6. Entry fees: equity arguments

Access to Heritage
Table of Contents

6. Entry fees: equity arguments

`Free entry is a subsidy by poorer nongoing taxpayers to richer goers'

6.1 Supporters of user charges argued that free entry is a subsidy by poorer nongoers to richer goers. In full the argument consists of a claim that visitors to museums, art galleries and national parks tend to be the better off people; a value judgment that the transfer from poorer nongoing taxpayers to richer visitors (through the public subsidy of museums, galleries and national parks) is unfair; and a conclusion that the unfairness can and should be remedied by making the visitors pay. We will consider each part in turn. [1]

Socio-economic profile of visitors to museums and galleries

6.2 It is a commonplace that museum and gallery visitors are drawn disproportionately from the educated professional classes who have the `cultural capital' (basically, education) to benefit from what they offer (the phenomenon is stronger for art galleries than for history museums). [2] There is a close correlation between low tendency to visit and low education and (as a predictable complement) low occupational status. All submissions regarded this as regrettable and stressed the need for access and equity programs to broaden the appeal of museums and galleries, quite apart from the particular matter of user pays policies. [3]

6.3 To what extent visitors are also the `better-off people', an important point in the terms of the present argument, is less certain. The correlation between tendency to visit and income exists, but is weaker -

`Bourdieu and Darbel [in their `now classic' 1969 study, For the Love of Art] found...that level of educational attainment and occupational status had a more direct bearing on museum and gallery attendance than level of income. This is not to say that income had no role in such matters. Its role, however, was an indirect one, mediated through the part it plays in helping secure the forms and levels of education and professional status associated with, in particular, art gallery usage.' [4]

6.4 In other words, education is the main predictor of propensity to visit; to the extent that income does not correlate perfectly with education (not all highly educated people are rich and not all rich people are highly educated), income will also not correlate perfectly with propensity to visit. [5]

6.5 In a recent South Australian survey the income profile of a group of museum and gallery goers was little different from that of a group of nongoers (except that an above average proportion of art gallery visitors reported annual household incomes over $60,000). [6] Similarly, an Australia Council survey of domestic tourists' cultural activities found that the tendency to visit museums and art galleries while travelling away from home differs predictably depending on level of education, but does not differ so much depending on level of income. [7] A recent Australia Council survey of Aboriginal & Torres Strait Islanders and people of non-English-speaking background found that `...the demographic and other differences between [a survey sample of] visitors and non-visitors [to the Powerhouse Museum, Sydney] were not great. Differences in income, education, exposure to museums and other typical distinguishing characteristics did not adequately explain the decision to visit or not to visit. The experience of having visited the museum appeared to be, in itself, a distinguishing factor...' [8]

6.6 Little is known about the socio-economic profile of visitors to special exhibitions and whether this differs significantly from that of visitors to permanent collections. [9]

6.7 To turn to the whole population (as distinct from visitors): [10] it has been suggested that, in relation to visiting museums, there are three types of people: frequent visitors, perhaps 15 per cent of the population; a middle group of occasional visitors, perhaps 40 per cent; and hardly ever visitors, perhaps 45 per cent. [11] Frequent visitors probably answer to the stereotyped educated élite (more or less); hardly ever visitors are committed nongoers; the middle group of occasional/potential visitors are, implicitly, the main target of museums' access and equity programs. In their demographic profile the middle group is far closer to the non-visitors (lower educational and occupational status) than to the frequent visitors (as in the Powerhouse Museum survey mentioned just above) - a point which has important implications for access and equity programs. [12]

Socio-economic profile of visitors to national parks

6.8 The Committee discovered practically no information on the socio-economic profile of national park visitors. We suspect that that there is less interest in the question in national parks than in museums, probably partly because national parks have less of the cachet of social improvement, causing fewer concerns about access and equity; partly because national park visitation has grown strongly in the last decade: managers' attention is probably focussed more on coping with people who do visit than on asking why some people don't. [13]

6.9 A commonsense theoretical view is that because of the expense of a national park holiday poorer people are probably excluded anyway:

`...in many situations given the costs associated with travelling to many environmental or cultural heritage sites (eg Great Barrier Reef, Uluru), low income earners may not be able to visit them at all.' (Treasury, submission 20 p175)

6.10 On the other hand, a visit to Uluru or the Great Barrier Reef is a very different thing from a daytrip to a popular national park on the city limits. It may well be that the latter is a much more typical national park `holiday' than the former; [14] and one would expect the income profile of these visitors to be lower. [15] As well, a camping holiday is a relatively cheap form of overnight stay. A recent South Australian survey seems to confirm that visiting national parks is more evenly spread across educational groups than visiting museums and galleries:

