spectrum is available to enable new
entrants, and the range of new services provided by new technology is more
mature and utilised by more consumers.
The Government has no evidence to
support their assertion that these reforms will not lead to a concentration of
the media market. They exaggerate the beneficial market impact that the
internet and ‘new media’ has and will have on credible information supply in
contrast to traditional media.
In November 2005, a Roy Morgan poll found that 48 per cent
of Australians get their main source of information from television, 22 per
cent from newspapers, 19 per cent from radio and only 8 per cent from the
internet. The internet market share data from ACNeilsen shows that Australian
content on the internet is now more concentrated than in the 'old' media of
newspapers, magazines, radio and TV. Clearly an
informed professional independent 'traditional' diverse media is still
necessary:
Mr Samuel—We think the internet is simply a distribution
channel. It has not shown any significant signs at this point in time of
providing a greater diversity of credible information and news and commentary.
There is talk all the time, as we have discussed on previous occasions, of the
establishment of web logs and the like, but in terms of credible news and
information—I say this without having done what I said we would always do,
which is conduct a detailed analysis—based on all the reports that one reads,
you could probably conclude that at this point of time, at the early stages of
the development of the internet, the primary sources of news, information and
the like still are your mainstream sources: the ABC, News.com and Fairfax. They
tend to be the primary sources of credible, timely news and information and
discussion.[7]
The Government has tried to focus on how this package
affects consumers, but more important is how it affects our democracy.
Likewise the submissions before the Senate Committee from media owners
overwhelmingly concentrated on their economic needs, not Australia’s
need for an energetic independent and diverse fourth estate. One witness’ body
language was something to behold in his barely suppressed rage that Senators
were more concerned with fourth estate issues than media business issues.
The lesson is that media owners and investors' self-interest
must be tempered by the national and public interest.
The freedom of the press to report whatever and however they
need has long been recognised as absolutely vital to democracy, and this
freedom is most effective and relevant when there are a variety of diverse
views of substance. Modern concentrated media power is such that if that power is
not to be abused, it needs to be dispersed and multiplied, and not concentrated
further.
Evidence to the Inquiry was that Australia already has one
of the most concentrated media sectors in the democratic world:
Mr Beecher—...Currently in Australia most
journalism of significance is in the hands of five families plus the Fairfax
organisation. Let us be specific about that: in the regional areas, it is the O’Reilly
family and the John B Fairfax family, and in the metropolitan areas it is the
Murdoch, Packer and Stokes families and the Fairfax organisation, which used to
be family owned and is now institutionally owned. So you have six unelected
groups—five of them families—and they are the gatekeepers of news and opinion
in this country.
....
The consolidation of the media industry in this country has been
going on for years. In the 1980s there were 13 daily newspapers in the five
capital cities and they had nine different owners. Today there are seven daily
newspapers—almost half—and they have four owners. All the major regional city
newspapers—Cairns, Townsville and all of those big places—are owned by four
companies: News, Fairfax, APN and Rural Press. The last of the majors, in
Albury, fell a few months ago. Most of the internet news and commentary sites—apart
from Crikey, really—are owned by the same people. So they own the lot. It is
the most concentrated media ownership in the Western world. We all know that,
we talk about it, and yet we are sitting here talking about concentrating it
even further. [8]
My clear impression of many media owners is that they fear
too many competitors – witness their opposition to a fourth free-to-air TV
channel – and many in the community fear too few media owners. Both from the
perspective of consumers and our democracy the central issue is that we need
more competition, less concentration and more diversity in all media markets.
Media diversity and independence are critical to the public
debate that makes our democracy function well. Any concentration of the market
in a few manipulative hands will reduce diversity in views and voices. It may
also reduce quality and Australian content. If those were the outcomes then
that would not be good for consumers or our democracy.
Therefore the starting point for revising these proposals has
to be the regulators – the ACCC, whose role is to decide on mergers and
acquisitions; ACMA, whose role is to apply and enforce standards; and the
Foreign Investment Review Board (FIRB) whose role is to determine foreign
ownership levels.
A parable – measuring media power
From the
Ezine Crikey.com.au[9] Item 12. Measuring media power
Christian Kerr writes:
...
In dealing with media, they are dealing with powers much greater
than they are.
How do we know? Back in 2004, John McMillan and Pablo Zoido of
the Stanford Graduate School of Business published an ingenious study of the
checks and balances that underpin democracy. The abstract says it all:
Which of the democratic checks and
balances – opposition parties, the judiciary, a free press – is the
most critical? Peru has the full set of democratic institutions. In the 1990s,
the secret-police chief Vladimiro Montesinos systematically undermined them all
with bribes. We quantify the checks using the bribe prices. Montesinos paid
television-channel owners about 100 times what he paid judges and politicians.
One single television channel's bribe was four times larger than the total of
the opposition politicians' bribes. By revealed preference, the strongest check
on the government's power was the news media.
Montesinos kept meticulous records. He
required recipients of his bribes to sign receipts. He routinely videotaped
himself doling out funds and explaining exactly what he expected of those whom
he paid.
McMillan and Zoida used the records to compile what they
described as price list for bribery – a yardstick that could be used to measure
the strength of the democratic countervailing forces that Montesinos was
undermining.
They discovered a clear hierarchy of power. A politician, for
example, was worth slightly more than a judge. But the most powerful force of
all was an owner of a television station. They commanded bribes about a hundred
times higher than a politician's.
"Each channel takes $2 million monthly, but it is the only
way," Montesinos told one of his henchmen. "That is why we have won,
because we have sacrificed in this way."
Why did television matter so much? Montesinos explained on tape:
"What do I care about El Comercio? They have an 80,000 print run.
80,000 newspapers is sh-t. What worries me is Channel Four...It reaches two
million people."
In the end, a small independent television station, one that
Montesinos had never bribed, aired the tape that brought the regime down.
The Senate committee is due to report back on 6 October. They
should look at McMillan and Zoida as part of their deliberations. If they’re
not going to take public interest into account, they should consider their own
self interest – and if they want to give more powers to forces already up to
100 times stronger than they are.
Free to Air television (FTAs)
If television channels are the most powerful of all (as the
parable above suggests) – or even if we just accept that television is a very
powerful media market – should Australia be looking to increase competition in
this market?
Senator MURRAY—In one word, do you support having
a fourth free-to-air channel introduced on television?
Mr Falloon—We do not. [10]
The Productivity Commission (PC) supports the ban on entry
of new television stations being lifted.[11]
Other witnesses at the hearing were also of a different view to Mr Falloon and
supported a fourth free-to-air channel:
Mr Warren— ... The second thing that could be done—and
which we believe should be done—is that the free-to-air networks, who have been
given this spectrum for nothing, should have a legislative mandate requiring
them to broadcast different programming—not just time shifted programming—with
all the normal quota restrictions and requirements that are on a free-to-air
network on one of their digital bands. We also support a fourth commercial TV
licence.[12]
Senator IAN MACDONALD—As I
understand your proposal, instead of having a B channel you would have a fourth
free-to-air network.
Mr Brown—Yes. There would be a fourth free-to-air
network, which would be simultaneous analog and digital to, say, 2010 and then
there would be a switch to digital two years before the incumbents—in other
words, it would switch in 2010 and 9,7 and 10 would cross over in 2012.[13]
Senator MURRAY—Mr Williams, it has been put to us
by witnesses that a fourth free-to-air channel should be issued. Do you support
that or not, or do you not have a view on it?
Mr Williams—I have a personal view. My
company does not have a formal view.
Ms Richards—ASTA supports it.[14]
Rather shamelessly, the Government have made it quite clear
that it will not agree to a fourth FTA channel, or allow the independent regulator
ACMA to make that judgement on its merits.
It is hardly a matter of viability. As Mr Beecher said:
Mr Beecher— ... Are the media companies
ailing? Do we have an industry that has economic malfunction? Here are some
facts. In the past year, profits in the media industry were higher than ever
before. This is a booming industry. It is an industry that makes profit
margins—that is, the percentage of profits to revenue—that are higher than
almost all other industries in Australia. There is only one other industry in Australia
with higher profit margins.
The average profit margin of public companies in this country is
around 15 to 17 per cent—that is, $15 to $17 in every $100 of revenue is
profit. The media industry average is 24 per cent. It is the second highest
only after resources, and the reason resources is higher is that the capital
requirement is stratospheric and therefore the risk-reward ratio is higher.[15]
If then a fourth FTA is out of the question under this
Government, the only other option to introduce more competition in television
is in community TV. Community and suburban/regional press and community
broadcasting are able to supplement commercial radio and the big newspapers in
an impressive manner. Community TV needs a ‘leg-up’ to do the same.
Promoting Community Television
The main committee report strongly supports the community
television sector and the Australian Democrats fully endorse the committee's
recommendation in this regard.
