7. User charges: arguments of detail
7.1 The arguments of previous chapters relate mainly to compulsory entry
fees, as distinct from charges for `value-added' services, special
exhibitions and so on. Many submissions opposed entry fees but of these
most accepted or advocated charges for the other things. The chief question
that this raises is where the boundary between them should lie.
7.2 Some submissions opposed user charges on principle but stated fallback
positions (`...but if they are used they should be designed to avoid the
following undesirable effects...') These arguments are also reviewed in
this chapter.
`Basic access' versus `value-added services' in libraries, museums and
galleries
7.3 Many submissions argued for free `basic access' (`core services')
but accepted user charges for `value-added services.' This was non-controversial
among all who spoke of it; but it raises the immediate question: which
services should be considered `basic' and which should be considered `value-added'?
The distinction is not necessarily obvious.
7.4 This was most clear in the case of libraries and archives. The Australian
Library and Information Association's policy affirming the public's right
to free `core services' refrains from trying to define exactly what these
are. [1] The Australian Council of Libraries
and Information Services comments, `...what is classed as basic and what
is classed as valued-added will vary from service to service.' [2]
`There are some basic types of services, such as the public access to
the public record, which are quite easy to see as core services. Defining
services beyond that, such as reproduction and exhibitions and whether
to charge for that kind of thing, is something that each institution has
looked at within their particular client group.' (K Dan, Australian Society
of Archivists, evidence 6 August 1997 p212)
7.5 For example, different users of a library may need different amounts
of reference help to get the information they need: what one manager might
call `basic' reference help (that which is necessary to give the reader
the information) another might call extra advice (because it takes an
unusually long time). The fact that in this area an arbitrary cutoff to
`basic' service may be necessary is shown by the Australian Archives'
policy that `a maximum limit of an hour is devoted by staff [free of charge]
to each inquiry'. [3] The National Film and
Sound Archives charges a research and service fee of $50 per hour, commenting,
`[fees] can provide a means of diverting frivolous, vexatious or unduly
time-consuming requests'. [4] An analogous problem
for museums is how to treat requests to view items not on display. There
has to be a limit to the depth of free service that a public institution
can provide. [5]
7.6 Another area that some seem to call `core' and others `value-added'
(that is, charged for), is country tours and outreach programs. Other
than these examples the lists of core services versus value-added services
that witnesses offered seem reasonably consistent and unsurprising: the
core services involving access to facilities and reference help (libraries)
and access to the permanent collection (museums and galleries); the value-added
services involving things like copies, publications, special exhibitions
and `extra' consultancy services. [6] When we
say that the boundary between them is not necessarily obvious, we mean
simply that distinguishing between them is a matter of value judgment
about the desirable/affordable extent of free access, not a matter of
logic or of impartial observation of the features of different services.
Senator Tierney: `You seem to be heading towards full cost recovery
in areas... where they are not central to the business of government or
its resources. Could you just give some examples of areas that are considered
not central to the business of government?'
Mr Holmes: `...I think the definition of what is central and what
is not central is shifting...it is a matter of judgment and political
position at any point in time.' (A Holmes, SA Dept of Environment
& Natural Resources, evidence 2 July 1997 p137)
`Basic access' versus `value-added services' in national parks
7.7 A similar distinction between basic access and value-added services
was generally accepted in submissions on national parks, and it was generally
accepted (even by those who opposed entry fees) that charges for
value-added services are appropriate. Value-added services were said to
be things like `roads, toilets, camping facilities, information centres,
rubbish removal'. [7]
`It is my experience that visitors expect to pay a basic camping fee
to cover site management costs such as water supply and rubbish removal,
but they do not expect to pay an entry fee as well.' (J Lennon, submission
13 p111)
7.8 As with museums and galleries, the boundary between `core/basic'
and `value-added' is not necessarily clear:
`There is the issue of what do you define as a community service obligation,
and what do you define as something that an individual should pay for.
There has been a view, for example, that bush camping, rough camping,
should be something that is free, whereas more service delivery camping
should be cost recovery.' (A Holmes, SA Dept of Environment & Natural
Resources, evidence 2 July 1997 p137)
7.9 The inclusion of `roads' in a suggested list of `value-added' services
is another example of this problem. For most people in most national parks,
free access without a road is as little use as free access to the library
without a catalogue. What looks like a `value-added' charge on vehicles
for road maintenance to one person may look suspiciously like an entry
fee to another.
Is new computer technology `basic' or `value-added'?
7.10 Several submissions spoke of the expense of digitising museum collections
and otherwise improving access to information through computer technology;
and the question of who should be charged for this type of access, and
on what basis. Should electronic access be considered a basic service
or a value-added service? Should it be free as a principle of equity,
just as personal access to the institution is (if it is)? Should the setup
costs be charged to users over some period, or regarded as a capital expense
to be absorbed into government-funded fixed costs?
`[Electronic] access to [museum] collection information is a complex
and highly contentious issue... Some individuals express the view that
government funded museums should make data freely available because government
paid for acquisition of the objects and their associated data. The reality
is that governments rarely fund collection and database development and
maintenance adequately... It seems clear that in future the users of the
information will need to accept some responsibility for paying for quality
improvement....' (Australian Museum, submission 30 p245)
7.11 Whether the old free service remains available beside the new `value-added
service is an important point:
Senator Hogg: `But in the hiatus period in which we are getting
the conversion of old records onto computer disk or whatever it might
be, does that warrant the government necessarily absorbing the cost, or
should the government somehow retrieve the cost through user-pays charges?
Is there a fundamental right that, regardless, free access to that information
should be available to the community, and it just happens to be a quirk
of the time that we live in that we are undergoing this transition?'
Ms Dan: `I would say that there is a fundamental right. The question
is whether that right can be satisfied through provision of the service
as it is given now - for example, through people visiting the Archives
or getting in touch the Archives and having access to the documents. That
fundamental right would remain. What we are doing with computerising or
digitising records in the hiatus period is adding value and making them
more accessible, so I would see that there is a legitimate right
to charge for that type of service.' (K Dan, Australian Society of Archivists,
evidence 6 August 1997 p212)
7.12 Equity issues may intervene, particularly for country people who
are less able to visit city institutions:
`Free delivery of the contents of collection materials to remote areas
via the Internet and other means is becoming an issue for collecting organisations.
In fairness to remote Australians, should these services be freely available,
as national and state libraries are to city dwellers? User pays
has become a way of avoiding the problem of increasing demand for these
services...' (National Film and Sound Archive, submission 40 p341)
7.13 A similar equity issue arises in deciding whether `outreach' programs
should be regarded as core or value-added. For example, the Queensland
Museum provides free admission in Brisbane but charges entry fees at its
country branches, and acknowledges the equity concerns that this raises.
[8]
Risk of `user pays by stealth' with new technology
7.14 What should be called `core' and what should be called `value-added'
depends on society's norms of the day. The Committee does not accept
that today's core services should be seen as fixed for evermore, and all
improvements or novelties henceforth may be called `value-added' and charged
for. This would be a sure recipe for `user pays by stealth' as new technology
replaces old, as old `core' services disappear and new `value-added' services
become the norm. Just as the presence of a photocopier in the library
should be seen as a core service today, so the presence of computers will
be in future. It may be acceptable to charge for faster access by computer,
as long as the printed book remains freely available on the shelf; it
is not acceptable to continue to charge for access by computer after that
has become the norm and the printed book is no longer available. As well,
the development costs of introducing computer technology into libraries,
archives and museums should not be charged as a supplement on the marginal
cost prices paid by today's direct users: it should be seen as an investment
in the next generation of core service, and should be budget-funded like
any other capital expense. As the information economy grows, it is ever
more important that all Australians should have free and equal access
to the information that is held in public institutions.