`...those with only primary education reported that they were more likely than the more highly educated groups not to take part in all cultural activities - `high' or `low' - except for visiting friends, eating out, church attendances, picnicking, visiting national parks and watching television.' [16]

6.11 The Australia Council survey of domestic tourists' cultural activities mentioned in paragraph 6.5 had similar results for national park visits as for museum/ gallery visits: tendency to visit is positively correlated with level of education, and also positively correlated with level of income - but not so strongly. [17]

6.12 Professor Bennett surmises that the socio-economic profile of national park visitors is more `average' than that of museum/gallery visitors:

`I cannot recall any surveys done, for example, of the social profile of visitors to national parks but I do know that, if you look at the social profile of visitors to botanical gardens, they are spread much more broadly. There is much greater cross-class - if you like, a general community - participation in those institutions. I would expect the same is true of national parks... it would be difficult to identify any systemic barriers to access [of the kind that exist in relation to museums and galleries]...' (Prof. T Bennett, evidence 21 May 1997 p80)

6.13 But, considering the `travel cost' argument just mentioned, it is likely that the socio-economic profile of visitors varies much more from one national park to another than from one museum or gallery to another.

Is it `unfair' for poorer nongoers to subsidise richer goers?

6.14 The Committee considers that the claimed disproportionate presence of better-off people is, in the case of museums and galleries, generally true but the extent of the disproportion uncertain; in the case of national parks, unproven one way or the other on average. But if it is true, is it `unfair'?

6.15 We note first that using some people's taxes to subsidise other people's benefits is not `unfair' in principle: it is a large part of the business of government in any civilised compassionate society. Healthy people's taxes subsidise sick people's hospital care; childless people's taxes subsidise the education of other people's children. [18] An equity problem is perceived only if there is a systematic transfer of benefits from less advantaged to more advantaged people. [19]

6.16 Assuming for the moment that this is the case, is it `unfair'? The committee does not wish to pass judgment on this; we only point out that the there are imponderable ethical issues involved and the answer is not as obvious as is implied by the supporters of user charges who put this argument. How important are the sums of money involved? Is it fair to ask everyone to contribute perhaps a few dollars a year to national institutions that exist primarily for their community/ non-use benefits, even if this incidentally provides a windfall gain to better-off direct users? How do we discount the `unfairness' to allow for the fact that there is wide public acceptance of the value of public subsidy to cultural institutions and nature conservation even among people who are not direct users? [20] How do we discount for the fact that they are widely seen as `merit goods' (that is, society wishes to encourage their consumption)? [21]

`Culture and heritage is not necessarily a short term consumable where the customer can have a complete and comprehensive understanding of the product's utility prior to use.' (Australia Council, submission 35 p288)

`There is little doubt that merit good considerations have probably been the most significant single explanation of government involvement in the arts in all the countries we are dealing with. If the motivations of politicians can be inferred from their public pronouncements, it is clear that most of them believe that the existence of the arts is essential to civilized life.' (Throsby C D & Withers G A, The Economics of the Performing Arts, Melbourne 1979 p192-3)

6.17 How do we value the fact that among the better-off visitors there are some poorer visitors, who may disproportionately value free entry, who may be gaining disproportionate benefit, and who may be disproportionately discouraged by entry fees? A favourite story in museum circles is the story of the poor working class child who is awakened and set on the path to self-fulfilment and high achievement by dropping in to the free public museum. Perhaps in reality these lives are few, but they do exist - how much are they worth?

6.18 And if, even now, we accept that the situation is `unfair', is imposing user charges a good response? This is the question of practical importance. The socio-economic profile of visitors we have described is a static situation; introducing user charges makes the situation dynamic. What other results would the change cause? Could the side-effects be damaging? This brings us to the main argument put against the `unfair subsidy' argument: that user charges will disproportionately discourage poorer or otherwise disadvantaged people - the very people who (at least in the case of museums and galleries) are the targets of access and equity programs. We will describe this argument before commenting further.

...versus `fees disproportionately discourage poorer people'

6.19 A number of submissions argued that entry fees would disproportionately discourage poorer and disadvantaged people. Some put the argument in context of general opposition to user charges; others merely to press for suitable concessions. Some referred to particular groups who would be relatively disadvantaged:

`National park entry fees would certainly reduce their utilisation by families, individuals and social groups who have limited financial capacity.' (National Parks Association of Queensland Inc., submission 24 p206)

`Since Indigenous people are the most economically disadvantaged group of Australians, a charge would have more of a deterrent effect for them than for non-Indigenous Australians - surely an inequitable and unjustified outcome.' (Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander Commission, submission 52 p460)

6.20 The implication here is that because `limited financial capacity' is systematically associated with other social disadvantages (relating to education, ethnicity, etc.), anything that tends to exclude the poor from the use of public services is in effect an unfair `double whammy' for these people. Obviously, as discussed in chapter 3, poorer people are excluded from many things in our society. The piquancy of the complaint here is that these are public services, supposedly provided for all. [22]

6.21 The question is, what is the elasticity of demand broken down by socio-economic groupings? When a charge is introduced and visitation drops, are poorer people the first to drop out? Or are the now-absent ones a cross-section of society similar to continuing visitors?