The community television sector is a growing and alternative
voice to Australia's mainstream media. It provides much needed diversity and
local content in a market that will increasingly tend towards greater
concentration and reduced competition as a result of the government's changes
to media ownership. Community broadcasting is fundamentally different from the
commercial and national broadcasting sectors. It is media produced by
communities, for communities. It promotes the principles of access and
participation, volunteerism, diversity, independence and localism. The sector
caters to a diverse range of communities of interest, from core ethnic,
indigenous, and gay and lesbian communities, to youth, religious, senior
citizens, arts, fine music, Australian music and other special interest
cohorts.
In March 2006, there were 7 licensed community television
services. These are Channel 31 Adelaide, Briz 31 Brisbane, Linc TV Lismore,
Channel 31 Melbourne, Bushvision Mount Gambier, TVS (Television Sydney) and
Access 31 Perth. Community television in Australia has more than 260 member
groups, 3200 volunteers and 50 paid staff; provides training in all areas of
television production to more than 500 Australians every year; has a combined
annual turnover of more than $5 million and a cumulative monthly audience reach
of more than 3 million.
On numerous occasions the Government has expressed its
support for community TV and in particular its role in providing local content.
For example the (then) Minister for Communications, Information Technology and
the Arts, Senator the Hon Richard Alston noted:
CTV plays a valuable role in meeting local needs for
information, education and entertainment, providing an outlet for innovative
and niche programming, and opening opportunities for enthusiastic volunteers to
train in television production, programming and management.[16]
According to the Community Broadcasting Association of
Australia survey of the four metropolitan CTV stations on air for the duration
of 2005 revealed that every week these stations broadcast:
-
164 hours of locally produced programming;
-
61 hours of news and current affairs programming;
-
37.5 hours of religious programming;
-
33 hours of Ethnic programming;
-
30.5 hours of youth programming;
-
27.5 hours of arts programming;
-
21 hours of programming for new, emerging and refugee
communities;
-
19 hours of educational programming;
-
17 hours of sports programming;
-
7 hours of programming for people with a disability; and
-
6.5 hours of Indigenous programming.[17]
However, primarily due to the relatively high cost of
producing audiovisual content, the community TV sector is not able to provide
the same level of local content, news and information as community radio and
community-based newspapers.
To complement the committee's community television
recommendation I believe that the government should strongly support community
television to drive a greater level of local content and diversity on community
TV broadcasters. As the cost of producing local TV content and a lack of access
to funding are the primary restraints on greater local content in community TV,
I suggest that the government consider the following policy options.
Firstly, Government grants to support local content on
community TV: The Australian Democrats believe there is scope for some
modest level of government financial support for the production of local TV
content on community TV. Because of their limited financial capacity due to
their non-profit and community based nature, the government should put in place
a government grants scheme directed at supporting and promoting local TV
content on community TV. By providing a modest level of funding to community TV
providers the government would ensure that local communities have the ability
to enhance the local content and diversity that is an inherent attribute of
community TV.
Second, an industry levy to support local content on
community TV: Another policy option that the government should consider
is a low level media industry levy aimed at supporting local content on
community TV. The levy could be targeted at those commercial media
organisations that merge as a result of the changes to the cross media rules as
these organisations would benefit most from the government's decision to allow
greater concentration of ownership. As the commercial media conglomerates would
dwarf the size of the community TV providers the levy would necessarily be very
small, perhaps a fraction of a percentage point.
Third, broadening sponsorship arrangements on
community TV: The Democrats believe that one way to increase the
available funding to community TV providers is to allow greater flexibility in
its sponsorship arrangements. The current arrangements allow community
television licences to broadcast 7 minutes of sponsorship announcements in any
hour of broadcasting.[18]
Although it would not be desirable to see a large increase in the amount of
time dedicated to sponsorship, allowing community TV providers some degree of
flexibility in how that amount of sponsorship is allocated throughout its daily
and weekly programs may attract a greater number of sponsors.
It is also worth noting that community television may be
losing their current sponsors as a result of the uncertainty created by the
government's indecision on community televisions access to digital spectrum.
Asked whether the lack of a presence on digital TV affected their current
sponsorships, Mr Melville, General Manager, Community Broadcasting Association
of Australia responded:
...from my discussions with station managers of community
television stations I believe it to be true to say that the effect is starting
to be felt. I think some of the more savvy businesses that are seeking to
differentiate themselves in the [sponsorship market] are starting to ask
questions about where they will be in six months to a year in terms of
continuing exposure to audiences and whether they will have a place in digital.
I do not know that it has actually stopped anyone coming forward and placing
their sponsorship message on community television, but I know the question is
beginning to be asked.[19]
In this regard the Community Broadcasting Association of
Australia indicated in its submission:
While the community television (CTV) sector is not currently
broadcasting on digital, the Government has long been committed to providing
the CTV sector with access to a digital channel free-of-charge.
The Minister’s discussion paper, released in March, says that
the Government’s Digital Action Plan will reveal how this access will be
provided.[20]
The CBAA also reminded the committee of the generous support
the government currently provides to the commercial TV industry regarding the
conversion to digital TV:
Because the sector cannot afford to meet the costs of both
analogue and digital transmission, the CBAA has asked Government to fund the
costs of digital transmission during the simulcast period. The Government
currently provides $75 million per year to fund the national and commercial
broadcasters’ digital conversion costs.[21]
The ACCC and improving media competition
The very first requirement in any
matter of industry regulation is to ensure competition is protected. On the
surface the assurances that further concentration in the Australian media
industry cannot occur if the ACCC opposes mergers or acquisitions should be
reassuring. They are not.
It is not credible for the Minister to assert that the ACCC
and the Minister will control any proposed media mergers adequately, because
there are insufficient safeguards. The ‘Dawson’ bill (the Trade Practices
Legislation Amendment Bill (No. 1) 2005) will actually reduce safeguards
because it allows for forum shopping and the application of different
principles between the ACCC and the Australian Competition Tribunal.
Without very significant strengthening of the Trade
Practices Act (TPA), including section 46, and including divestiture
provisions, plus the addition of a media-specific public interest test, any
media market deregulation through this legislation seems bound to result in
reductions in real competition, and a greater concentration of media power.
I have outlined elsewhere at
length the weakness of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (TPA) with respect
to mergers and acquisitions, such as in these remarks three years ago:
... a dynamic, modern market economy means that the efficiency and
competitiveness of the market should be facilitated and that mergers,
acquisitions and takeovers should be made easier. The flip side of easing the
market for mergers, takeovers and acquisitions is a need to ensure that the
overmighty and abusive are properly constrained. I have said before that big
business roars approval at the dynamism of the American market but fiercely
condemns a major contributor to that dynamism—that is, the effects of antitrust
or divestiture laws. We need those regulatory tools in Australia. Balanced
divestiture laws are the corollary of balanced merger laws. We do not have
effective divestiture laws. It is a strange and illogical policy that can
prevent mergers to maintain effective competition but cannot require
divestiture also to maintain effective competition. [22]
The non-Government members of the March
2004 Senate Economics References Committee Report into the effectiveness of
the Trade Practices Act 1974 in protecting small business accepted the
proposition that divestiture powers were essential:
Divestiture
Divestiture powers are powers which enable a Court to order that
a dominant corporation be broken up into several smaller corporations in order
to prevent the anticompetitive domination of a market by one player.
Such powers are currently available under s.81 of the Act, but
cannot be applied to creeping acquisitions, nor to offences under s.46. The
Committee considers that the application of s.81 should be expanded, so that
divestiture becomes a remedy for other breaches of the Act, including section
46 (Misuse of market power) and any new section introduced in line with the
Committee’s recommendation 12 (relating to the regulation of creeping
acquisitions).
As divestiture is a quite severe remedy, it is appropriate to
provide “warning mechanisms” to ensure that a corporation which is expanding
its business is able to comply with its obligations under the Act. A suitable
warning mechanism could be based around a “trigger” market concentration.
This trigger should not operate as a de facto cap on
market share. Rather it would require companies proposing acquisitions in
concentrated industries to notify the ACCC. The Commission would then assess
whether the acquisition would result in a substantial lessening of competition.
The Committee notes that this already occurs in the retail grocery industry.
Recommendation 13
The Committee recommends that s.81(1) of the Act be amended
so that s.81 can be applied where a corporation is found to have contravened
section 46, section 46A, or any new section introduced to regulate creeping
acquisitions. [23]
Even the Government, which has
hardly covered itself in glory in strengthening competition laws, has accepted
the TPA needs strengthening, although it has done nothing to translate its
in-principle acceptance into legislation. The Government accepted the Senate
Economics References Committee recommendations 5, 8, 9, 16 and 17; and 3, 6 and
11 in part; all made well over two years ago.
The point is the Government seems
divorced from reality. It does not even recognise that it is simply bad policy
to introduce much looser media concentration rules without simultaneously
introducing legislation to bolster general competition law. And of course,
strengthening the TPA will benefit competition in all other sectors too.