`In democratic societies the power derived from information must not
be the preserve of a few.' (Australian Archives, submission 33 p261)
Principles for charging for value-added services
7.15 As to how to charge for value-added services, the National Library
of Australia proposes three categories (with provision for subsidy or
differential pricing for social justice or other policy reasons):
1. services that mix core and value-added elements: to be charged
at marginal cost recovery with a rebate representing the core element;
2. value-added services for private purposes: marginal cost recovery,
with consideration to making a surcharge to finance development costs
`where ongoing investment is required to develop a service to provide
improved benefits to users';
3. value-added services for commercial purposes: full cost recovery
plus a target profit. [9]
7.16 The Australian Museum has similar policies: `Government departments...
are usually charged [for data] on the basis of avoidable cost... commercial
requests for data are generally charged at a combined avoidable cost plus
service fee.' [10]
7.17 The National Film and Sound Archive (NFSA) stresses the need for
flexibility: `Publicly funded organisations need to retain the flexibility
to deal with individual clients, to be able to make deals of beneficial
interest to both parties. For example, in exchange for waiving access
fees, copies of certain programs and/or research materials may be donated
to NFSA for future public access... [we need] the discretion to charge
commercial clients, while being able to respond to the special needs of
pensioners, researchers and students.' [11]
7.18 In submissions on national parks, if it was not explicit it was
usually implicit that charges for tourist services should be based on
marginal cost recovery:
`Cost recovery from the tourism industry, as an easily targeted user
group, should not be used to offset management costs that would have to
be met regardless of tourism use of these public assets.' (Department
of Industry, Science & Tourism, submission 26 p220)
`We do not accept that the present generation of walkers should be expected
to pay for the full cost of rehabilitating and maintaining the tracks
and areas they frequent. Indeed, the cost of ongoing management is something
which should be borne principally by the State Government... on behalf
of the interests of the wider community.' (Tasmanian Conservation Trust,
submission 17 p154)
7.19 But note that this principle may conceal uncertainties about what
the relevant marginal cost is - as when we try to define the exact scope
of `rehabilitation', `maintenance' and `ongoing management.' Similarly
in the library: perhaps supplying the photocopier with paper is a marginal
cost, but what about supplying the photocopier? Should the charge for
copying have a loading to allow for periodic replacement of the photocopier,
or should the presence of the photocopier be regarded as a core
service which (the Committee would maintain) should be budget-funded as
a fixed cost?
7.20 The Committee discussed this problem from paragraph 5.22, and suggested
that, for the purpose of marginal cost pricing, the relevant marginal
cost should be defined as the avoidable cost of any activity which, if
it cannot cover costs at marginal cost pricing (not enough people are
willing to pay), management would discontinue without hesitation.
If management does hesitate, it is a sure sign that the activity is regarded
as `core' (that is, conveying community/non-use benefits) to some degree.
7.21 This scheme, by definition, aligns fixed and marginal costs with
core and value added services. In this form, what is a relevant marginal
cost depends entirely on the value judgment about where the line between
core and value-added should be drawn. [12]
Of course in practice there will be a continuum on which managements accept
less than marginal cost recovery from value-added services insofar as
they perceive some core element in them. [13]
7.22 Note that by this definition `value-added' services must be optional:
`core' services may include not only things visitors want but also any
compulsory incidentals. For example, take `rubbish removal' in
national parks. This was sometimes proposed as a value-added service,
[14] probably because it is an obvious variable
cost depending on the number of visitors; possibly also because of an
underlying view that the main business of the park is nature conservation,
and catering for visitors is somehow peripheral. But these are not the
criteria we propose. Our questions are simply: Is it practical to charge
for it separately? and If not enough people are willing to pay for it
separately, would management do it anyway? If management would
do it anyway it is by definition a core service, and a compulsory charge
on visitors to cover its costs is an entry fee.
Marginal cost pricing of value-added services
7.23 The Committee accepts the distinction between core and value-added
services, and accepts that it is reasonable to charge for value-added
services. We comment:
7.24 1. In line with the marginal cost pricing principle (see
paragraph 5.18) charges for value-added services for personal non-commercial
use should generally not go beyond marginal cost recovery. The fixed costs
of maintaining the institution and its core services for future generations
must be acknowledged as a public responsibility. Some provisos are
discussed below.
7.25 2. We have some concern about the concept of charging users
a supplement to finance development costs of improved services (see the
second dotpoint in the National Library's policy quoted in paragraph 7.15).
This goes beyond the principle of marginal cost pricing. The underlying
question is whether today's core services should be seen as fixed forevermore,
and all improvements or novelties henceforth are thrown in the `value-added'
basket; or whether providing new or better services as time goes by, having
regard to the technological possibilities and society's norms, should
be seen as a core function. The question arises most pointedly in respect
of financing computerised access. As noted in paragraph 7.14, the Committee
does not accept that today's core services should be regarded as fixed
for evermore. The proper scope of `core services' depends on the state
of technology and society's norm's of the day.
7.26 3. In cases where elastic demand suggests that basic access
should be free (as discussed in chapter 5), the
validity of marginal cost pricing for value-added services depends on
retaining free basic access as a real alternative. Where a visitor
has a real choice between viewing a document free or photocopying it at
cost, if the visitor forgoes the photocopy there is no net loss of welfare,
since the visitor still has the money that they might have spent on the
copy, and still has the benefit of viewing the document - which is the
reason for the library's existence as a publicly subsidised facility.
By contrast, if a supposedly marginal charge is actually unavoidable,
so that it behaves like an entry fee (as in the example of roads in national
parks mentioned in paragraph 7.9), and visitors turn away at the entrance,
then there is a deadweight loss of community welfare not compensated by
economy of operating costs, and all the arguments discussed from paragraph
5.15 come into play.
Marginal cost pricing versus surcharge to subsidise fixed costs
7.27 Many submissions suggested or implied that income from value-added
activities could be used to subsidise the fixed costs of core activities
(such as maintaining the museum collection, or conservation management
in national parks). The implication is that if people are willing to pay
big bucks to see a special exhibition, that is all to the good if it can
help support the permanent collection.
7.28 This is not consistent with the principle of marginal cost
recovery in pricing value-added services (since, at marginal cost pricing,
the marginal activity earns no surplus). The alternative view is that
the special exhibition should aim simply to recover costs:
`We have not presented those exhibitions to generate a surplus; our genuine
desire has been to cover costs. Obviously, if there is a surplus, the
public seems very happy for that money to be spent on acquisitions, which
is what happens.' (Dr C Turner, Queensland Art Gallery, evidence 21 May
1997 p121)
7.29 There is a possible equity issue here. Do poorer people not have
the right to see the special exhibition too? The Committee does not have
the answer to this question. It brings us back to a fundamental point
in chapter 3: we live in a society where poorer
people do not have as many things as better-off people. Any cross-subsidy
scheme is a compromise in which freer access to the subsidised part is
won at the expense of limiting access (relatively speaking) to the fee-paying
part. The assumption is that the gains outweigh the losses.
7.30 An analogy in national parks is whether charges at a more popular
national park (or one with fewer conservation management needs) should
subsidise management of a more remote or fragile one. Better management
at the more remote park is funded at the expense of limiting access -
by price - to the more popular one. There were differing opinions on whether
this is `fair' - most witnesses seemed to accept cross-subsidy providing
revenue is retained for the purposes of the organisation.
`For example, there are national parks in western New South Wales with
feral goat problems. The parks are being degraded by those goats and they
need some serious management resources to deal with that problem. But
if you tried to cover the cost by levying a user charge, you would be
charging $10,000 to get through the gate. It is not feasible. Heavily
used parks are going to provide much more of an opportunity for that kind
of funding to be raised to contribute.' (M Horstman, Australian Conservation
Foundation, evidence 15 September 1997 p465)
7.31 A risk of relying on user charges to cross-subsidise core activities
is that it may bias managers to maximise money-making developments at
the expense of their focus on core conservation goals:
`There is a very dangerous tendency here in Victoria - because, as far
as I am concerned, they have misunderstood the concept of user pays -
to try to move the national park service to self-funding over time or
by stealth... The idea, as we see at Wilsons Promontory, is that they
may be trying to use revenue from lodges, they are developing lodges in
the park in order to use that revenue to fund the national park...' (F
Grey, evidence 15 September 1997 p427)
7.32 The analogy in museums and galleries is the risk, which several
submissions referred to, of developing a `blockbuster syndrome' in which
the institution becomes forced to devote excessive effort to staging special
exhibitions at the expense of the permanent collection. See paragraph
7.63ff.