Elasticity of demand for museums/galleries by socio-economic profile

6.22 Making allowance for the uncertainties, on balance there seems to be strong evidence that museum entry fees (probably even `modest' fees) significantly discourage visitors (see chapter 5). But there seems to be very little hard information on the equity question: what type of people the discouraged ones are.

`What is not clear, however, is who stops using museums and galleries when admission charges are applied.' (Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p83) [23]

6.23 It has been suggested that, in relation to visiting museums, there are three types of people: frequent visitors, perhaps 15 per cent of the population; a middle group of occasional/potential visitors, perhaps 40 per cent; and hardly ever visitors, perhaps 45 per cent. Significantly, in their socio-economic profile the middle group is far closer to the non-visitors (lower educational and occupational status) than to the frequent visitors (see paragraph 6.7).

6.24 An obvious inference is that the first group has a low elasticity of demand (they are committed goers), the third group has a low elasticity of demand (they would never go anyway), while the waverers in the middle are likely to have a higher elasticity, and so are likely to be more affected by fees than the committed goers. Since the middle group has lower socio-economic status than the committed goers, the reasoning supports the intuitive suggestion, made in several submissions, that in response to entry fees poorer people would probably drop out disproportionately:

`Admission charges do however probably compound the bias in the socio-economic/ educational profile of museums visitors towards upper levels.' (Australian Museum, submission 30 p241)

6.25 An implicitly contrary view (if one assumes that repeat visitors tend to be the better off people) is that `A more likely explanation for the kinds of declining figures reported... is that those who already regularly visit museums and galleries do so less frequently when charges are introduced, perhaps partly because of a revaluation of the marginal value of repeat visits but also because frequent users are the most likely to oppose, and so also to resent, the introduction of admission charges.' [24]

6.26 A 1991 Australia Council survey of art gallery visitors found that `those from poorer households were more likely to report that admission charges would discourage them from visiting art galleries: 54 per cent against a sample average of 44 per cent.' [25] A 1995 Australia Council study of older people and the arts (including museums and art gallery visitation) found that older people greatly value participating in the arts, but find cost a significant barrier: `Young people can replace the money they spend, but we [retirees] can't.' [26]

6.27 A 1996 Australia Council study of barriers to museum visitation among non-English-speakers and Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander people found that `cost (entry fee, especially for large families)' figured most prominently. [27] The Australia Museum comments generally: `There can be no doubt that admission charges result in a decline in family visits.' [28] This is a particular matter of concern if we consider that positive early experience of museums is probably a significant predictor of propensity to visit throughout life:

`The experience of having visited the museum appeared to be, in itself, a distinguishing factor.... Once people had visited they were generally positive about the experience, visited again and sometimes took others to visit.' [29]

6.28 The National Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd compared recent Australian research on the demographic profile of nongoers with Canadian research showing that cost is a relatively important `leisure motivation' for that type of people:

`According to an Ontario report involving the Ontario gallery, museum, science centre and zoo, attendance cost was an important factor to single income and families with children, to recent immigrants, to older people (50+), and those with lower attained education levels. Cost remains an important factor to the reluctant museum visitor, raising issues of fairness and equity.' [30]

6.29 Anecdotal evidence from the National Gallery of Victoria, which removed its general entrance fee on 1 July 1996, was:

`The attendant staff who man the floors of the gallery commented within a week or two weeks of the charge going, “We have people in this building who do not know what to do in an art gallery...” It means that we are going to a different audience with what seems like a simple gesture.' (J Payne, National Gallery of Victoria, evidence 15 September 1997 p402) [31]

6.30 Similarly in the case of the Powerhouse Museum, Sydney:

`It is almost worth this inquiry going to the Powerhouse on the day of free admission, because the number of people that you see in that museum and the range of Australians that you see - I would almost say to you that the language that is most frequently spoken is not English on those days - are people who would obviously not otherwise go to that museum. It is extraordinary.' (Dr S Wallace, Museums Australia, evidence 16 September 1997 p486)

6.31 These observations tend to support the other comments above suggesting that middle group of occasional/potential visitors - the main focus of attempts to increase visitation through access an equity programs - are sensitive to price, and that for them entry fees are a disincentive additional to other cultural barriers.