As I’ve emphasised earlier, the
great concern with the Media Ownership Bill is the fear it will harm our
democracy through excessive concentration, a loss of diversity, and increased
abuse of media power. These are matters which concern society. These are values
matters and political matters, requiring public interest judgements. It is
worth repeating the quote at the start of this Minority Report:
Senator MURRAY— ... As you would be aware,
a great deal of commentary, particularly political commentary, concerns the
issue of whether further media concentration, or indeed these changes, would advance
the health of our Australian democracy. Just so that we have it on the record,
when you consider a merger proposition in the media industry in future you will
not consider the issue of whether it will contribute to the health of our
Australian democracy, will you?
Mr Samuel—No, we will not.[24]
All is not lost, provided the Government comes to its
senses. The ACCC and TPA as presently configured are simply not equipped to
deal with these matters at present, but in his evidence Mr Samuel made it clear
that the ACCC would be able to deal with public interest issues if there were a
law change:
Senator MURRAY— ... the only way in which
you could be obliged to take the public interest—which would include what I
would classify as social considerations, such as the health of our
democracy—into account would be for a provision to be specifically inserted
into legislation, wouldn’t it?
Mr Cassidy—I take it that you are
saying, ‘Leave aside authorisation,’ which is a public interest matter?
Senator MURRAY—That
is right.
Mr Cassidy—In considering media mergers
generally, the only way in which we could, or could be required to, take into
account the public interest would be if that was specified in legislation.
Senator MURRAY—My
judgement of the media area is that the political class have always recognised
that the ACCC is inadequate in determining these broader issues. That is why
they have introduced rules which are specific to the media area and which are governed,
effectively, from a political perspective. The restrictions on cross-media and
foreign ownership and so on are quite different to those which apply in other
industries. If you want to lessen that industry specific control, in my view
you have to increase the capacity for the ACCC as a competition regulator to
take matters like that into consideration. My question is this: do you think
that if a public interest test was required of you in issues concerning media
you would be able to develop and devise, with your usual ability ... guidelines
and methodologies which are appropriate to that task?
Mr Samuel—Tests such as that would probably be no different to
the sort of test the guidelines provide for us already in section 50. For
example, we are required to take account of regional considerations as part of
our determinations in dealing with merger matters. These are all factors that
we take into account in many senses.[25]
The Australian Democrats position
on these Bills is informed by the PC’s broadcasting report of March 2000.[26] That report looked into a range of conflicting policy
issues including convergence, media markets, protecting diversity and cultural
identity. All these issues are of great concern to the Democrats and to many
Australians.
The Government did not respond to
the complexities of the PC’s report, and certainly the Commission’s
recommendations are not reflected in the Discussion Papers issued by the
Minister for Communications, or the legislation which the Government has
presented to the Senate.
A key recommendation from the PC
was that the cross-media ownership rules should not be repealed or changed
until the following had been achieved:
-
the removal of regulatory barriers to entry, including making
spectrum available for new broadcasters;
-
the repeal of restrictions on foreign investment, ownership and
control; and
-
amending the Trade Practices Act to provide for a media-specific
public interest test to apply to mergers and acquisitions.[27]
The Democrats would add to the PC’s
list, the amendments to the TPA including the introduction of effective
divestiture powers; clarification of the meaning of a ‘substantial degree of
power in a market’ and ‘take advantage’ in section 46 to overcome existing
deficiencies; introduction of a 'financial power' consideration; and
strengthening the ACCC’s powers to prevent creeping acquisitions.
Those recommendations, if
implemented would give the TPA real teeth and afford enforceable protection
from anti-competitive abuses of market power. If those recommendations were
implemented there would be the opportunity to loosen up the present media rules
quite considerably and allow greater competition.
Instead, under the proposed
changes to the Broadcasting Services Act 1992, big media business will
get the chance to accelerate the oligopolisation of the media market. The
Democrats believe that some of the amendments in the Digital Television Bill
are long overdue and have considerable merit, but the amendments proposed to
the Media Ownership Bill cannot be agreed to until the Government implements
the PC’s recommendation regarding a public interest test, and strengthens the
TPA as outlined above.
Many witnesses agree that a
media-specific public interest test should be added to the TPA. The PC made a
number of key points in this regard.
The PC said the TPA is unable to
deal effectively with cross-media mergers and mergers between ‘old’ and ‘new’
media which could affect concentration and diversity in the ‘market for ideas’.
They said a media-specific public interest test should be added to the Act. [28]
The PC said that cross-media
rules prevent mergers among ‘old’ media companies, and will impose increasingly
severe constraints on them. They thought the rules’ effectiveness will decline
as convergence proceeds. Therefore they believed cross-media rules should be
removed once a more competitive media environment is established, that is,
when:
-
the media-specific public interest test is in place;
-
foreign investment is permitted under normal guidelines;
-
the ban on entry of new television stations is removed; and
-
a significant amount of spectrum is available for new entry.[29]
It is useful to quote the Report in full:
[Productivity
Commission] Overview
Australia could
try to extend the cross-media rules to other media, but such an approach would
become increasingly difficult to implement in a convergent world. The
Australian community will be better served by policies that encourage
contestability and entry. Given that ownership structures are changing rapidly,
the Commission recommends that a media specific public interest test be
inserted into the Trade Practices Act immediately (recommendation 10.3).[30]
...
Once the new
media-specific public interest test is in place and new entry has established a
more competitive atmosphere for Australian media, the cross-media rules should
be repealed.[31]
...
RECOMMENDATION
10.3
The Trade
Practices Act 1974 should be amended immediately to include a media-specific
public interest test which would apply to all proposed media mergers. The test
would be administered by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission,
and require that the commission seek ABA input on social, cultural and
political dimensions of the public interest.
RECOMMENDATION
10.4
After the
following conditions have been met:
·
removal of regulatory barriers to entry in broadcasting (s. 28
and the s. 23 non-technical criteria), together with the availability of
spectrum for new broadcasters;
·
repeal of BSA restrictions on foreign investment, ownership and
control; and
·
amendment to the Trade Practices Act 1974 to provide for a
media-specific public interest test to apply to mergers and acquisitions; the
cross-media rules should be removed.[32]
There is also the question of what
will constitute a market in the new media landscape. ACCC Chairman Graeme Samuel has already suggested in a number of speeches that the
definition of ‘market’ may have to be reviewed in some aspects of the media
industry. Rather than dividing the industry into radio, television, newspapers
and internet, he says it may have to be looked at in terms of sports markets,
classified advertising markets, and so on, so that it revolves around a
question of content rather than a question of delivery platform.
These issues remain unaddressed by this legislation and many
of the provisions of the Bills are something of a knee-jerk reaction to certain
examples of media failure in regional areas brought to the attention of the
Liberal Party by their Coalition partners, the Nationals. In particular, this
is true of the Local Content Plans, which require licensees to demonstrate how
they are meeting local content licence conditions and includes provision for
emergency warning broadcasts and other matters. Some regional witnesses warned
against an ineffective bureaucratic approach here. Media commentator, Mr Jock
Given acknowledged that while aimed at laudable goals, the regional radio
localism requirements:
...involve a troubling level of detailed intervention in the
day-to-day operations of commercial broadcasters, including their physical
facilities. They are framed negatively, to ‘maintain’ rather than ‘enhance’ or
‘encourage’ localism, and are activated not as part of a general policy
applicable in all situations, but only where a trigger event occurs that might
give rise to special fears about cutbacks in local content or presence.[33]
WARNER, Ms Joan - A lot of our broadcasters—and you will
hear from a number of them tomorrow, I believe—are quite concerned about going
back to the bad old days where a bureaucrat comes in and demands a book of 10
pages and then decides with the stroke of a pen whether it is acceptable or
not. ... So we are just harking back to the pre-BSA days when everything was a
beauty pageant and it was a lot of time and a lot of effort on every
broadcaster to provide that so the bureaucrat would tick it off.[34]
The FIRB and foreign ownership
restrictions
In the media ownership bill, the Government proposes the
removal of media-specific foreign ownership and control restrictions in the Broadcasting
Services Act 1992 (BSA), and the discontinuation of newspaper-specific
foreign ownership limits under Australia’s Foreign Investment Policy.
The media would be retained as a ‘sensitive sector’ under the Foreign
Investment Policy.
In principle the Australian Democrats could agree with the
lifting of foreign ownership restrictions to enable more competition in the
market, subject to some important caveats. We do agree that it is retained as a
‘sensitive sector’ under the Foreign Investment Policy.
There are many issues to consider here. Firstly, if other
countries close out their media or parts of their media to competition from Australia,
why should Australia allow those countries to buy Australian media outlets? If
non citizens in one country are prohibited from owning or operating TV stations
or are subject to ownership caps or other barriers to entry, as they are
reported to do, why should non-resident foreigners from those countries be
allowed to run Australian TV stations or other media?.
The logic here is that only those countries that open their
markets to us should get the reciprocal privileges here.