Marginal cost pricing versus surcharge for investment or profit
7.33 To extend the argument (mostly put in relation to national parks),
in popular tourist areas where elasticity of demand is low, is it reasonable
to load charges to include a component for investment in long term improvements,
or to include a component for profit (an economic rent)? [15]
If so, should commercial tourist operators be treated differently from
private visitors? [16]
7.34 In the case of computerisation in libraries, the Committee had concerns
about charging a component for investment, mainly because of the risk
of `user pays' by stealth as new charging services replace old free ones
(see paragraph 7.14). In the case of national parks, the idea of contribution
to improved facilities seems uncontroversial, [17]
providing -
`In terms of fairness the revenue should be allocated to `enhance' the
facility of natural area and not be seen as a `cash cow' with the user
charges going into consolidated revenue.' (Tourism Council Australia,
submission 57 p598)
7.35 Allowing a component for profit could in effect mean charging what
the market will bear - and this could mean much higher charges in popular
tourist areas where elasticity of demand is low. The Committee does not
favour this, even for commercial operators, mainly because higher ambitions
for cost recovery would greatly increase the risk of bias towards management
for tourism at the expense of fundamental conservation goals. See paragraph
7.53ff.
`User pays can fund better management'
7.36 The most prominent practical argument put in favour of user charges
was that the revenue can finance better management - better conservation
management and better visitor services. In the case of natural areas,
for example, Mr Donovan argued that tourist operators should see this
as the normal business expense of making provision for maintenance to
conserve their capital resource:
`...tourists can be made to provide substantial funds directly and indirectly
towards the sustainability of the natural environment from which the tourism
industry draws revenue... It is not a question of whether there should
be user pays but rather, when and how much? The quick answer
is - as soon as possible and at a level which provides substantial funds
to ameliorate deterioration on a permanent basis.' (M Donovan, submission
6 p43-4)
7.37 This comment is implicitly focused on popular national parks with
large tourist businesses and low elasticity of demand. It may not be so
applicable to more `ordinary' national parks (that is, ordinary in their
attractions for public recreation) with higher elasticity of demand. [18]
As well, it does not consider the equity dimension; but this is probably
less relevant for higher profile national parks anyway (in light of the
argument that `poorer people probably can't afford to travel to Kakadu').
7.38 The argument was sometimes put in a more positive light, as above
- user pays can fund improved management - and sometimes as a fallback
position - user pays can at least compensate for the reduced central government
support in recent years which many submissions observed:
`For a number of years, the level of Commonwealth contribution to [its]
national park running costs has been decreasing. The introduction of park
fees, and subsequent increases in fees, have been integral in making up
the difference.' (Environment Australia, submission 46 p394)
`Downturns in traditional revenue sources have meant that museums have
to be concerned to protect their future revenue raising opportunities
by placing as little as possible in the free of charge public
domain.' (Australian Museum, submission 30 p239)
...versus `user pays allows governments to reduce central funding'
7.39 In answer many opponents of user charges claimed that in fact user
charges are more often the thin end of the wedge - the means by which
governments wind back central funding:
`The reality, of course, is that any funds at all raised by any government
instrumentality offset funds which would otherwise have been provided
through the normal wider (tax based) funding process. Little net benefit
is ever gained.' (D Chinner, submission 1 p5)
`Experience in the USA has shown that when `user pays' fees were introduced
- Parks and the public came out the losers. That year, the increased
entry fees generated some $50 million, which was earmarked for research
and infrastructure. The next year Congress reduced the parks' budget by
- surprise - $50million [Phillips J, `Can We Save our National Parks',
Sunset, June 1996 pp74-80]' (National Parks Association of Queensland,
submission 25 p208)
7.40 Whether the initiative comes from boards of management or from higher
in government may be a matter of political dispute, but scarcely affects
the result:
Senator Lees: `We have heard in evidence and have a number of
submissions that highlight the case in the natural environment where a
user-pays charge comes in and then the base funding level is dropped to
make up... Is that happening in museums and art galleries as well?...'
Mr Marginson: `Generally the budgets have been held at steady fixed
dollars over a long period of time... I do not think many governments
normally specifically say, `You will introduce a charge.' It becomes a
consequence of budget deliberations by the boards.' (G Marginson, National
Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd, evidence 6 August 1997 p295)
`Our politicians and bureaucrats gave no real choice to an institution
[Australian Museum, Sydney] that for 164 years has been dedicated to the
discovery, preservation and free communication of knowledge about
our natural environment... The [New South Wales] Government claimed it,
too, was opposed to fees and distanced itself from the decision of the
trustees [to introduce general entry fees]. But it had simply cut funds,
ensuring that the museum would go under if the trustees had not either
introduced entrance fees or engaged in wholesale sackings.' (Dr P Pockley,
Sun-Herald 27 October 1991)
7.41 It is a commonplace that people become cynical when they suspect
that a new user charge is simply another form of taxation:
`Whilst it is true that the community is adapting quite quickly to the
idea of legitimate applications of the user pays principle, there is enough
cynicism about to ensure a hostile backlash whenever the consumer suspects
that he or she is the victim of a con job.' (Mackay Research, The Mackay
Report: Keynote: User Pays, October 1992 p32)
Can `hypothecation' of funds reduce this risk?
7.42 Many witnesses, who accepted user charges (sometimes reluctantly)
as a way of funding/improving core activities, tried to avoid the thin
end of the wedge by stressing that the revenue should be retained for
local improvements and not simply siphoned off to the government treasury
(`hypothecation').
`...there is a risk that the implementation of user pays practices may
become a means for governments to send institutions on a downward spiral
of further subsidy reduction based on the income raising potential of
the institution.... The possibility suggests the need for incentive and
income retention agreements between museums and government.' (National
Museum of Australia, submission 42 p359)
Senator Gibbs: `If user-pays system is implemented and then you
recoup a certain amount of money from those people who do go through the
gate, do governments then take away that extra money rather than it being
a supplement to what the government is already paying. That is the danger...'
Mr Donovan: `I am not in favour of the money going back into the
government purse because I have never seen it ever given back again.'
(M Donovan, evidence 16 September 1997 p503)
7.43 A alternative and minority view was that user charges income should
be returned to the central government treasury specifically to break
the nexus between fees and central funding:
`Protected areas should be funded from general revenue on a basis which
is adequate for the purpose and not in any way related to the fees collected.'
(Peak Environmental Enterprises and Conservation Centre of Australia,
submission 15 p137)
7.44 But most submissions that commented on this matter felt strongly
that user charges income should be retained locally - not least because
it creates a more positive attitude among visitors if they can see what
their payments are used for. Environment Australia noted that the World
Tourism Organisation and UNESCO have signed an accord promising co-operation
to `make sure fees collected from visitors and some of the income generated
from tourism goes directly to the protection and maintenance of historic
monuments, as well as conservation of the environment.' [19]
Senator Payne: `It would be, I think, reasonable to observe that
funding and budgets - matters that concern governments regularly - are
changing. They have been changing over 10 to 15 years in terms of the
user-pays principle.... Do you not think that many Australians would find
it reasonable to pay a reasonable fee or a moderate fee to assist in that
process of preserving our environment and playing a role in that in some
small way themselves?'
Mr de Horne: `I agree... The point is that any fees have to be
seen by them to benefit national parks and not just something off the
budget...' (J de Horne, National Parks Association of Queensland, evidence
21 May 1997 p91)
7.45 The evidence on all this was anecdotal and consisted of hopes and
fears as much as observed cases. What is the trend? Are user charges really
adding to the resources of our cultural institutions and nature
conservation agencies, or simply replacing central funding? If the latter,
which is cause and which is effect - is it the facility to charge fees
that encourages governments to reduce central funding, or is it governments'
decision to reduce central funding that forces site managers to charge
fees?
7.46 The first question suggests an obvious research program, which would
be to track the budgets of cultural institutions and national parks services
over time, broken down into central funding and user pays revenue (and
of course accounting for other factors such as the overall enlargement
of the national parks estate) to see whether increasing user charges is
really adding to total resources for improved service. [20]
RECOMMENDATION 4
7.47 The Committee recommends that the Department of Communications
and the Arts, in consultation with State/Territory authorities and relevant
peak bodies, should sponsor research into the trend of user charges and
similar revenues versus budget funding among cultural institutions.
7.48 The Committee recommends that Environment Australia, in consultation
with State/Territory authorities and relevant peak bodies, should sponsor
research into the trend of user charges and similar revenues versus budget
funding among nature conservation agencies.