`I think that the experience in Australia and overseas is that [entry fees] would result in a significant decline in attendances. I believe that that decline would be registered in the very areas where we are making enormous efforts to increase patronage by developing specific programs...' (Dr C Turner, Queensland Art Gallery, evidence 21 May 1997 p126)

`We believe it is clear from the evidence we have reviewed that the widespread introduction of museum charges in Australia would, at present, reduce the rate at which museums and art galleries are used by present users while, at the same time, making them marginally less accessible to non-users by adding an economic [dis]incentive to the existing cultural disincentives which disincline non-users to visit...' (Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p87)

Elasticity of demand for national parks by socio-economic profile

6.32 The Committee has no information on elasticity of demand by socio-economic profile for national parks. The first intuitive answer would be, `of course poorer people will be the first to drop out in response to charges - it's more likely that they can't afford it.' This is in effect the `last straw' argument put in some submissions. But this is not necessarily valid. Elasticity of demand for a good depends both on price relative to buyer's income and on availability of substitutes. [32] In the case of a national park holiday, the entry fee is likely to be a small proportion of total costs, diluting any `can we afford it?' effect. A camping holiday, being a relatively cheap holiday, may be more attractive to poorer people (hence their demand less elastic) because of lack of substitutes at that price level (with provisos that national parks may differ greatly one from another in these matters, as just noted). We do not know. In cases where elasticity of demand is low anyway - when `modest' fees are charged, hardly anyone drops out - the question becomes unimportant.

Comparison of museums/galleries and national parks

6.33 On elasticity of demand, the comparison of national parks and museums/galleries is perplexing. The socio-economic profile of national park visitors is probably more average than that of museum visitors (less educated/ professional/ high income bias), yet demand for national parks, to judge from the evidence we have described, is probably less elastic, at least in some cases. This is inconsistent with the intuitive view that in response to charges poorer people would be likely to drop out first.

6.34 Part of the explanation may be that elasticity of demand depends not only on price compared with income, but also on the availability of substitutes. The national parks with low elasticity are likely to be those with rare or unique attractions. Similarly, there may be few substitutes for a museum as a free day out indoors (the scenario of the `wet Sunday afternoon' visitors); but a charging museum is competing in a quite different market.

6.35 Part of the explanation may lie in different attitudes to the benefits of a national park visit versus a museum/gallery visit. Perhaps the image of national parks is more to do with `mere' recreation, seen as a simple private benefit which most people are willing to pay for; [33] perhaps the image of museums is more to do with education and cultural enrichment - a complex, perhaps inseparable mixture of private and community benefits which more people see as the right of all. [34] It may be that any charge for museums has a disproportionately negative effect on people who, in light of these value-laden and emotionally charged concepts, may resent paying anything for what they regard as a public facility. [35]

`Museums have traditionally been seen both by policy makers and the public as a “good thing” of benefit to all citizens. Charging at the door emphasises a changed relation between the public and the museum - from one of citizen to one of customer.' (National Museum of Australia, submission 42 p360)

6.36 This would explain why it is sometimes said anecdotally that if you are going to charge at all, you might as well make it $10 rather than $2. By implication, even at $2 some damage is done: the museum's image has changed, and it is trying to compete in a different market where there are more substitutes. This would account for the loss of visitors being relatively high at the change in price from nothing to something, and lower thereafter (see paragraph 5.69).

Are entry fees a wise response to any perceived inequity?

6.37 This brings us back to the question raised in paragraph 6.18: even if we accept that free entry is an unfair subsidy from nongoing taxpayers to goers (or in the stronger form, an unfair subsidy from poorer nongoers to better-off goers) - and the Committee does not necessarily accept this - it does not necessarily mean that entry fees are a wise response.

`It [Department of Finance, 1989] drew the conclusion that museums were institutions which were used, in the main, by only some members of the population, so that in effect public monies were subsidising the interests of the narrower rather than the broader community. While the research reported above supports this conclusion, its policy implications are far from clear.' [36]

6.38 What other results would entry fees cause? Could there be damaging side-effects? Could alternative approaches be more positive?

6.39 The answers to these questions depend crucially on what the elasticity of demand really is; how many visitors a charge drives away; accordingly, how great is the deadweight loss of welfare; to what extent the discouraged visitors are the poorer people who (at least in the case of museums and galleries) already labour under other cultural barriers to access.

...in national parks

6.40 In the case of national parks, the Committee's evidence was inconclusive. The safest statement is that the position probably varies greatly from one national park to another, depending on how strong the attractions of the particular site are, and how many substitutes there are. This suggests that pricing policies should be flexible: some national parks with rare attractions and inelastic demand (such as the Snowy Mountains, for snow) may support high entry fees, while a similar charge in a more `ordinary' national park (in terms of its attractions for public recreation) could drive many visitors away.

...in museums and art galleries

6.41 In the case of museums and galleries, according to the predominant evidence given to the Committee, demand in response to price changes may be quite elastic and accordingly the effects of entry fees may be very damaging on both efficiency and equity grounds.