The next question is one that cannot be avoided. Nationalism
is an issue in Australia. Australians do not seem to concern themselves much
with foreign media ownership that already exists, from relatively similar
countries like Canada, the USA and Great Britain. Based on what I read see and
hear, I expect they may be less comfortable with some types of ownership from
other countries.
Australia cannot discriminate by race or country. If foreign
ownership is to be allowed it has to be open to all. This is well understood by
some witnesses:
Senator MURRAY— ... The question I want to ask you
concerns foreign ownership. It is your position, isn’t it, that foreign
ownership of media in Australia should not be restricted other than through the
normal processes of the Foreign Investment Review Board?
Mr Falloon—Correct.
Senator MURRAY—And your position is, isn’t it, that with
respect to those issues that you might describe as nationalism they should be
catered for by local content rules and rules about the coverage of news and
information with respect to Australia? Is that correct?
Mr Falloon—Again, correct.
Senator MURRAY—And in principle, of course, opening the
market to foreign owners means that it does not matter whether it is an owner
from France, the United States, Great Britain, Canada, China, India or, indeed,
Iran?
Mr Falloon—Again, correct.[35]
Of course even the new rules will prevent one owner owning
all TV media for instance but it would not prevent one owner owning a key or
dominant TV station and 70% of the major newspapers:
Senator JOYCE—With regard to your broader critique on
globalisation and your belief that everything should be put up for sale and
that anybody should be able to buy it, could I run this past you: if everything
is up for sale and anybody can buy it, and al-Jazeera buys the lot—everything
that is in Australia—would you be happy with that outcome?
Mr Berg—No, not necessarily, but I do not think that
could ever possibly happen.
Senator JOYCE—Under your proposal, yes, it could.
Mr Berg—No, only if we fix a point in time. If al-Jazeera
buys up absolutely everything, I am sure that there would be individuals who
would like to break that al-Jazeera monopoly by setting up some other.[36]
Perhaps. I would only be comforted if there were changes to
the TPA strengthening it and including divestiture provisions (see my comments
on the TPA and the ACCC above).
ACMA and standards
ACMA powers
The Communications Legislation
Amendment (Enforcement Powers) Bill 2006 is the bill that strengthens ACMA's
powers.
The TPA is the legislation which
regulates competition and consumer needs as enforced by the ACCC, and oversees
mergers and acquisitions. However, ACMA as the media industry-specific
regulator which must have the necessary powers to promote genuine real and
meaningful diversity of economic, political, social and other media voices. If
these two regulators are properly resourced, have interconnecting provisions
where necessary and are given the appropriate powers then there is a chance
that the media landscape of the future will adequately provide the information,
social, political and entertainment needs of future generations.
Unfortunately this legislation
does not give ACMA sufficient appropriate powers to achieve this and the TPA
remains inadequate to deal with the competition and consumer issues which are
raised by this legislation.
ACMA needs to have its role boosted, so that it can
interlink with the ACCC more effectively, in mergers that it considers likely
to be anti-competitive. The exchange below elucidates this point:
Senator BRANDIS—It has to be the ACCC, doesn’t it?
Ms Beal—Not necessarily. In my view there
is also a way to give stronger direction to ACMA in these reforms. I suggest
that both regulators are given clear statutory guidance in relation to ensuring
that their different roles—they have different roles, of course—are clear.
Senator BRANDIS—Let me just make sure that we have
this straight. At the moment, ACMA has no power to prevent an anti-competitive
merger within any of the forms of media organisation over which it has
jurisdiction and it is not proposed to give ACMA such powers in these bills, is
it?
Ms Beal—No.
Senator BRANDIS—So your understanding is that the
only way in which that could be done is under the existing law with the ACCC
seeking an injunction under section 80 of the Trade Practices Act for an
apprehended breach of section 50 of the Trade Practices Act. Is that right?
Ms Beal—I had not thought about it quite so technically.
I had been striving to demonstrate ways that content could be brought into the
picture when considering the point of mergers because it is so important to the
public interest. If the quality and type of content that Australians have
access to are going to be affected by a merger, that ought to be something that
the ACCC can take into account and protect against. We have had preliminary
consultations with the ACCC in exploring this issue which suggest that content
would not be a key focus in the minds of the ACCC when carrying out their role
of enforcing the Trade Practices Act in relation to competitive conduct.[37]
Local Content
With respect to local Australian
content the Australian Democrats support the submission put forward by the
Screen Producers Association of Australia (SPAA) regarding assistance to
produce local content. There is no point in regulating for a certain level of
Australian content on television and radio, when the financial conditions
surrounding the production of that local content are too difficult to make it a
sensible business proposition.
Everyone accepts that cheap
imported American product which has proven its ability to attract viewers in
other marketplaces, is much more likely to be purchased by profit-conscious FTA
broadcasters than perhaps more costly Australian locally written and produced
content. Therefore if there is to be more and better local content for FTA
television stations or digital channels to show on the different delivery
platforms then conditions conducive to the production of such content should be
implemented as soon as possible. As Bill Gates is said to have once pointed out, ‘content is king’ and
although he was talking about the internet, he also acknowledged that it was
true of broadcasting.
If Australians are to continue to
hear Australian voices, across a range of media platforms, then the
recommendations of the SPAA regarding changes to the taxation system need to be
given consideration by the government:
Senator MURRAY— ...The question is: if you open up
foreign ownership in the way we have just discussed, do you think that we need
additional protection supplied to ensure that there is sufficient local
content, localism and Australian character and that that area is protected more
than it has been? I ask you to recognise in your response that there has been
something, I think, of a community reaction to what is regarded as an excessive
Americanisation of our entertainment and information. I do not know what weight
to put on it, but I get that feeling.
Mr Falloon—I think if you look at the free television
industry first, on local content, you see that there are rules in place: the
transmission plus the drama quota. We think they are essential; they have been
an important part of the whole mix. The issue where there has been some debate
in the past years, which unfortunately now is a matter of fact, is that in the
new industries that are clearly growing, namely the internet and pay
television, the local content requirements under those rules as part of the
free trade agreement have been fixed at 20 per cent maximum. The rule on pay TV
is only at 10 per cent currently, but it cannot go above 20 per cent. So, as I
was saying to you before, it is important in these rules that we keep it vibrant.
It is not just because of the debate you hear from some people about having
completely free and open competition in every market. In the television
industry in this country, regulation has played a part for 50 years to get a
position where we are the envy of most countries for the amount of local
content that is on free television for viewers for free. We have got a
fantastic system; we should be very proud of that system.
As new technology is coming down the pipe, you will never get in
the new media more than 20 per cent under legislation that has now passed. That
is why I keep saying that we need to be mindful of what part local content
plays in this package of rules. As we move through the transition, whether we
continue to have localism and local content as part of our mix will continue to
be an important part of consideration for legislators such as you. Going
forward, free television is the only area that is going to be able to deliver
that, by definition.[38]
Telstra and telecommunications
The ACCC needs stronger regulatory powers, not just specific
to media but to cover telecommunications, because the ACCC needs the power to
regulate both the content and the pipes that deliver it, to achieve that. The
media proposals package fails to acknowledge the pivotal role of the
telecommunications industry in the provision of media content and access in the
future, and that is a big hole that should have been addressed.
The big hole in the media proposals package is that there is
no mention of Telstra and how its future privatisation feeds into this debate.
You cannot debate media regulation, access and content in a vacuum that
excludes telecommunications. You must also debate telecommunications
infrastructure and access along with it.
Competition has improved in the telecommunications markets
over the years, especially in mobile phones, but Telstra, with its ownership of
the copper network and Hybrid Fibre Coax (HFC) cable (used for pay TV and
broadband delivery), is still the dominant player in most other telecommunications
markets. Telstra also has a significant share in Foxtel, giving Telstra a
potentially dominant position in the new media market.
In the 21st century one of the most important delivery
systems of media content is the internet, which is why telecommunications and
media are absolutely intertwined. It provides access to the most diverse range
of media content, but much of rural and regional Australia will miss out on
this access because of the lack of telecommunications infrastructure to deliver
high speed broadband access. Recently Telecommunications expert Paul Budde told
Meet the Press that it is likely Telstra will only roll out fibre to
metropolitan areas, leaving rural areas in the lurch.
When the sale of Telstra was negotiated, the media side of
Telstra was neglected. It is a pity nobody reminded the National Party
negotiators that telecommunications is the way to deliver media diversity in
the 21st century.
The Democrats have argued time and time again that Telstra
should at a minimum be forced to divest Foxtel and its HFC cable. This stance
supports the ACCC’s view. This would open up more competition in the market.
The ACCC has argued that Telstra, in protecting the revenue of both the copper
wire and the HFC network, will only invest in services that would cannibalise
the revenue of the other network.
Ideally the Democrats say that for fair and transparent
competition and parity for rural Australians the Government must separate the
wholesale access network from the retail business and retain ownership of the
infrastructure. Ownership of the HFC cable could be retained in this case, or
divested to raise revenue for fibre roll-out.