7.49 The Committee suggests that the second question posed just above
is probably unanswerable, and unimportant. User charges and reduced central
funding have neither cause nor effect, but are aspects of one phenomenon:
they go hand in hand where there exists a broader trend to `user pays'
in general:
`Governments have shifted resources in the economy and there have been
concurrent political pressures to introduce charging for access to services
which have been previously delivered to the user at little or no direct
cost....' (National Museum of Australia, submission 42 p358)
7.50 Where this philosophy exists it will not be changed by `administrative'
recommendations to do with whether fee revenue should be retained locally.
That will not stop governments from reducing central funding correspondingly,
if that is where the philosophy leads. [21]
Ultimately, public funding for public services depends on community support
for them.
`The argument that entry should be free needs to be accompanied by an
argument about the source of replacement funding or a revised assessment
of the value of the institutions and its benefits.' [emphasis added]
(Australian Museum, submission 30 p242)
7.51 This is why the committee argues that entry fees to museums and
art galleries, if they change them from cultural institutions which
we visit as citizens to entertainment businesses which we visit merely
as customers, are so dangerous for their longer term public support.
7.52 The important thing is to affirm as a matter of principle the high
importance of the community benefits that museums, art galleries and national
parks provide. Accordingly, the Committee agrees that they should be funded
from general revenue on a basis which is adequate for the purpose and
not in any way related to the fees collected. Deciding how much is adequate
(having regard to the fact that no grant is ever as great as it could
be, and there are many competing demands for public expenditure) is fundamentally
a political question.
`Reliance on user pays diverts attention from core charters'
7.53 A further argument put against user charges is that they will divert
attention from core conservation/ education functions. Part of this argument
was the administrative complaint that professional staff tend to be inefficiently
distracted by the demands of book-keeping. [22]
The more important part of the argument was that once charges are introduced
managers will come to rely on them, and this will lead to subtle
(or not so subtle) undesirable changes in management's direction. This
was typically described as pressure to `overdevelop' national parks, maximising
revenue at the expense of the core goal of nature conservation, and pressure
to `popularise' museums in a negative sense, at the expense of core goals
of education and cultural enrichment.
7.54 The argument is closely linked to the `thin end of the wedge' argument
described in the previous section: reduced central government funding
is said to be the cause of these undesirable pressures:
`The [Australian Conservation] Foundation ... supports various mechanisms
to ensure that user pays principles are followed, and that funds thus
generated are directed back into proper management. However, this must
not be misused by governments to avoid adequate funding thus making
a nature conservation resource dependent on tourism use.' [emphasis
added] (Australian Conservation Foundation, submission 22 p186)
`...and creates pressure for overdevelopment' (national parks)
7.55 A number of submissions feared that a growing `cost recovery' mentality
in national parks would downgrade the core function of nature conservation
and encourage excessive development for the sake of maximising revenue
from visitors.
`Other visitor facilities, however, such as overnight accommodation and
catering, can be provided by private enterprise outside the park boundaries.
Allowing them within the parks (as at Kosciuszko and Kakadu) as a means
of raising park revenue defiles the natural environment.' (The Colong
Foundation for Wilderness Ltd, submission 7 p58)
7.56 There are two aspects to this: firstly, the fear that managements
will be encouraged to increase visitation, perhaps beyond an environmentally
appropriate level; secondly the fear that managements will come under
pressure to give more emphasis to visible visitor facilities than to less
visible but equally important fundamental conservation projects:
`In may cases there is a desperate need for funds to be put toward feral
animal control, noxious weed control, fire management including hazard
reduction and proper park planning and wildlife research. It is disappointing
then to see the priorities changing toward those of construction, engineering
and development in what is seen to be an attempt to make locally visible
the results of entry fee collection.' (D Chinner, submission 1 p4)
Senator Lees: `Are you suggesting that the reality is that, instead
of spending money perhaps on the control of feral animals or to protect
a particular species within a park, the money go to, let us say, a new
tourist promotion facility or a new toilet block to encourage more people
to visit the park?'
Ms Gibbs: `That is right... Wilpena was going to get several million
dollars for redeveloping the tourist facility, of which $1million was
going to go for upgrading of the entrance off the highway so that people
would have a nice aspect as they were driving up. This was being accounted
for as conservation dollars, while there is no improvement in the real
tangible conservation programs.' (J Gibbs, Conservation Council of South
Australia, evidence 2 July 1997 p167)
7.57 Some who accept user charges in principle emphasised that they should
not be so great a proportion of income as to risk causing bias:
`The Australian Conservation Foundation supports user pays in relation
to visitors to national parks with the following qualifications:...2.
these funds not being the predominant source of revenue for the national
park as this would cause tourism-orientated management to dominate over
nature conservation imperatives.' (Australian Conservation Foundation,
submission 22 p182)
7.58 The Tasmanian Conservation Trust suggested a protocol that no more
than 25 per cent of the costs of track management should be recovered
from current users. [23]
7.59 Several national parks were mentioned as sites of controversy over
conservation versus development:
1. Wilsons Promontory (Vic): proposals for a 150 person licensed
hotel and a serviced lodge within the park, `despite the fact that there
are untapped reserves of accommodation of three and four star level around
the promontory'; [24]
2. Kosciuszko (NSW): `... a large increase in accommodation (about
1,000 beds) for some of the ski resorts... a major development at Perisher,
with buildings up to five storeys in height...' [25]
`Mr Prineas [chairman of the Nature Conservation Council] said the Perisher
master plan was a test case for the future of NSW's national parks, which
faced growing demands for commercial and other access for non-conservation
purposes. Certainly funding is at the bottom of it and I see that
as dangerous for the parks service. he said.' [26]
3. Fraser Island (Qld): `There is now a history over the past decade
of road standards on Fraser Island being developed to meet tour operators'
requirements rather than tour operators acquiring vehicles which would
conform with the best interests of managing Fraser Island... the reluctance
of the Department of the Environment to place a ceiling on visitor numbers
is an indication that they are already addicted to the expectation of
funds from an ever increasing number of visitors, although there is clear
evidence of degradation resulting from overuse of a number of sites.'
[27]
4. Port Arthur (Tas): `...commercial activities have taken precedence
over conservation of the site and have trivialised its significance....
The new plan reads not as a management plan but as a development strategy
devoid of sensitivity towards the heritage values of the site....' [28]
5. Wilpena Pound (SA). [29]
`You have to really be aware of the way things tend to go historically.
A small resort where somebody has chosen to have their weekender gathers
a few more people and then it becomes a small village with more facilities
and it finishes up as a town.' (Dr G Mosley, Peak Environmental Enterprises
and Conservation Centre of Australia, evidence 15 September 1997 p457)
7.60 These stories bring to mind the cautionary tales that one can read
about over-development of national parks in the USA:
`Americans went down the path of allowing increasing access, accommodation
and commercialism in US parks. However, they have seen that, in an ever
crowded world, this is a slippery slope to completely undermining the
nature conservation purpose of national parks. In the July/August edition
of the magazine Audubon, there is a detailed chronicle of regreening
parks through road closures and removal of millions of dollars of commercial
development, including the destruction of hundreds of buildings in California's
Sequoia National Park. The principle that the US Parks Service has rediscovered
is that any use of national parks should be consistent with the primary
purpose of conserving nature; that parks should be passed on unimpaired
to future generations.' [30]
7.61 The United States research mentioned in paragraph 7.46 (footnote
20) tends to support the fears of opponents of user charges. Following
steep increases in entry fees to US national parks in 1986, visitor numbers
became relatively more influential in decisions allocating appropriations
among different national parks; nature conservation needs relatively less
influential. `Since visitors inevitably produce wear and tear on resources,
such an allocation makes some environmental sense... However, increasing
such emphasis may also preclude increasing resources to new issues or
to areas with special needs, such as parks with severe external threats...'