6.42 Visitor numbers will probably drop significantly, causing a deadweight loss of welfare to the community as a whole (since the operating cost of the institution does not drop correspondingly). Visitors' socio-economic profile will probably become even more élitist, going against access and equity goals. Older people on fixed incomes will be particularly discouraged, which is especially regrettable because they particularly recognise the importance of active cultural participation for their quality of life (and this problem will increase with the current greying of the population). Families will be particularly discouraged, with very serious implications for losing the early positive museum experiences of the next generation of potential visitors. These last two points have particular significance in light of demographic changes:

`...art museums, like other cultural institutions, benefited from a demographic windfall during the 1960s and 1970s that will not be repeated. Individuals with almost all of the characteristics associated with museum attendance - relative youth, college educations, white-collar occupations - became far more numerous than they had been before. During the past decade real incomes and educational attainment have stopped growing, the baby-boom generation has reached middle age, and labour force growth has shifted to low-income service occupations... Art museums can no longer count on steadily increasing demand for their services.' [37]

6.43 In the longer term, the place may lose the sympathetic image as a community cultural facility which it needs in order to attract public subsidy, private sponsorship and volunteer input. [38]

`At the broader access and equity level, admission charges have the effect of excluding sections of the community from access to cultural and information services.' (Government of South Australia, submission 38 p319)

`Entry fees usually account for no more than about 10 per cent of the income of most publicly funded museums. The real cost of entry fees is the effective exclusion of two thirds of the visitors. To maintain entry fees makes a mockery of often much touted efforts to increase the inclusiveness of museums and to sweep away barriers to participation in their programs.' (P Filmer-Sankey, Newcastle Regional Museum, submission 56 p589)

6.44 This is not a sensible outcome. Where it has occurred the Committee suspects that it may result from pressures from government for greater cost recovery with too little regard for the negative side-effects. It is particularly inappropriate since, for all these detriments, fee revenue cannot usually hope to be more than a small percentage of total costs (as all submissions to the inquiry admitted); the museum will still require a large public subsidy; and because costs do not decrease in proportion to decreased visitation, the public subsidy for each remaining visitor will probably increase, frustrating the goal of reducing the `unfair' subsidy. [39]

6.45 All these detriments arise quite predictably because these institutions are primarily `public goods' which, according to orthodox economic theory, should be funded by general taxation. The policy push to shift the burden onto direct users, whatever its merits in principle, in this case is misguided. It damages the standing of the museum as a community cultural institution, and it leads to a loss of community welfare (through reduced visitation) which the Committee regards as regrettable. We stress again that, despite the confusing moral connotations of `public good', in economic theory a `public good' is simply something supplied collectively to counteract market failure - even though, depending on the case, the benefits of it may be completely private to individual recipients. Thus the fact that a `public good' conveys private benefits is not, by itself, a sound reason for imposing user charges.

6.46 Finally we comment on the argument that entry fees (to be exact, being forced to rely on entry fees for a certain proportion of income) will focus the minds of managers on `customer service'. [40] The implication may be either that user charges revenue will finance `customer-focussed' programs that will attract more visitors; or (if they don't attract more visitors) in any case quality matters more than quantity.

6.47 This of course raises the debate over exactly what `greater customer focus' means and whether it is a good or bad thing - whether it means making museums and galleries more relevant, or takes them away from their core functions of education and cultural enrichment as societal goals. The Committee will not buy into that argument here: we comment only that either way, the proof of the pudding is in the visitor numbers. To judge from the evidence quoted above, it seems that `customer focus' has not been able to prevent a serious loss of customers where entry fees are imposed. A museum cannot provide a quality experience to people who have turned away at the door.

Alternatives

6.48 What alternatives are possible? First and foremost, we may reject the formulation of the problem - that for some reason publicly funded institutions `ought' to achieve an arbitrary amount of cost recovery through user charges.

`...there is power in public goods - the museum is an excellent example, and the Treasury Gardens over the back here. The public love those things in a way that politicians do not understand until they try to shut them down. Also, for most of this century the idea of public goods was easily accepted by all sides of politics in that they are important... It is only in the last 15 years with this push towards economic efficiency that the whole issue of user pays has come up.' (F Grey, evidence 15 September 1997 p434)

6.49 The philosophical position that users should pay for private benefits, simply because they should (by analogy with private markets) is inappropriate. These places are public facilities which are maintained for public purposes to do with conservation, education and cultural enrichment. With them, as a matter of public policy, the goal of the widest possible public access is fundamental - they are not free (as private enterprise is) to pursue élite niche markets if that happens to be most profitable. Cost recovery policies must be secondary. If the total benefits in relation to given fixed costs are greatest when funded entirely through general taxation, then it makes most sense to fund them entirely through general taxation.