THE DIGITAL TV BILL AND RELATED ISSUES
The motive behind the Broadcasting Legislation Act (Digital
Television) Bill 2006 (Digital TV Bill) is to set up conditions which are,
hopefully, conducive to the take up of digital television, and to open up media
markets to some competition brought about by new technologies. These are
laudable aims and the Australian Democrats agree with the majority report on
some of the matters arising from this Bill which came before the Committee.
However, although the Digital TV Bill contains some aspects with which the
Australian Democrats agree, it also contains aspects which do not promote
diversity of voices, or provide conditions in which an effective fourth estate
can flourish as part of the democratic process.
The Australian Democrats wish to raise three issues that it
believes are of great concern in relation to the Digital TV Bill, namely:
-
the transfer of decision-making power from the ACMA to the
Minister in relation to the grant of new commercial television licences;
-
the Minister's power of veto over the grant of licences in the
non-broadcasting services band; and
-
the need for adequate funding for the national broadcasters to
enable them to provide high quality multi-channel services now that genre
restrictions have been lifted.
Transfer of decision making power from ACMA to the Minister
The Australian Democrats strongly oppose this change. The
decision to grant a commercial television broadcasting licence should be made
by an independent regulatory body, it should not be something that the Minister
can be lobbied on by the big media owners.
The Government has not articulated any good policy reason
for a fourth commercial TV licence to be excluded from the discussion, except
another station would impact negatively on the revenue streams of the FTA
commercial networks in the market.
The submission by the Media, Entertainment and Arts Alliance
(MEAA) captured the folly of the Government's proposals:
The Alliance does not support the Government removing the
capacity for the regulator to determine licence allocation. It is a central
part of ACMA’s role as an independent regulator and it should retain this
decision-making capacity.
In announcing that it will assume the decision-making capacity
to allocate a fourth licence, the Government has announced that it will not do
so.
Again, the Alliance is at a loss to understand why the Government
is so averse to opening up the broadcasting industry to competition.
The oft claimed arguments in defence of the Government’s
position rely on the assumption that to do so would threaten the viability of
the incumbents because it would fracture the advertising pie, a pie that is
already under threat from new media.
These arguments fly in the face of reality.
According to research undertaken by Free TV Australia – the
association that represents the free to air commercial television broadcasters
– 'seven out of ten media planners and buyers believe that there are even more
opportunities to engage with viewers on Free TV than there were five years ago'
and '80% also agree that having ads on free to air television strengthens the
performance of [their] campaign in other media.[39]
The Government is again seen to be pandering to vested
interests, and not dealing sufficiently with policy issues. The common
perception is that while free and open competition is the claimed mantra of
this government, in reality that only applies until it impacts on selected
media mates.
The Australian Democrats do not believe there is a
discretionary role for the Minister in competition matters. Evidence of the
undesirability of this practice was recently borne out by the Treasurer’s
behaviour in relation to access to rail networks in the North West of Western
Australia.[40]
ACMA is the regulator of media matters in Australia and it
should be up to that body, which presumably is (or if not, should be) made up
of appropriately skilled impartial and independent people, to investigate these
types of matters and to come to an objective conclusion which is based on the
application of evidence.
The Minister's power of veto
The Digital TV Bill provides a power to the Minister to veto
an application made to ACMA for a new commercial television broadcasting
licence outside the BSB (under section 40 of the BSA) on the basis that the
allocation of the licence would be likely to be contrary to the public
interest.
Again this is a decision that should not be able to be
vetoed by the Minister. Under existing provisions of the TPA this has shown to
be a power that can be misused and work against new players entering a market
when they are up against powerful and financially endowed incumbents (again, I
refer to Fortescue Metals efforts to become a third player in the Pilbara iron
ore industry). There is no reason why ACMA can not make these sorts of
decisions itself, taking into account 'the public interest'.
Neither the BSA, or the Digital Television Bill, set out
exactly what factors will be taken into account when the Minister considers
whether the grant of a licence under section 40 is 'likely to be contrary to
the public interest'.
There are a couple of differences between the media-specific
test that the PC put forward and the proposal in the Digital TV Bill, namely
that the power of veto would be exercised by the Minister, and not by the ACCC
and it is being applied in relation to the grant of a broadcast licence, not in
consideration of a media merger.
The Australian Democrats understand that this particular
issue received little attention in submissions and at hearings. However, the
Democrats believe that this is a reflection on the volume of other issues that
needed to be considered in the legislative package, and not an indication that
the informed public simply agrees with this measure. For example when the
Government announced this proposal in its Meeting the Digital Challenge
discussion paper, released earlier this year, the MEAA responded:
The [MEAA] is strongly opposed to the plan for the Government to
assume the regulatory and licensing functions of ACMA. ACMA is the statutory
authority established at arm’s length from Government to make such decisions.
The Alliance does not consider that a case has been made to remove the
licensing capacity from the communications and media regulator. [41]
Mr Jock Given, in his submission on the discussion paper,
also opposed the transfer of this power from the ACMA to the Minister. Mr
Given's reasons for opposing the proposal were outlined in his opposition to
the transfer of decision-making power in respect of commercial television
broadcast licences, namely:
Why a practice put in place shortly after World War 2 should be
equally appropriate for ‘21st Century Broadcasting’ is not explained. When this
policy was put in place, licences were awarded after a qualitative review of
the merits of competing bids. Once granted, they were subject to a serious
process of periodic review whereby there was a real possibility that they would
not be renewed if performance was inadequate. This all changed in 1992.
Commercial television licences are now awarded by price-based allocation, a
highly inappropriate process for direct government involvement. The much more
limited grounds on which renewal can be refused, or revocation undertaken, mean
licences are now much more secure commodities than those handed out in the
1950s. They are very close to perpetual franchises. Lessons have been learned
about communications regulatory processes since the 1950s. The separation from
both industry participants and central government of telecommunications
regulatory functions and spectrum allocation have been among the most important
changes. They reflect the now widely accepted principle of independence in
authorising the use of public resources. This is fundamental to the Rule of Law
and due process, which underpin investment confidence in a modern economy. Australia
has been an active and principled supporter of these ideas in international
trade forums. The Discussion Paper’s proposal would disrupt the careful balance
of planning and licensing responsibilities without adequate justification, and
contradict the ‘convergence’ of radiocommunications and broadcasting regulation
that ACMA is supposed to be a response to, by creating yet another distinction
in the way spectrum is allocated for different purposes. Regulation for the
21st century would be replaced with a discredited 1950s process.[42]
The Australian Democrats note that Mr Given did not make any
comment in his submission to the committee on the proposal to grant the
Minister a power of veto over the grant of commercial television broadcasting
licences outside the BSB. Nonetheless, the Democrats believe that Mr Given's
argument set out above is worthy of consideration in the current debate.
Adequate funding for national broadcasters
Removing the genre restrictions on multi-channelling by
national broadcasters will permit them to provide a broader range of digital
services. The Australian Democrats support the lifting of genre restrictions on
content for ABC and SBS so they can provide a broader range of digital
services. The ABC has shown itself to be a great innovator in the area of radio
broadcasting with podcasting, and they have also produced some popular VODcasts
in the recent past.
This lifting of genre restrictions will enable the national
broadcasters to broaden their ability to create new and innovative programming.
However the Australian Democrats have reservations about this because of course
there has been no increase in real funding for the ABC or SBS over the last
decade so that raises the question of how will these new services be financed?
The Government continues to expect the national broadcasters to produced
quality news and current affairs on a diminishing budget. Many argue that there
are few options available for the ABC now, except to introduce advertising in
the same way that SBS has done, to meet the increasing costs of content
production.
Even though it was not covered in this Committee's majority
report, the Australian Democrats would like to record their opposition to the
introduction of advertising to make up the Government shortfall in funding to
the national broadcasters. The obvious reason for this is that it impacts on
the independence of the broadcasters, and the media environment is already
affected enough by commercial interests.
High Definition Television
The proposed amendments to the HDTV obligations would
require the 1040 hours per year HDTV quota to continue during the simulcast
period, but will be removed once the simulcast period ends. Essentially this
would allow the market to decide the preferred use of the digital spectrum
beyond the simulcast period.
Although there was no clear consensus amongst submitters on
this issue, the Democrats are persuaded by the argument made by those that
support the early removal of the quota. For example SBS favoured an early
transition:
Mr Meagher—We certainly think that, come either the
switch-off time or perhaps the time when multichannelling is provided, it would
be appropriate to do away with the high-definition quota. We do believe that,
over time, there will be increased high definition and that people will come to
value high definition. If you look at the UK, it is quite interesting. They
started with a model driven by multichannelling, and now that has been quite
well established there are substantial amounts of high definition, and that is
often the point of differentiation for channels and providers. But we agree
with you that, over time at least, removing the quota obligation would be a
sensible move.[43]
The Democrats believe that the mandated HDTV quota should be
removed sooner than the end of the simulcast period in order to free up
broadcasting spectrum for the other digital services.