As well, the fee increases did not increase the management autonomy of
the National Parks Service (as some had hoped), but rather increased the
tendency for members of Congress to interfere in day-to-day management:
`One superintendent explained the exact process this way. Rather than
returning the fee money to parks for discretionary operations, representatives
instead observe the increased revenues in the General Fund and then, under
pressure from various constituents, tell field managers what to spend
the money on within individual park units. Thus, even though appropriations
did not go up accordingly, more expenditures were mandated for specific
projects, such as visitor centres or roads, from higher levels... constituents
are more likely since the fee increase to complain to their representatives
about their park experience since they assume that the money they paid
to enter goes back into the park's budget.' [31]
7.62 An underlying issue in this argument is that what constitutes `over-development'
is a matter of opinion: what may be `overdevelopment' to those who emphasise
the conservation function of national parks may simply be `improving access'
to those who emphasise the public recreation function. (The point correlates
to the underlying tension in museums and galleries over how `popular'
they should try to be.) Witnesses of the second type tended to see `pressure
for improved facilities' in a more positive light:
`Seeking value for money, this consumer interest will drive the park
authorities to supply more cost effective services than previously.' (Treasury,
submission 20 p174)
`...and may change the place's focus undesirably' (museums/galleries)
7.63 The concerns just described for national parks have close correlates
in the case of museums and galleries. Many submissions feared that a cost
recovery mentality in museums and art galleries could or would change
their focus detrimentally:
`This extension of use diversifies the purposes and meanings imbued in
an organisation. This can have positive consequences in terms of audience
development. However it can also broaden function too widely, diluting
and confusing the organisation's sense of purpose and core business.'
(Australia Council, submission 35 p287)
`Increasing consumer focus may only result in a different product, rather
than a better quality product. `Safe' exhibitions may not achieve exhibition
and education goals....' (National Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd,
submission 37 p309)
7.64 Some submissions feared the emergence of a `blockbuster treadmill',
where `the audience loses all interest in the permanent and locally based
exhibitions, devaluing the collection and forcing staff focus to remain
on high output exhibitions.' [32]
`We know and say often that collection maintenance and scholarship functions
are important. But even more importantly we must say that good public
programming depends on those functions as much as it does on good education,
good design and so on. If we don't keep this uppermost then we may well
go down the track of the fairground... If museums are forced to depend
critically on earnings from exhibitions and the like, balanced and innovative
and diverse public programming will be out!' [33]
7.65 Some submissions expressed particular fears that too great a `customer
focus' could cause management to downgrade less visible longer term `back-of-house'
functions of collection, curation and research:
`...while increased visitor focus is desirable, it can result in such
a strong visitor focus that other functions of the organisation are eclipsed.'
(Australian Museum, submission 30 p242)
`There is also some concern [in the Western Australian Museum] that less
profitable, but still important programs may be cut with this new focus
upon cost recovery. This may be particularly true for research and long-term
collections.' (Government of Western Australia, submission 53 p464)
`The British Museum (Natural History) has suffered immensely in this
regard. Permanent curatorial appointments are a thing of the past and
over forty scientific and support positions have been lost in the last
four years. In that same period three dinosaur exhibitions have been mounted,
not because of their intrinsic merit but to exploit the almost unique
ability of dinosaurs to attract visitors.' (P Filmer-Sankey, Newcastle
Regional Museum, submission 56 p584)
7.66 On the other hand, increased `customer focus' can be seen in a positive
light, depending on the relative emphasis that one places on the institution's
various functions:
`Customer focus is increasingly recognised as an important element for
major museums to consider.' (National Campaign for the Arts Australia
Ltd, submission 37 p309)
7.67 The different angles of witnesses on this - `increased focus on
customer service' as a positive [34] versus
`unadventurous programming choices... resorting to becoming entertainment
venues' as a negative [35] reflect interesting
underlying tensions over how `popular' museums and galleries should try
to be.
7.68 On the particular problem of caring for deteriorating collections,
the Committee notes the concerns of the Heritage Collections Committee
of the Cultural Ministers Council:
`The silent, scarcely visible damage to items in Australian museums...
(Pigott 1975) remains at crisis point... recent research has shown that
collections in Australian museums are still in a perilous condition (Anderson
1991)... The renaissance experienced by museums since the mid-1970s, and
the dramatic growth in the number, range and quality of museums and programs
in Australia has compounded the problems associated with the conservation
and preservation of collections... While museums continue to collect they
have a backlog of heritage in need of treatment. None of these institutions
has adequate resources to meet their in-house conservation and preservation
needs (Arts Victoria 1991-92)' (Cultural Ministers Council Heritage Collections
Committee, National Conservation and Preservation Policy for Movable
Cultural Heritage, 1995, p7)
7.69 In light of this, the risk that greater `visitor focus' will cause
museums to downgrade back of house functions such as curation is a particular
concern.
Making museums/galleries more `commercial'
7.70 An extra dimension is added to the argument with the proposition
that trying to make museums more `commercial' may be not only dubious
in terms of their core mission; not only detrimental to considerations
of public esteem and `citizenship' (see chapter 4);
but also imprudent simply in terms of their market position. Some fear
that an excessive `entertainment' focus may destroy a museum's traditional
positive image as a worthy cultural institution without establishing
a viable replacement image:
`By charging for general entry, the Museum presents itself as a competitor
with other elements of the entertainment industry. This is
an arena in which museums in the full sense of the word are poorly equipped
to compete. At a stroke they have achieved three things: the cultural
disenfranchisement of a large section of their client group, swapped their
traditional and sympathetic image as places of education and learning
for the hurly burly of commercial entertainment, and put themselves in
direct competition with better equipped and less constrained organisations
for the recreational dollar.' (P Filmer-Sankey, Newcastle Regional Museum,
submission 56 p583)
7.71 Others think that the challenge should be accepted wholeheartedly:
Senator Hogg: `What areas do you see as your direct competitors?'
Mr Morris: `The entertainment industry, without any doubt... I
went to Seaworld in Orlando last year. It had a couple of the finest exhibitions
I have seen anywhere. They were using live animals. They had polar bears
and dugongs in the exhibitions. They were outstanding. They were educationally
sound. The entertainment value was enormous. They invested in the polar
bear exhibition, which was an arctic experience, $US38million. That is
a huge investment in one exhibition. It is quite clear that if you are
just down the road with a museum and you have a few stuffed polar bears
it will not have the same appeal... If we are stuck over here with a bunch
of rocks and stuffed animals on display, assuming that we are doing something
to seriously help benefit this community, we need to think again.' (G
Morris, Museum of Victoria, evidence 15 September 1997 p412)
7.72 Mr Morris envisages a museum that is both educationally relevant
and entertaining - a goal no-one would quibble with. What it means
in practice, and how these goals should be balanced where they conflict,
is of course a matter of constant debate. The question here is what are
the risks of failure.
`People have very intractable attitudes to the role and performance of
museums which permeate even the highest political levels. Generally museums
are regarded as static and unchanging, and a place of serious education...'
(Australian Museum, submission 30 p241)
7.73 There is the risk that if an institution imposes charges for the
sake of a small proportion of cost recovery, it may make itself into something
that is neither fish nor fowl: it may damage its public image as a community
cultural `institution' and come to be seen as merely an entertainment
business; it may lose a large proportion of its visitors (and the political
support that those numbers provide); it may lose volunteer or sponsorship
support; yet it may still not be very effective in competing as an entertainment
business, and it will still need a large proportion of public subsidy,
to get which it needs a positive public image as a community facility.
`Quite aside from the problems a market-centred strategy raises for the
museum's mission, such a strategy is unlikely to be viable in the long
run. For one thing, income earned through admissions and retail operations
represents a limited, if indispensable, part of the art museum's operating
budget - far smaller than is the case for theaters or symphony orchestras,
for example. What this means is that large and hard-won percentage increases
in admission and retail income yield small increases in operating budgets.
Altering this situation would require changing the museum's mission, structure,
and mode of operations, and going into head-to-head competition with department
stores, motion pictures and theme parks. It is not obvious that museums
would fare will in such competition (especially given their limited access
to capital markets) or that they would willingly make the changes such
a strategy would require.' [36]
`Museum directors [should] cultivate, in their public relations campaigns,
the goodwill of the population in general (as opposed to visitors only)
since it is the willingness to pay taxes that is the main source of value
[ie income] for a museum.' [37]
7.74 Thus the cost recovery focus, just as it changes the visitor from
citizen into customer, may change the institution itself, in people's
minds, from a community resource to just another business competing in
a wide market.
7.75 The Committee shares these concerns. We return to the theme of chapter
2: the fundamental reasons for the existence of the place as a public
facility - the core charter to do with education and cultural enrichment
- must be paramount. Otherwise the place has no good reason for existence
in the public realm, and one might well ask what the government is doing
running an entertainment business.
Comment on the risk of diverting from core charters
7.76 The Committee shares the concern that too great a `user pays' focus
risks may detrimentally divert management's attention from core functions.