6.50 Secondly, if we perceive an upper class bias in the socio-economic profile of visitors, we may take constructive steps to remedy it - the foundation of which is free entry:

`The position adopted by the Department of Finance [1989] was to advocate the introduction of museum charges to reduce the level of public subsidisation to private benefits. An equally cogent response, however, is to urge the need for the public funding of compensatory programs intended - in a variety of ways - to make museums more accessible to a wider cross-section of the community.' [41]

6.51 Access and equity generally is a staple concern of museum professionals, and the Committee affirms its fundamental importance, though we will not consider it further in this report. We make only one comment. The argument that focuses on free entry as an `unfair' subsidy from poorer nongoing taxpayers to better-off goers makes an implicit value judgment that the most important differences between people are unequal resources of money income. But money income is not the only way we can describe welfare, and a dichotomy between rich and poor is not the only way we can categorise people's differences. The more important dichotomy (in context of this discussion of museums and galleries) is the dichotomy between people with and without the `cultural capital' (basically, education) that makes them feel comfortable visiting museums. If we focus on this dichotomy, it is obvious that exacting fees from better-off goers does nothing to remedy the unequal distribution of cultural capital. Constructive access and equity programs might. [42]

6.52 Thirdly, if we wish to reduce the level of public subsidy per visitor, we may search for means of doing so which do not jeopardise the core goal of wide public access. Given the predominance of fixed costs in museums and galleries, the most obvious way of reducing the subsidy per visitor is to increase visitation:

`When we had an entry fee, we took almost exactly $2.00 per head from an ordinary annual visitation of 50,000. Now we are taking $0.61c from each visitor via the shop, cafe, donation boxes and other income sources, but we are earning this from nearly four time as many people. Our cost per visitor has fallen from between $12 and $17 a head to an estimated $3.50 for this year.' (P Filmer-Sankey, Newcastle Regional Museum, submission 56 p589) [43]

6.53 Another obvious way is to exploit increased visitation by charging for `value-added' services, which the Committee (with most submissions, even from those opposed to entry fees) accepts; and to exploit the favourable public image of a free-entry community cultural institution to promote volunteer input and private sponsorship.

`...the [Western Australian] Museum feels that implementing a general admission charge could seriously limit other avenues of funding.... the Museum recognises that entrepreneurial activities can and do generate an increasing percentage of museum budgets. However, in applying any model of “user pays”, the Museum believes that the long term cultural investment represented by museums should not be endangered. In this respect, the modified model of a mix of free and pay-to-enter spaces is preferred...' (Government of Western Australia, submission 53 p464)

`The philosophy is about getting the community into the gallery and then looking at different ways of generating revenue other than a straight entry fee.' (R Sue See, Queensland Art Gallery, evidence 21 May 1997 p122)

`Consequently [the Australia] Council would argue for a sophisticated approach to considering the constellation of uses and users of assets and a creative and innovative approach to developing and exploiting a wide suite of income sources...The starting point for this approach should be base admission without charge. The opportunity of Australians young, old in city and country to learn and delight in our rich cultural and heritage resources should be limited at the gateway to these assets.' (Australia Council, submission 35 p289)

6.54 `Basic access' and `value-added services' are discussed further from paragraph 7.3, and volunteerism and sponsorship from paragraph 7.81.

 

Footnotes

[1] One can also argue that direct users `ought' to contribute more without any reference to rich or poor, but simply from a general `user pays' philosophy. This may be called equity between users and non-users: it is the implicit foundation of the `users should pay for private benefits' argument. The argument is intrinsically weak in relation to non-rival public goods, because of the marginal cost pricing rule (see paragraph 5.18), so it is usually put with the rich/poor equity angle to buttress it.

[2] Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p81. Bennett T & Frow J, Art Galleries: Who Goes?:a study of visitors to three Australian art galleries, with international comparisons, Australia Council 1991, p53.

[3] Professor Bennett comments that little is known about the extent to which such programs are successful - that is, whether the profile of museum visitors is becoming more `average' over time, as hoped: `The attempts of my co-researcher, Robin Trotter, in a recent inquiry to ascertain how many Australian museums had regular mechanisms for statistically measuring the success of their access policies in terms of altered visitor profiles drew pretty much of a blank.' Bennett T, `Consuming culture, measuring access and audience development', Culture and Policy vol 8 no. 1, 1997, p17 (attachment to submission 8)

[4] Bennett T, `That those who run may read: museums and barriers to access', Evaluation and Visitor Research in Museums Towards 2000, conference papers, Powerhouse Museum, March 1995, p12. Bourdieu P & Darbel A, The Love of Art: European art museums and their public, Cambridge, Polity Press, 1991 (first published in French 1969)

[5] `When this class [the `dominant class'] is broken down into its components, however, marked differences between its `intellectual' and its managerial/industrial wings become apparent...In some key measures of cultural capital... the group of secondary and tertiary teachers scores many hundreds of per cent more than the groups of employers.' Bennett T & Frow J, Art Galleries: Who Goes?:a study of visitors to three Australian art galleries, with international comparisons, Australia Council 1991, p54; see also p52.