The Democrats also have a concern that, as the Government
has previously failed to meet its simulcast deadline on a number of occasions
and its lack of ingenuity to drive digital take-up, that the simulcast date may
be further delayed. As a result, this would further extend the duration of the
HDTV quota, which would be undesirable.
Anti-siphoning
The anti-siphoning scheme ensures that certain events are
available to the whole viewing public by preventing pay TV licensees from
acquiring exclusive rights to listed events. The Minister may gazette a list of
events, or events of a kind, which the Minister believes should be available
free to the general public.
The current anti-siphoning list comprises domestic and
international sporting events in twelve categories including cricket, tennis,
golf, motor sports and the football codes. Pay TV licensees are prevented from
acquiring a right to televise a listed event until a right has first been
acquired by the ABC, the SBS or commercial free-to-air broadcasters reaching
more than 50 per cent of the Australian population.[44]
The Government's preferred option of dealing with this issue
is to apply a 'use it or lose it' approach, where, in the event that FTA
broadcasters fail to provide adequate coverage of a listed event, the event
would be considered for removal from the list.[45]
Amongst the criteria the Government is considering for
determining 'adequate coverage' of events on the anti-siphoning list is whether
the event or events that make up the item were shown live, or near live
(commencing within one hour of the start of the event).
As highlighted in the Hearings the Democrats are concerned
for communities outside the eastern seaboard states, as these areas often
receive delayed broadcasts of major sporting events (as well as news and
weather). The Democrats stress that 'live means live' and that the
anti-siphoning regime should take greater account of the interests of those in
non-east coast states. This issue should be considered during the review of the
anti-siphoning scheme, scheduled to occur prior to 31 December 2009.
Mr Williams—I think perhaps we have not
made our position sufficiently clear. The issue is: if you have legislative
commercial preferment, which is what we are talking about, we are saying there
needs to be a rule around it. And the rule is: you must play it within one hour
of the thing starting. Sports broadcasting is about live sport. It is not about
starting the transmission of the Rugby League grand final on Sunday in Perth
over three hours after the lap of honour around the ground will have been run.
That is preposterous. There need to be proper rules. We are saying: if it is
delayed by an hour, yes, it comes off the list. And, hopefully, the industry,
which seem to hunt in a pack when it suits but then become guerrilla agents
when it does not suit, will actually do something about it. Live means live.
National means national. We are one nation. This is one parliament for the
nation.[46]
...
Senator MURRAY—Mr Williams, as a general observation as a
Western Australian, my experience has been that eastern staters do not pay
enough attention to the real effects of time zones in this country. You saw me
nod vigorously when you said ‘live means live’. It is a strong issue in Western
Australia. It is not just with respect to sport; we want real-time news, we
want real-time weather—[47]
THE LICENCE FEES BILL
As part of the general package of media bills being
considered, the Television Licence Fees Amendment Bill 2006 amends the definition
of ‘gross earnings’ (of the licensee, upon which fees payable are calculated)
to take into account the fact that broadcasters will now be able to earn
revenue from providing multiple services (ie. the new digital services and the
existing services). Effectively, the Bill ensures that all revenue generated
by the licensee will be taken into account in determining the relevant licence
fee.
At the Senate hearing concern was raised about the
detrimental burden that would be placed on these new services if they were
forced to pay licence fees from the very beginning (with the licence fees
currently being about nine per cent of gross revenues). Ms Julie Flynn, Chief
Executive Officer of Free TV Australia, stated:
In relation to the Television Licence Fees Amendment Bill, we
are opposed, as you have just heard from Channel 7, to bundling multichannels
with the main channel for the purpose of calculating licence fees. These are
new services operating in an uncertain environment and should be exempt in the
first instance, as new services have been in the past. We all agree that when
fees are applied they should be levied separately from the main channel.[48]
I believe that Ms Flynn has a point. Some sort of ‘break’
is needed for those that choose to provide these new services. As Ms Flynn
notes, these are new services operating in an uncertain market, and ‘small’
should also be added. It is not uncommon for infant industries to be allowed a
transitional period before the fees kick in. Also, if other services, when
first starting, have been given exemptions (as Ms Flynn notes), it is only fair
and equitable that similar exemptions be granted.
What is needed is some sort of transitional period, in which
the success (or failure!) of the new services can be assessed, and the licence
fee situation review accordingly. I would like to lend my support to the idea,
as put forward by Ms Bridget Godwin (Manager, Regulatory and Business and
Affairs, Seven Network) at the Senate Hearing, that a moratorium be placed on
licence fees, until such time as it is appropriate to review the situation.
The possibility of separating out the main channel and the
new digital service should also be considered, so that a sliding scale (as
contained in the Television Licence Fees Act) could be used, with the new
services paying in accordance with their revenues, and not the revenues of the
channel as a whole.
CONCLUSION
Given the ridiculously short time for this Inquiry, and the
length and complexity of the four bills that comprise this media proposals
package, it is inevitable that this Democrats’ Minority has not covered all the
material issues that arise from consideration of this legislation. We have
just run out of time.
The Majority Report covers a number of issues more fully.
We will support those Coalition Senators’ initiatives that will have the effect
of improving diversity, adding more real competition and enhancing regulatory
process and oversight, as outlined in the Majority Report.
Naturally, my Minority concentrates on negatives or on
shortcomings, but I have also attempted to suggest a number of improvements in
policy that would positively contribute to greater diversity and competition,
such as greater assistance for community TV.
I emphasise that the Democrats welcome a number of features
of this package of legislation, including advancing technology and new media,
and strengthening ACMA.
As stated at the outset of this Minority Report, our main
problem is with the Media Ownership Bill. Without substantial and concurrent legislation
to strengthen the ACCC in particular, ACMA and the FIRB; and to tighten the
‘voices formula’ to require a safety net of real meaningful voices in each
significant media market, the Media Ownership Bill must be opposed outright.
Senator Andrew
Murray
Senator for Western Australia
Appendix A
March 2004: Senate Economics References Committee Report
into the effectiveness of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (‘the Act’) in
protecting small business
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
AND LIST OF RECOMMENDATIONS
1.1
The Senate Economics References Committee’s inquiry into the
effectiveness of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (‘the Act’) in protecting
small business is the latest in a long series of government and parliamentary
inquiries into the operation of this Act.
1.2
The most recent of these, the Review of the Competition Provisions of
the Trade Practices Act (‘the Dawson Report’), canvassed a number of areas
relevant to this inquiry, particularly regarding the ‘misuse of market power’
provisions in Section 46 of the Act. After the Dawson Committee had completed
its consultations with interested parties, however, several decisions were
handed down from the Full Federal Court and the High Court which have raised
questions about the application and operation of Section 46 of the Act. The
decision of the High Court in Boral Besser Masonry Ltd v ACCC (the Boral
case), in particular, raised these issues and forms a significant backdrop to
this Committee’s inquiry.
1.3
An issue which has been raised during many of these inquiries is the
question of whether the Act should seek to protect competition or competitors.
The Committee considers that the Act can best protect competition by
maintaining a range of competitors, who should rise and fall in accordance with
the results of competitive rather than anticompetitive conduct. This means that
the Act should protect businesses (large or small) against anticompetitive
conduct, and it should not be amended to protect competitors against
competitive conduct. This inquiry considered how well the Act achieves this
goal.
Misuse of market power
1.4
Section 46 of the Act prohibits corporations with a substantial degree
of market power from taking advantage of that power for the purpose of
eliminating or substantially damaging a competitor, preventing the entry of a
competitor into the market or deterring or preventing a competitor from
engaging in competitive conduct.
1.5
A number of submissions and witnesses argued in evidence that the High
Court’s decision in the Boral case has raised the threshold for
determining that a corporation possesses a substantial degree of market power.
They argued that the High Court’s finding that Boral did not possess a
substantial degree of market power means, effectively, that a corporation would
have to be near dominant in the market to satisfy that element of section 46.
1.6
Accordingly, many including the ACCC argued that section 46 requires
amendment to ensure that the lower threshold intended by Parliament is given
effect in the legislation. The ACCC in fact informed the Committee that, as a
consequence of the decision in Boral, it had discontinued four cases
that had reached the ‘second threshold’ stage of its investigations in relation
to section 46.
1.7
The Committee considers that the amendments suggested by the ACCC are
consistent with the intention of Parliament in 1986, and that their inclusion
in the Act would clarify the intentions of Parliament.
Recommendation 1
The Committee recommends that the Act be amended to state that the
threshold of ‘a substantial degree of power in a market’ is lower than the
former threshold of substantial control; and to include a declaratory provision
outlining matters to be considered by the courts for the purposes of
determining whether a company has a substantial degree of power in a market.
Those matters should be based upon the suggestions outlined by the ACCC in
paragraph 2.16 of this report.