The weight of evidence on this from opponents of user charges (with examples)
was stronger than the in-principle statements of the other side that user
charges can lead to `improved customer focus.' We acknowledge that the
evidence on this matter was anecdotal, and we recommend wider research
comparable to that on US national parks quoted in paragraph 7.61.
RECOMMENDATION 5
7.77 The Committee recommends that the Department of Communications
and the Arts, in consultation with State/Territory authorities and relevant
peak bodies, should sponsor research on the relationship between user
pays policies and management emphases in cultural institutions.
7.78 The Committee recommends that Environment Australia, in consultation
with State/Territory authorities and relevant peak bodies, should sponsor
research on the relationship between user pays policies and management
emphases in national parks.
7.79 Otherwise, as with the matter of funding discussed further above,
it is hard to suggest `administrative' recommendations on the matter.
Just as the funding of a public institution depends on community support,
so the emphases in its functions and the style of its services depend
ultimately on community preferences. Debates on conservation versus development
in national parks, or what is the proper mission of museums and art galleries,
must be fought out in the political arena. To serve this debate it is
of course vital that nature conservation and cultural heritage agencies
should have orderly, open, consultative strategic planning processes,
so that the community is aware of all options and their consequences,
and can avoid the tyranny of little decisions.
7.80 For the Committee's in-principle view, we repeat the fundamental
themes of chapter 2: these are public institutions
maintained for public purposes of conservation, education and cultural
enrichment. Priority must go to these primary goals: otherwise the whole
reason for maintaining the place in the public realm is undermined. A
certain amount of cost recovery may be possible, but as an influence
on management policy it must be secondary.
Effects of `user pays' on volunteerism and sponsorship
7.81 In 1995 an estimated 11,400 volunteers were involved with 228 museums
and art galleries which had paid staff - an average of 50 volunteers per
institution. There are also about 1,500 museums and galleries around Australia,
mostly small local museums, which have no paid staff. [38]
A 1993 survey found that about 60,000 people had a `work involvement'
in museums and art galleries (defined to include volunteers), and about
75 per cent of these (45,000 `involvements') were completely unpaid. [39]
Volunteerism also exists in national parks, but the Committee has no information
on the extent of it.
7.82 Several submissions argued, mostly in respect of museums and art
galleries, that the services of these volunteers are important (particularly
in small museums and in the country); that `user pays' policies discourage
volunteers; and that, because volunteer help is often badly recognised
in accounts, the detriment of losing it tends to be insufficiently noticed.
`Volunteering arises from the people's desire to contribute to the public
good... The more an institution takes on a private sector profile, the
less it can attract this assistance and support.' (National Association
for the Visual Arts, submission 34 p278)
`An enormous amount of voluntary work is done by members of the public,
particularly through `Friends' organisations. Generally speaking, all
of these contributions from members of the public do not show up on balance
sheets. If our major institutions are run like profit-oriented businesses,
all of this support will, in time, dwindle away to nothing.' (Trustees
of the Tasmanian Museum and Art Gallery, submission 21 p179)
Senator Hogg: `What you have just described [volunteerism] has
been tagged `social capital' in more recent times, and it would seem to
me that that needs to be taken into the equation when one is considering
the funding that is occurring to various institutions. Do you find that
happening in your case?'
Mr Marginson: `No... I do not think it has ever been a greatly
successful argument with government, except in the general sense of the
commitment by the community. In small regional museums, I believe that
that local dedication and commitment is what often sustains them.' (G
Marginson, National Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd, evidence 6 August
1997 p300)
7.83 Similar considerations arise in respect of sponsorship more generally:
`An important effect [of removing entry fees] has been the response of
the business community. Where previously the [Newcastle Regional] Museum
had been fairly unsuccessful in attracting sponsorship, a significant
change in attitude has been observed...Without exception, actual and potential
sponsors indicated that their interest is due to the Museum's very large
visitation and the positive public sentiment towards it. This sentiment
in turn, is due to the adoption of free entry.' (P Filmer-Sankey, Newcastle
Regional Museum, submission 56 p526) [40]
`We find that the capacity to attract private funds, particularly for
buildings, is greatly enhanced because the museum is free. This is an
ideal of generosity that attracts generosity.' (N MacGregor (National
Gallery, UK), New Statesman 7 November 1997 p37)
7.84 When we add the public contribution to the collection, opposition
arises on ethical grounds to charging for access to it:
`All major museums and galleries have valuable works of art and historical
exhibits on long-term loan from members of the community. All benefit
substantially from bequests, gifts of valuable items, gifts of money and
corporate sponsorship.... The contributions made by members of the public
in the past by way of gifts, loans, voluntary work and bequests, in our
view necessitate the giving of free entry to the public to our major institutions.'
(Trustees of the Tasmanian Museum and Art Gallery, submission 21 p179)
`We mentioned the Art Gallery of New South Wales where there is a clear
sense that the public collection, which has been collected over 150 years,
is there for all the community to see and enjoy.' (G Marginson, National
Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd, evidence 6 August 1997 p293)
7.85 Such comments recall a key discussion point of chapter
4: are we citizens or merely customers? Entry fees, if they change
the public image of museums and galleries to merely another entertainment
business, jeopardise these other dimensions of their community purpose.
Miscellaneous arguments
7.86 Many submissions (including both those who favoured `user pays'
and opponents presenting fallback positions) suggested features of a good
user pays regime. We conclude by describing these and some other miscellaneous
arguments, mostly without offering any particular opinion of the Committee.
Should user charges revenue be retained locally?
7.87 Most submissions on national parks felt strongly that user charges
revenue should be retained locally, since there is strong evidence that
charges are accepted by the public more readily when the money is used
for visible local improvements (in the case of museums and galleries this
argument was hardly mentioned). A subtlety is that this emphasises the
concept of fee for service rather than a charge to enter public land -
which is regarded as an important distinction. [41]
7.88 The desirability of retaining income for visible local improvements,
and the risk of pressure to overdevelop the park at the expense of less
visible conservation management needs, are of course two sides of the
same coin. On balance the Committee agrees with retaining income for visible
local improvements, providing one extends the concept to include less
visible local conservation projects. This of course raises the need for
better public education about the true costs - more visible and less visible
- of managing a national park.
Senator Payne: `When you talk about hypothecation of funds to
nature conservation management of the national parks would you contemplate
a direction of some of those funds into an education process like that?'
Mr Wright: `I think education is a very important part of park
management.' (P Wright, Australian Conservation Foundation, evidence 15
September 1997 p461)
7.89 Local contribution to local improvements should be seen as something
more than just public relations massaging. It relates to the discussion
of `citizenship' in chapter 4: the local contribution with visible local
results can help put over the idea that the facility does not just belong
to `the government' - it is ours as a community. This is the same
attitude that promotes volunteerism and sponsorship.
`I am doing a review of advisory committees that assist with national
park issues in Tasmania. One of the key things which has come up is we
have now developed a strategic approach to what we call community partnership...
There are many people with an intimate knowledge of their coastline -
people who are quite willing to form groups to assist with some management
decisions and things of that kind.' (Prof. B Davis, evidence 7 March 1997
p7)
7.90 A nuance to the question is `how local is local'? In other words,
at what level should money be pooled? Is it fair to ask visitors at more
popular national parks to subsidise facilities at more remote national
parks? The National Parks Association of Queensland thought it was not
fair; [42] by contrast, the Conservation Council
of South Australia recommended hypothecation within the region: `charges
raised to enter a large park could be used in that and in smaller nearby
parks.' [43] Another view is that hypothecation
for the purposes of the organisation is sufficient, and is necessary for
flexible management:
`It is necessary to have flexibility to target particular projects or
areas from one year to the next. For instance, it may be a priority to
undertake a major capital works program in an area that does not generate
much revenue. This program may be financed out of revenue generated in
a number of different areas.' [44]
7.91 The same range of opinions on this point was reported in Managing
Australia's World Heritage, a 1996 report by the House of Representatives
Standing Committee on Environment, Recreation & the Arts.
Is there a need for standardisation of user charges?
7.92 The question sometimes arose in evidence, is there any need for
a `national policy' on user charges in museums, art galleries and national
parks? Few submissions addressed this issue. One relevant comment was:
`Tourists and holiday makers in Australia are being faced with an endless
array of small and irritating charges all of which tend eventually to
discourage travel and the enjoyment of areas which, in tourist and economic
terns, should be the source of longer stays and more frequent visits.'