[6] Bennett T, The Reluctant Museum Visitor: a study of non-goers to history museums and art galleries, Australia Council 1994, p11

[7] Spring J, Culture on Holiday: a survey of Australian domestic tourists' cultural participation December 1990 - April 1991, Australia Council, no date [1991], pp17,21. A tourist is defined as a person spending at least one night away from home at a minimum distance of 40km.

[8] Robertson H & Migliorino P, Open Up - guidelines for cultural diversity visitor studies, Australia Council 1996, p34

[9] Prof. T Bennett, evidence 21 May 1997 p80

[10] The distinction is important. Frequent visitors will count more strongly in statistics about visitation than in statistics about the whole population's propensity to visit. This is relevant, for example, to the argument that free entry is an `unfair' subsidy to a small élite of frequent visitors. A small élite of frequent visitors may exist, and yet the institution's main use may still be in the form of occasional visits by the mass of people. Free entry for the masses gives a windfall gain to the élite because of the practical impossibility of discriminatory pricing.

[11] Hood M G, `Audience research tells us why visitors come to museums - and why they don't come', Evaluation and Visitor Research in Museums Towards 2000, conference papers, Powerhouse Museum, March 1995, p3ff

[12] An alternative formulation is: `The first audience is the committed museum visitor... Then we have the visitor who can be kicked across the portals with encouragement but could also go to sporting events... There is a third group of visitors who, if they knew a bit more about it, would come...' Dr S Wallace (Museums Australia), evidence 16 September 1997 p488. The second and third group described thus are probably both part of Hood's middle group. Bennett and Frow describe six groups of art gallery goers and four (three) groups of museum (gallery) nongoers. Mapping these onto Hood's categories is a point of interest. Bennett T & Frow J, Art Galleries: Who Goes?:a study of visitors to three Australian art galleries, with international comparisons, Australia Council 1991; Bennett T, The Reluctant Museum Visitor: a study of non-goers to history museums and art galleries, Australia Council 1994.

[13] For example, visits to Victorian national parks and other parks have grown from 3.4 million per year to 10.2 million per year from 1977 to 1993. Hall C M & McArthur S, Heritage Management in Australia and New Zealand: the human dimension, OUP, Melbourne 1996, p133

[14] The question requires a breakdown of individual national park visitation figures correlated to the characteristics of individual national parks.

[15] The hypothesis that poorer people are excluded from visiting Uluru by travel costs has the logical complement that poorer people are not so much excluded from visiting less distant places.

[16] Bennett T, The Reluctant Museum Visitor: a study of non-goers to history museums and art galleries, Australia Council 1994, p37. Australian Bureau of Statistics data on cultural expenditure broken down by household income do not particularly corroborate this, but the actual figures for `national park and zoo fees' are so small as to be statistically unreliable. As well, of course, expenditure on `national park fees' does not account for visits to places where entry is free. Department of Communications and the Arts & Australian Bureau of Statistics, Cultural Trends in Australia No. 4 - Australians' expenditure on culture, 1996, p43

[17] Spring J, Culture on Holiday: a survey of Australian domestic tourists' cultural participation December 1990 - April 1991, Australia Council, no date [1991], pp17,21.

[18] Arguably this is a sufficient answer to the claim that `users should pay for private benefits' as a matter of equity between users and non-users. That is, equity between users and non-users, as a general principle, is simply not on the agenda in a society which taxes and spends communally, since any taxing and spending must create such `inequities'.`Users should pay for private benefits' relies on an implicit judgment that in the particular case ethical considerations or community benefits are not strong enough to make the community want to subsidise associated private benefits.

[19] The rich/poor dichotomy is the main one and was the only one raised in submissions to this inquiry, but other dichotomies may raise equity problems depending on one's point of view. For example, we hear arguments over whether it is `fair' for some States to subsidise other States through differential Commonwealth general revenue grants; whether it is `fair' for country people to subsidise city people's public services (or vice versa); and so on.

[20] See paragraph 4.35, footnote 16.

[21] Merit goods are conceptually distinct from public goods, though they may overlap in practice. Public goods, however great the demand for them, are undersupplied in private markets because of non-rivalry or non-excludability. Merit goods are undersupplied in private markets because (in society's view) individuals' private demand is deficient: some people don't know their own best interests. The two categories are easily confused or may overlap in practice since  deficient demand for a public good because of free-rider problems may have the same appearance as deficient demand for a merit good because of imperfect knowledge;  individuals may not see external benefits arising from their consumption of a public good.