1.8
The Committee received some evidence arguing that amendments are also
required to section 46 in order to clarify what a court may have regard to in
determining whether a corporation has ‘taken advantage’ of its market power.
1.9
Witnesses argued that the need for clarification arises from the Federal
Court’s decision in Safeway, which found that the business rationale for
the conduct was relevant to considering whether the corporation had taken
advantage of its market power. The ACCC was concerned that this reasoning left
open the possibility of a defence on the grounds of ‘rational business conduct’
to corporations which had unfairly taken advantage of their market power.
1.10
The Committee considers that the Act should be amended to remove current
uncertainty with regard to the meaning of ‘take advantage.’ The Committee
considers that its proposed amendment would make clear and explicit the link
between proscribed conduct and the possession of substantial market power, and
would deal with the issue of ‘rational business conduct.’
Recommendation 2
The Committee recommends that the Act be amended to include a
declaratory provision outlining the elements of ‘take advantage’ for the
purposes of s.46(1). This provision should be based upon the suggestions
outlined in paragraph 2.28 of this report.
1.11
A number of submissions and witnesses expressed concern about predatory
pricing activities which, they argued, are not adequately captured by section
46. The Committee notes that predatory pricing has proven difficult to define
or establish. Low, or below cost, prices may be evidence of predatory pricing
but they may also occur as a consequence of normal, competitive behaviour.
1.12
The Committee considers that the Act would be strengthened by making
predatory pricing a clearer target of section 46.
1.13
One factor which may indicate that the relevant pricing is predatory is
where the price-cutting company plans to recoup its losses by increasing prices
once its opponents have been driven from the market. However, there was dispute
in the evidence before the Committee over whether recoupment is a necessary
feature of predatory pricing.
1.14
The Committee considers that, while evidence of a corporation’s
intention to recoup losses may well contribute to the proof of an allegation of
predatory pricing, there is nothing in s.46 which makes recoupment an element
necessary to prove predatory pricing. The Committee considers that the Act
could be improved by stating that recoupment is a factor which the courts may
examine when considering allegations of predatory pricing.
Recommendation 3
The Committee recommends that the Act be amended to provide that,
without limiting the generality of s.46, in determining whether a corporation
has breached s.46, the courts may have regard to:
-
the capacity of the corporation to sell a good or service
below its variable cost.
The Committee recommends that the Act be amended to state that:
-
where the form of proscribed behaviour alleged under s.46(1) is
predatory pricing, it is not necessary to demonstrate an capacity to
subsequently recoup the losses experienced as a result of that predatory
pricing strategy
1.15
The Committee received some evidence suggesting amendments designed specifically
to deal with the use of financial power to support predatory pricing. The
proposed amendments set out to capture predatory pricing conduct of firms with
financial power but not market power, that might otherwise fall outside the
scope of section 46.
1.16
The importance of such amendments was highlighted by the outcome of the Rural
Press case, handed down in December 2003. In that case, Rural Press pursued
a clearly anticompetitive business strategy, but was not found to be in breach
of the Act, partly because it relied on its “economic and financial power” and
not its market power. An attempt by the trial judge to link economic, financial
and market power was overturned on appeal.
1.17
The ACCC supported the use of the concept of financial power in regulating
conduct contrary to s.46, but considered that rather than introducing a
financial power threshold in s.46, financial power should be listed as one of
the factors contributing to a determination of substantial power in a market.
Recommendation 4
The Committee recommends that s.46 of the Act be amended to state
that, in determining whether or not a corporation has a substantial degree of
power in a market for the purpose of s.46(1), the court may have regard to
whether the corporation has substantial financial power.
‘Financial power’ should be defined in terms of access to
financial, technical and business resources.
1.18
Evidence raised the issue of whether amendments are required to ensure
that s.46 applies where a corporation uses market power in one market to engage
in proscribed conduct in a second market. This issue was determined by the High
Court late in the Committee’s deliberations, when in the Rural Press
judgment the Court clearly stated that misuse of market power in a second
market is not a breach of the Act.
1.19
The Committee considers that this should not be the case. The possession
of market power in one market should not become the base for anticompetitive
conduct in another market, and the Act should be amended to make this clear.
Recommendation 5
The Committee recommends that s.46 be amended to state that a
corporation which has a substantial degree of power in a market shall not take
advantage of that power, in that or any other market, for any proscribed
purpose in relation to that or any other market.
1.20
The Committee, finally, considered the impact of coordinated market
power on competition. The Committee considers that corporations which do not
have a substantial degree of market power on their own, may obtain that power
through ‘conscious parallelism’ or ‘coordinated interaction’ with other
corporations. For this reason, the Committee considers that s.46 of the Act
should be clarified to indicate that a company may obtain market power by
virtue of its co-ordination with another company, and that such coordinated
market power may amount to a substantial degree of power in a market.
Recommendation 6
The Committee recommends that s.46 be amended to clarify that a
company may be considered to have obtained a substantial degree of market power
by virtue of its ability to act in concert (whether as a result of a formal
agreement or understanding, or otherwise) with another company.
Unconscionable conduct
1.21
Part IVA of the Act prohibits the anti-competitive behaviour known as
‘unconscionable conduct’. Section 51AC, which seeks particularly to protect
small businesses from unconscionable conduct by large businesses, attracted
most comment during this inquiry.
1.22
A number of submissions sought to extend s.51AC to proscribe ‘unfair,
harsh or unconscionable conduct’. The Committee considers that ‘harsh’ conduct
is often a normal part of tough competitive dealing, and that the concept of
‘unfair conduct’ is much less legally certain than the concept of
‘unconscionable conduct.’ It is not clear that either of these proposed
additions would enhance protection for small business under the Act, and as a
result the Committee does not support their inclusion.
1.23
Subsections 51AC(9) and (10) limit the operation of s.51AC to the supply
or acquisition of goods or services at a price in excess of $3,000,000. A
number of organisations called for greater clarity around the $3 Million
figure, suggesting it should operate on a per-invoice basis, and should be
indexed. Other evidence suggested that the $3 Million threshold was fundamentally
inappropriate, and should be removed.
1.24
The ACCC agreed with this view, saying that subsection 51AC(3)(a)
already stated that the courts may have regard to the relative strengths of the
bargaining positions of the companies, so no threshold is necessary.
1.25
The Committee noted these arguments and further noted that subsections
51AC(1) and (2) exclude publicly listed companies from the protection of the
section. The Committee agrees that the removal of the thresholds will not
reduce the current protection for small businesses, and will enhance protection
for businesses involved in transactions over $3 Million, who are nevertheless
subject to unconscionable conduct within the terms of s.51AC.
Recommendation 7
The Committee recommends that subsections 51AC(9) and 51AC(10) of
the Act be repealed.
1.26
Submissions and witnesses also sought to extend s.51AC to proscribe a
number of specific activities, including the unilateral variation of contracts,
unilateral termination of contracts, and the presentation of standard form
contracts. In relation to the behaviours identified in these activities, the
Committee notes that many are already captured by the terms of s.51AC,
particularly subsections (3)(j) and (k).
1.27
The Committee also notes evidence that there are occasions upon which
the use of standard form contracts or unilateral variations of contracts may be
pro-competitive and commercially beneficial for both parties. Standard form
contracts, for instance, save both parties time and money when similar
transactions are conducted regularly, and when the terms and conditions are
well known and agreed by both parties. The Committee is concerned that the
proscription of standard form contracts per se, would remove these cost
saving benefits in addition to proscribing the unconscionable use of such
forms.
1.28
The ACCC presented a slightly different proposal in relation to
unilateral variation of contracts. The ACCC argued that, rather than
proscribing such contracts, they should be added to the list of matters,
contained in subsections 51AC(3) and (4), to which the courts may have regard
in determining whether conduct is unconscionable. This proposal would not ban
the unilateral variation of contracts outright, but would make it clear that
such contracts could constitute conduct which is, in all the circumstances,
unconscionable.
1.29
The Committee finds this argument compelling, since it would discourage
the inappropriate use of unilateral variation of contracts, while allowing
unilateral variation where such provisions are commercially necessary and
pro-competitive.
Recommendation 8
The Committee recommends that subsections 51AC(3) and 51AC(4) of
the Act be amended to include ‘whether the supplier (in s.51AC(3)) or acquirer
(in s.51AC(4)) imposed or utilised contract terms allowing the unilateral
variation of any contract between the supplier and business consumer, or the
small business supplier and acquirer.’
1.30
Witnesses indicated to the Committee that some government authorities,
particularly at State and local levels, are not covered by s.51AC of the Act,
despite being large scale purchasers of products, often from small businesses.
The Committee agrees that such authorities should be subject to the Act.
Recommendation 9
The Committee recommends that s.2B(1) of the Act be amended so
that it is clear that Part 1VA of the Act applies to the Commonwealth
Government; and that the Government consult with the states and territories
with a view to amending subsection 2B(1) of the Act, so that Part IVA of the
Act applies to state, territory and local governments.