(D Chinner, submission 1 p3) [45]
7.93 On the other hand, several submissions spoke of the need for flexibility
in response to local circumstances (particularly in relation to schemes
of concessions). [46] Professor Davis favoured
`careful consideration of the pattern of parks usage, so as to cater for
repeat visitors, casual visitors and tourism operators.' [47]
Mr Grey commented:
`These services have both private and public components and each on will
have its own peculiar mix and will vary from park to park, from site to
site and within the site itself on some occasions.' (F Grey, evidence
15 September 1997 p428)
7.94 On the whole a need for standardisation was not regarded as an issue.
The evidence on national parks suggests that entry fees should be sensitive
to elasticity of demand, which may vary greatly from one national park
to another depending on the alternative attractions; and The Committee
has recommended that user charges for value-added services should be based
on marginal cost recovery (providing the services really are optional
extras, and not just proxies for an entry fee - see paragraph 7.26). In
the case of museums and galleries, the Committee supports free entry for
key national and state institutions as a matter of social policy. For
both national parks and museums/galleries economic theory suggests free
entry wherever charges would significantly depress demand. [48]
We hesitate to make any more detailed recommendations - local circumstances
are too variable.
Policies for tourist operators versus private visitors
7.95 Some witnesses thought it was unfair that in some national parks
commercial tourist operators must pay fees while private visitors do not.
`Is there really any reason why a family going up by car to a national
park and enjoying that is any different from people who take a bus trip
there?' (J de Horne, National Parks Association of Queensland, evidence
21 May 1997 p92)
7.96 This was especially raised in relation to the Great Barrier Reef
Marine Park Environmental Management Charge. [49]
Others thought it was quite fair to make tourist operators pay for their
commercial use of public property.
Senator Hogg: `Why should the commercial people have to pay for
a permit when the locals can go out and watch the whales for nothing?'
Mr Wellard: `...It is a philosophical argument, I guess, because
the argument would be that the commercial people are actually utilising
the public resource for commercial gain so they, therefore, need to put
money back in to help with the management of that resource.' (G Wellard,
Queensland Departmentt of Environment, evidence 21 May 1997 p101)
7.97 The principle is analogous to the extra charges for commercial use
reported by some libraries and archives. [50]
The equity issues echo those raised in respect of visitors versus local
residents (paragraph 4.22ff).
7.98 Some thought that national park authorities are generally not very
good at making money from commercial tourist operations: `Park managers
are not without blame for their own situation either. Licence fees are
so low as to be ridiculous...' [51] Mr Donovan
quoted an opinion that would go even further:
`Extract: Pacific Asia Travel Association Conference:... Indeed,
the concept that those who profit from tourism should contribute to conservation
can and should be applied to the wide range of businesses - hotels, stores
and restaurants - that make money from visitors to historical monuments
and sites.' (M Donovan, submission 6 p50)
7.99 Mr Sinclair described various bureaucratic impediments that national
park authorities put in the way of tourist operators, and regarded these
as particularly regrettable on the grounds that sometimes environmental
impacts can be minimised by encouraging visitors to come on tours rather
than privately. [52]
7.100 The Committee agrees that commercial tourist operators should be
charged fees that represent a fair contribution to preserving the resource
from which they draw profit. Where tourist operators are charged and private
visitors are not, it is usually because of the greater practical problems
of targeting the private visitors, and this must be accepted as a rational
management response. As noted in paragraph 7.35, the Committee does not
favour charging an additional component for profit (the `cash cow'
that tourist operators objected to [53]), mainly
because higher ambitions for cost recovery could increase the risk of
bias towards management for tourism at the expense of fundamental conservation
goals.
Consultation and timing of new regimes
7.101 Around the time of this inquiry there was particular criticism
of an increase to the Great Barrier Reef Environmental Management Charge.
In August 1996 as a budget-related decision, the government announced
that the charge (then $1 per visitor per day) would rise to $6 from 1
January 1997. In light of concerns expressed by tourist operators the
government later amended its plan so as to increase the Environmental
Management Charge to $2 from 1 January 1997 and to $4 (with various concessions)
from 1 April 1998.
7.102 There has been criticism of the short lead time for the increase
of the Environment Management Charge. [54]
The Inbound Tourism Organisation of Australia Ltd, without referring to
the Great Barrier Reef issue by name, stressed that tourist operators
make international contracts well in advance, and (depending on foreign
laws that may limit options for variation clauses) they may be unable
to pass on to customers extra government charges levied during the contract
period:
`We do ask that the Committee... take into account the special problems
of the inbound tourism industry and the impossible task it has in passing
on price increases, including government charges on the user pays principle,
when notice of less than two years is given.' (Inbound Tourism Organisation
of Australia Ltd, submission 45 p384ff)
7.103 The Committee endorses this concern. The underlying issue is that
government levies are liable to change much more erratically, in much
larger lumps, than ordinary business costs. What is needed is not only
adequate consultation and notice to the industry in the event of changes,
but also a stable ongoing policy of making changes in small increments
at more regular intervals.
Details of user charges schemes
7.104 Submissions, mostly in respect of national parks, described the
great variety of ways that user charges are levied around Australia (see
paragraph 2.21ff). Most of this is uncontroversial (if we have accepted
user charges in principle) and the Committee has no particular comment
except:
1. It appears that the public reacts negatively to the absence
of appropriate concessions, particularly for families and pensioners.
[55] The Committee supports the inclusion of
suitable concessions both on equity grounds and for the sake of good public
relations.
2. One option raised in submissions was higher charges for international
tourists. [56] This does not seem to be done
much at present. The philosophical justification for this would be that
these people have not contributed to management costs through their taxes;
the practical justification would be that they are probably less price
sensitive than domestic tourists. An opposing view is that because of
the wider importance of tourism to the Australian economy, attempts to
`milk' tourists, if they reduce the overall attraction of Australia as
a tourist destination, could be counter-productive. [57]
There is also the practical problem that international tourists do not
walk around with labels on their foreheads saying `international tourist.'
Where the cost of collecting fees is excessive
7.105 Several submissions, mostly in respect of national parks, argued
against entry fees/ user charges on the grounds that the cost of collecting
them may be prohibitive. [58] On the other
hand, the Committee notes that honesty boxes and advance ticketing schemes
which some submissions described can make it viable to charge for remote
or little visited national parks where it would not be viable with the
traditional staffed tollbooth.
7.106 In any case, a situation where it is not practical to collects
fees says nothing about another situation where it is practical.
Where the cost of collection is excessive, the economically rational course
is simple: don't try. There was no suggestion in evidence by management
authorities that they do anything other than follow this rule. It leads
to a windfall gain to visitors who escape paying, but the Committee does
not think that this should be called an injustice to visitors in other
places who do pay, providing the charge is fair in principle.
Rationing fragile areas by price or permit
7.107 Some submissions suggested (mostly in relation to national parks)
that user charges can be used to ration access to fragile areas or areas
where visitors' satisfaction is reduced by congestion. [59]
An alternative view is that this is unfair to poorer people, and where
rationing is necessary it should be done in ways that do not depend on
ability to pay (as is already done in a few national parks by means such
as permits and booking systems).
7.108 We note as a related matter that entry fees may reduce vandalism:
`When we introduced fees in Belair, the most significant flow-on effect
was the reduction in vandalism and hooliganism in Belair National Park.
The fact that we began to charge took out a whole element of park users
that were, in our terms as managers, undesirable.' (A Holmes, SA Dept
of Environment and Natural Resources, evidence 2 July 1997 p141)
7.109 Rationing by price was not mentioned in relation to museums and
archives Several submissions commented that access to fragile items might
have to be restricted, but none suggested it should be done by imposing
charges for that purpose; the tacit assumption is that more sensitive
controls are necessary (such as limiting access to researchers who will
then publish for a wider public). [60]
7.110 The Committee acknowledges that rationing by price can be an economically
efficient way of maximising the welfare gain from a congested public good
(since, when a charge is imposed, those who drop out first will tend to
be those who value the good least). Nevertheless, on balance the Committee
does not agree with rationing by price. Efficiency must be balanced against
equity. We consider that the matter of principle is the more important
consideration. National parks and cultural institutions belong to the
community as a whole. Where access needs to be restricted for conservation
reasons, it should be done in a way that is impartial to all. Where permit
and booking systems are used, any associated fees should not be so great
as to depress demand, but rather should aim to cover administrative costs
only.