[22] `...it is surely untenable that the rich should have more of the stock of public goods than the poor, yet this is exactly the priority in resource allocation that Willingness To Pay [theory] would assume.' Hamilton-Smith E, `Challenging the Willingness To Pay model,' Valuing Natural Areas: applications and problems of the contingent valuation method, ed. Lockwood M & De Lacy T, conference papers Charles Sturt University June 1992, p150

[23] See also Prof. T Bennett, evidence 21 May 1997 p83

[24] Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p83-4. Most statistics, though they may misleadingly refer to `visitors', are actually counts of `visits' - that is, turns of the turnstile. To discover the incidence of repeat visits requires surveying visitors to ask when they last visited.

[25] Bennett T & Frow J, Art Galleries: Who Goes - a study of visitors to three Australian art galleries, with international comparisons, Australia Council 1991, p28, appendix 2 table 13. T Bennett's 1994 study of non-visitors to museums and art galleries did not ask a comparable question: Bennett T, The Reluctant Museum Visitor: a study of non-goers to history museums and art galleries, Australia Council 1994

[26] A focus group participant quoted in Australian Pensioners and Superannuants Federation, Older Australians and the Arts, Australia Council 1995, p41

[27] Robertson H & Migliorino P, Open Up - guidelines for cultural diversity visitor studies, Australia Council 1996, p35; pers. comm. G Miltenyi (EMD Workforce Development)

[28] Australian Museum, submisssion 30 p241

[29] Robertson H & Migliorino P, Open Up - guidelines for cultural diversity visitor studies, Australia Council 1996, p35. The comment is made in respect of non-English-speakers and Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islanders.

[30] National Campaign for the Arts Australia Ltd, submission 37 p315. Bennett T, The Reluctant Museum Visitor: a study of non-goers to history museums and art galleries, Australia Council 1994. Art Gallery of Ontario, Royal Ontario Museum, Ontario Science Centre, Metropolitan Toronto Zoo, Audience Research Consortium - summary report, September 1993.

[31] `It seems clear that the removal of the admission charge has broadened the appeal of the National Gallery [of Victoria] beyond the traditional gallery-going groups, and has encouraged increased attendance from those who were previously infrequent or non-visitors.' Stewart-Hunter D, National Gallery of Victoria: omnibus poll and visitor study: summary report, 1997, p6

[32] If matches go up from $1 to $2, it is unlikely to change people's buying habits - demand for that good is inelastic at that price. If cars go up from $20,000 to $40,000, it is very likely to change people's buying habits.

[33] For example, The Friends of South Australia's Archives, submission 10 p98

[34] In other words, in terms of the categorisation in paragraph 4.37, the variable community benefits associated with people's use would be regarded as less in the case of national parks.

[35] The suggestion is made in respect of national parks in paragraph 5.13.

[36] Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p86. Department of Finance, What Price Heritage: the museums review and the measurement of museum performance, Canberra 1989

[37] DiMaggio P J in Feldstein M ed., The Economics of Art Museums, University of Chicago Press 1991, p49. The comment is about the USA but there is no reason to think Australia is significantly different.

[38] Sponsorship and volunteer input are discussed from paragraph 7.81.

[39] The last point depends critically on the exact balance between cost recovery and lost visitors. A fee aiming to recoup 10 per cent of costs (based on initial free-entry visitor numbers), if it drives away more than 10 per cent of visitors, or a fee aiming to recoup 20 per cent of costs, if it drives away more than 17 per cent of visitors, increases the subsidy for each remaining visitor (assuming costs are constant). A fee is most counterproductive where even a small proportion of cost recovery quickly strikes the limits of people's willingness to pay. See the case study from paragraph 5.32.

[40] Australian Museum, submission 30 p240

[41] Australian Key Centre for Cultural and Media Policy, submission 8 p86. Department of Finance, What Price Heritage: the museums review and the measurement of museum performance, Canberra 1989

[42] If `possesssion of cultural capital' is regarded as a fundamental good, the broader education system is also implicated. `There are real limitations on the kinds of inroads, if you like, that museums and art galleries can make in access terms so long as an education system operates in a way that, whether unintentionally or by design, stratifies the population culturally... What art galleries and museums can do so far as opening up access to their own resources is very much dependent upon the policies that are pursued in the education domain.' Prof T Bennett, evidence 21 May 1997 p77

[43] Comparisons of subsidy per visitor between different institutions are not useful, because of their different circumstances (such as big or small collections or research activities). Comparisons within the same place over time, other costs unchanged, are relevant, pace G Morris (evidence 15 September 1997 p416).