1.31
The Committee examined, in some detail, unconscionable conduct in retail
tenancy arrangements. Some witnesses argued that ACCC has not pursued retail
tenancy issues with sufficient vigour, despite the introduction of s.51AC which
was intended to strengthen the remedies available to retail tenants who were
the victims of unconscionable conduct.
1.32
The Committee observed, however, that since a number of State and
Territory jurisdictions have drawn down versions of 51AC into their respective
retail tenancy regimes the full impact of s.51AC on retail tenancies may be
larger than is suggested by a simple observation of the ACCC’s activity.
1.33
The Committee recommends that the Commonwealth government work with its
State and Territory counterparts to harmonise retail tenancy laws.
1.34
The Committee noted that there are inconsistencies and areas where the
law could be strengthened, including in relation to the common practice of
‘secret pricing’ in retail tenancies. While the Committee does not support the
compulsory disclosure of rental terms, the Committee does not support
arrangements which prevent such disclosure. Such arrangements inhibit, rather
than support, an informed market for retail tenancies. In particular, retail
tenants who utilise the collective bargaining notification arrangements
proposed in the Dawson Report and supported in this report should be able to
freely share information about their rental prices and conditions. If this
process fails to deliver satisfactory outcomes over time, the Government should
consider the adoption of a mandatory code.
Recommendation 10
The Committee recommends that the Commonwealth Government
negotiate with state and territory governments, with a view to introducing
measures which would prohibit retail lease provisions compelling tenants to
keep their tenancy terms and conditions secret.
Codes of conduct
1.35
The Committee considered Part IVB of the Act, which enables voluntary or
mandatory industry codes to be prescribed under the Act, so that contravention
of a relevant code also contravenes the Act. The Committee further noted the
ACCC’s proposals to endorse codes of conduct which meet its quality criteria.
1.36
The Committee concurs with the scepticism
expressed by a number of small business representatives about the extent to
which voluntary codes of conduct can address entrenched problems within
particular industries.
1.37
The Committee does not support the general use of voluntary codes as a
substitute for sensible regulation. The Committee notes that the
recommendations it has made in this report are likely to accomplish more to
support successful competition than the most well-meaning ambitions of
developing voluntary codes.
Collective bargaining
1.38
The Committee generally supports the Dawson Report’s recommendation for
a notification process rather than an authorisation
process for proposed collective bargaining arrangements. The Committee notes
that these recommended collective bargaining arrangements include provision for
collective boycotts, where these are judged to be in the public benefit.
1.39
Although the government accepted the recommendation of the Dawson Report
in relation to collective bargaining, the Committee notes that it has yet to
introduce the legislation to implement that proposal.
Recommendation 11
The Committee recommends that the Government immediately
bring forward legislation to introduce a collective bargaining notification
scheme, including the right to boycott, and excluding the proposed $3 million
threshold for notifications.
Creeping acquisitions
1.40
Submissions before the inquiry suggested that in the retail grocery
sector and the retail liquor sector, large chains are acquiring the stores of
independent competitors in a program of ‘creeping’ acquisitions. Witnesses
expressed concern that s.50 of the Act, designed to prevent acquisitions that
would have the effect of ‘substantially lessening competition in a market’, is
inadequate in dealing with piecemeal acquisitions because no single purchase is
likely, by itself, to lead to a substantial lessening of competition.
1.41
The ACCC itself expressed concern about this issue, but also noted that
it has not yet determined whether creeping acquisitions in general (as opposed
to specific case) do substantially lessen competition and so cause economic
detriment. Further, if they do have this effect, the ACCC expressed uncertainty
about whether the current section 50 provisions would be adequate to deal with
that issue.
1.42
The Committee considers, as a matter of logic, that creeping
acquisitions must, if continued indefinitely, at some point result in a very
concentrated market. The clear consensus of evidence before the Committee
supported this view, and no substantial arguments were raised to oppose it. Current
merger law does not effectively address this issue. Section 50 of the Act
should be strengthened to take account of the cumulative effects of
acquisitions which over time may substantially lessen competition.
Recommendation 12
The Committee considers that provisions should be introduced into
the Act to ensure that the ACCC has powers to prevent creeping acquisitions
which substantially lessen competition in a market.
Divestiture
1.43
Divestiture powers are powers which enable a Court to order that a
dominant corporation be broken up into several smaller corporations in order to
prevent the anticompetitive domination of a market by one player.
1.44
Such powers are currently available under s.81 of the Act, but cannot be
applied to creeping acquisitions, nor to offences under s.46. The Committee
considers that the application of s.81 should be expanded, so that divestiture
becomes a remedy for other breaches of the Act, including section 46 (Misuse of
market power) and any new section introduced in line with the Committee’s
recommendation 12 (relating to the regulation of creeping acquisitions).
1.45
As divestiture is a quite severe remedy, it is appropriate to provide
“warning mechanisms” to ensure that a corporation which is expanding its
business is able to comply with its obligations under the Act. A suitable
warning mechanism could be based around a “trigger” market concentration.
1.46
This trigger should not operate as a de facto cap on market
share. Rather it would require companies proposing acquisitions in concentrated
industries to notify the ACCC. The Commission would then assess whether the
acquisition would result in a substantial lessening of competition. The
Committee notes that this already occurs in the retail grocery industry.
Recommendation 13
The Committee recommends that s.81(1) of the Act be amended
so that s.81 can be applied where a corporation is found to have contravened
section 46, section 46A, or any new section introduced to regulate creeping
acquisitions.
Powers of the ACCC
1.47
Before the Dawson Committee, the ACCC argued that it should be given the
power to issue ‘cease and desist’ orders to stop anti-competitive conduct.
Other organisations supported the extension of these powers before this
Committee. The Committee considers that cease and desist powers are a vital
tool for the ACCC if it is to prevent anti-competitive conduct from resulting
in substantial damage to small business. The ACCC requires a tool which will
enable it to act in ‘real business time’ yet which will protect the rights of
companies against whom the cease and desist orders are sought.
Recommendation 14
The Committee recommends that the Act be amended to provide for
cease and desist orders, modelled on the orders provided for in sections 74A to
74D of the Commerce Act 1986 (NZ), appropriately modified to conform
with Australian constitutional law.
1.48
The ACCC argued, before this Committee, for an extension of its powers
under s.155 of the Act beyond the commencement of injunctive court proceedings.
The Committee is reluctant to interfere in the powers possessed by the ACCC
once a matter is before the courts. However the Committee considers that the
ACCC should be able to apply to the courts for its s.155 powers to continue
after the commencement of injunctive proceedings.
Recommendation 15
The Committee recommends that s.155 of the Act should be amended
to enable the ACCC to seek the permission of the court (whether as part of a
warrant application or otherwise) for the continued use of its powers under
s.155 after the commencement of injunctive proceedings. The use of s.155 powers
should cease prior to the commencement of substantive proceedings.
Resources of the ACCC
1.49
The ACCC acknowledged to the Committee that it is often constrained in
its ability to pursue legal proceedings in relation to s.46 and s.51AC, because
of the lack of availability of funding. The Committee wishes to rectify this
problem.
Recommendation 16
The Committee recommends that the ACCC should be adequately funded
to undertake its role as the principal litigant in s.46 and s.51AC cases.
Judicial arrangements
1.50
One organisation suggested to the Committee that jurisdiction for s.46
and s.51AC matters should be extended to lower courts and tribunals, in order
to increase access to justice for small businesses. The Committee supports this
proposal, and considers that the Federal Magistrates Court has developed
expertise in resolving issues without requiring the expense of a fully
contested court case. This expertise could resolve a substantial number of s.46
and s.51AC matters with cost savings for all sides. Recourse to the Federal
Magistrates Court may also enable more small businesses to utilise the
provisions of section 83 of the Act to seek damages where anti-competitive
conduct has already been established by the courts.
Recommendation 17
The Committee recommends that the jurisdiction of the Federal
Magistrates Court be extended to enable it to deal with Misuse of Market Power
(s.46 and s.46A where cases rely upon s.83), Contravention of Industry Codes
(s. 51AD) and Unconscionable Conduct (Part IVA).
Approaches adopted in OECD economies
1.51
In its discussion of the effectiveness of the Trade Practices Act
1974, the Committee has compared the provisions of the Act with those in
the competition laws of a number of OECD economies. In particular, the
Committee has considered approaches adopted in relation to the following
issues:
-
UK and US legislation regarding predatory pricing and recoupment
(para 2.51);
-
US legislation regarding definitions of ‘unfairness’ (para 3.29);
-
UK legislation regarding the regulation of contracts (para
3.54ff);
-
UK legislation regarding a ‘trigger’ of market concentration for
the purpose of assessing acquisitions (para 4.76ff)
-
New Zealand legislation regarding cease and desist powers (para
5.10ff)
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page