Footnotes
[1] Australian Library and Information Association,
Statement on Free Library Services to All, 1979-1994
[2] National Library of Australia, submission
44 p378
[3] Australian Archives, submission 33 p264
[4] National Film and Sound Archive, submission
40 p340
[5] Australian Museum, submission 30 p245
[6] for example, Queensland Museum, submission
31 p248; Australian Archives, submission 33 p263; National Library of
Australia, submission 44 pp381-2; Australian Society of Archivists Inc.,
submission 47 p416
[7] Wildlife Preservation Society of Australia,
submission 9 p92. Also for example, Dr C Nobbs, submission 39 p 335, Government
of the Northern Territory, submission 41 p355. A few submissions opposed
these things in any case on conservation grounds: `Development within
national parks should be limited to properly maintained park roads, parking
and toilet facilities. We are opposed to commercial development or any
form of revenue raising within parks.' Colong Foundation for Wilderness,
submission 7 p59
[8] Queensland Museum, submission 31 p249
[9] National Library of Australia, submission
44 pp381-2
[10] Australian Museum, submission 30 p244.
Similarly Queensland Museum, submission 31 p248
[11] National Film and Sound Archive, submission
40 p340-1
[12] This conceptual scheme explains the otherwise
perplexing difference between a half-empty museum and a half-empty cinema.
Both are excludable non-rival public goods; in both cases the avoidable
cost of admitting an extra user is zero, the efficient charge is zero,
and a deadweight loss of welfare is created by refusing free admission
to those unwilling to pay. The difference is that in the case of the cinema
society does not recognise any `merit good'/ `core service' element, and
so does not subsidise fixed costs. In the language of this section, the
whole existence of the cinema is `marginal' (dispensible) to society.
The cinema operator must perforce charge entry fees that cover fixed costs.
Society accepts the deadweight loss of welfare as the price of refusing
public funding.
[13] As, for example, in the National Library
of Australia's pricing principles dotpointed in paragraph 7.15.
[14] Wildlife Preservation Society of Australia,
submission 9 p92; Dr C Nobbs, submission 39 p 335
[15] `Economic rent' is a price which a producer
can extract above that necessary to keep the factors of production in
their present use. In the case of a national park the possibility may
arise because of the operator's position as the monopoly provider of access
to a uniquely attractive place.
[16] Where elasticity of demand is significant,
the arguments of chapter 5 suggest that entry fees
should not be charged.
[17] That is, using user charges to contribute
to improved facilities was uncontroversial among those who believe
it is good to improve facilities. In the committee's evidence environment
groups varied in how much development they regard as acceptable in national
parks.
[18] See paragraph 5.49 for comment by the
New South Wales National Parks & Wildlife Service.
[19] Environment Australia, submission 46 p396
[20] Similar research in the USA following
steep increases in national park entry fees in about 1986 found no increase
in overall resources to national parks. In spite of the promises of proponents
before the fee increases, the increased fees entered general government
revenue but appropriations were not increased in return. Lowry W R, `Land
of the fee: entrance fees and the National Park Service', Political
Research Quarterly [University of Utah] vol. 46 no. 4, Dec.
1994, p823ff
[21] The Committee does support retaining revenue
locally for other practical reasons: the evidence was that it makes visitors
accept user charges more readily. See paragraph 7.87ff.
[22] D Chinner, submission 1 p6
[23] Tasmanian Conservation Trust, submission
17 p147
[24] The Colong Foundation for Wilderness,
submission 7 p67; Peak Environmental Enterprises and Conservation Centre
of Australia, submission 15 p138
[25] The Colong Foundation for Wilderness,
submission 7 p72
[26] Sydney Morning Herald, 20 October 1997
p4
[27] Fraser Island Defenders Organization/
J Sinclair, submission 43a p367-8
[28] A Piper, submission 2 p13,18. For a contrary
view see Prof. B Davis, evidence 7 March 1997 p2
[29] Wildlife Preservation Society of Australia,
submission 9 p96; J Gibbs (Conservation Council of South Australia), evidence
2 July 1997 p167,174
[30] P Figgis (Australian Conservation Foundation),
Sydney Morning Herald 5 November 1997 p16
[31] Lowry W R, `Land of the fee: entrance
fees and the National Park Service', Political Research Quarterly [University
of Utah] vol. 46 no. 4, Dec. 1994, p839-840
[32] National Campaign for the Arts Australia
Ltd, submission 37 p309
[33] Griffin D, `What is the notion of access
in museums all about?', Something for Everyone: Access to Museums,
proceedings of 1991 conference of the Council of Australian Museum Associations,
Adelaide 1991, p13-14
[34] Australian Museum, submission 30 p240
[35] National Association for the Visual Arts,
submission 34 p277
[36] DiMaggio P J in Feldstein M ed., The
Economics of Art Museums, University of Chicago Press 1991, p49
[37] Martin F, `Determining the size of museum
subsidies', Journal of Cultural Economics vol. 18 no. 4, 1994-5,
p263
[38] Museums Australia Inc., Museums 1995:
art museums, museums and public galleries in Australia, Museums Australia
July 1996, p9. Cultural Ministers Council Statistical Advisory Group,
Museums, Art Museums and Commercial Galleries in Australia 1993,
1993
[39] A `work involvement' was defined as being
involved in an activity, for the benefit of someone outside the respondent's
family, whether paid or unpaid, at least once during the sample year.
Australian Bureau of Statistics, Work in Selected Culture/Leisure Activities
- Australia, March 1993, 1993, p1,8
[40] In 1996 the value of corporate support
to the arts (including unconditional donations, sponsorship in return
for promotion, and various assistance in kind) was $65million, about 9
per cent of which went to museums and galleries. As a proportion of total
public benefit corporate support the arts has declined from 13 per cent
in 1986 to 5 per cent in 1996 (other categories are sport, education and
welfare). 29 per cent of supporters and 51 per cent of non-supporters
agreed that `the arts should be able to stand on its own without support
from government or business.' The survey was conducted at a level of generality
which sheds little light on Filmer-Sankey's proposition; but it is possibly
relevant that the most reported reasons for supporting the arts were `as
a community service' and `to improve the image of the company in the public's
eyes'. Yann Campbell Hoare Wheeler, Corporate Support for the Arts
1996, Australia Council 1996, pp5,6,24,29,33,36
[41] Queensland National Parks & Wildlife
Service & Department of Environment, Benchmarking and Best Practice
Program: user pays revenue, report for ANZECC September 1996 p23
[42] National Parks Association of Queensland
Inc., submission 24 p207
[43] Conservation Council of South Australia,
submission 29 p235
[44] Government of Queensland, quoted in House
of Representatives Standing Committee on Environment, Recreation &
the Arts, Managing Australia's World Heritage, Canberra 1996, p177
[45] Note the underlying view that payments
for entry to these public heritage sites are qualitatively different from
payments in the ordinary course of business. No-one objects to paying
an array of small charges when they go shopping and visit an array of
small shops.
[46] For example, National Film and Sound Archive,
submission 40, p340-1
[47] Prof. B Davis, submission 5 p38
[48] This assumes the marginal cost of admitting
an extra visitor is near zero.
[49] Mike Ball Dive Expeditions Australia,
submission 51 p453; Tourism Council Australia, submission 57 p595.
[50] National Library of Australia, submission
44 p382; National Film and Sound Archive, submission 40 p340
[51] M Donovan, submission 6 p51. Similar comments
are in House of Representatives Standing Committee on Environment, Recreation
& the Arts, Managing Australia's World Heritage, Canberra 1996,
p181
[52] Fraser Island Defenders Organization/
J Sinclair, submission 43a p365ff.
[53] Tourism Council Australia, submission
57 p598
[54] W Williams, evidence 20 May 1997
[55] Queensland National Parks & Wildlife
Service & Department of Environment, Benchmarking and Best Practice
Program: user pays revenue, report for ANZECC September 1996 p23
[56] National Campaign for the Arts Australia
Ltd, submission 37 p316
[57] The question depends on the elasticity
of demand for Australia as a whole as a tourist attraction, and for particular
attractions within Australia.
[58] For example, J de Horne (National Parks
Association of Queensland), evidence 21 May 1997 p88
[59] Treasury, submission 20 p173-5; Environment
Australia, submission 46 p396
[60] Australian Institute for the Conservation
of Cultural Material Inc., submission 16 p142
Top
|