Chapter 3
The price of milk
Retail prices
3.1
The Australian grocery market is dominated by the two major supermarket
chains, Coles and Woolworths. They have a combined market share in the total
grocery market variously estimated at 55–80 per cent.[1]
Their market share for drinking milk is somewhat lower, perhaps 50 per cent,
reflecting the large numbers of milk bars and convenience stores which also
sell milk.[2]
However the major chains still dominate the retail pricing of milk, as their
'deep pockets' would deter small local stores from starting a 'price war' for
milk.
3.2
The major supermarket chains sell milk in two formats: 'generic' milk
(also variously known as 'home brand', 'store brand' or 'private label'[3])
which usually carries the name of the supermarket selling it and 'branded' milk
which usually carries the name of the processor.[4]
Taking the common two–litre container of standard full cream milk in a major
suburban supermarket,[5]
a typical price is around $1.75 per litre for a branded product and
$1.25 per litre for a generic. Just over half of the milk sold in
Australia is now generic (Table 3.4 below).
3.3
The labels on branded milk (and other branded products) tend to be more
colourful and there is pervasive advertising, designed to create the impression
that the branded milk is a superior product. Under questioning by the Committee,
the processors and retailers, somewhat reluctantly, conceded that the branded
and generic (full cream) milk were in substance the same product:
Senator MILNE—... Is there any difference between a litre of
full-cream milk that is branded and a litre of full-cream milk that is a home
brand?
Mr Brennen—No. The national health standard...sets the standard
and you cannot adulterate white, liquid, fresh milk. You can take a bit of the
cream out and standardise it. You cannot put protein in—it is illegal and it
will not be done anywhere in Australia.[6]
Senator COLBECK—... the stock standard Pura milk in the blue
carton, versus the generic Woolworths brand or the generic Coles brand. What is
the difference in the products?
Mr O’Malley—To the best of my knowledge they are broadly the
same.[7]
Senator MILNE—... Is there any difference in a generic brand, a
house brand product in the fresh milk market in the same category? Let’s say we
are talking about full-cream milk. Have we got exactly the same product in the
packet, whether it is branded or non-branded?
Mr Mara—...They may have some minor specification differences...
Senator MILNE—So as far as you are concerned the home brand
product and the branded product are exactly the same and if there are additives
added or anything changed, that is not something you know about or have
specifications for?
Mr Mara—We may have specifications. I am not the buyer of the
milk, but if there are different specifications that we have, we are happy to
share them with you.[8]
3.4
The perception of a difference between generic and branded milk,
however, allows the retailers to engage in price discrimination. The market is
segmented into the more price-conscious/ lower income/ better informed
consumers who buy the generic product and the less price‑sensitive/higher
income/ status conscious consumers who buy the branded product. The latter are
then charged a higher price for their milk.
3.5
Prior to the repeal of section 49 of the Trade Practices Act 1974,
corporations were prohibited from discriminating between buyers of goods of
like grade and quality in relation to the price of those goods if that
discrimination was of such a degree or a recurring or systemic nature that it
would have the effect or be likely to have the effect of substantially
lessening competition in the market.[9]
Section 49 was repealed in 1995; the view at the time being that price
discrimination would still be able to be regulated under other provisions of
the Trade Practices Act 1974 for example, sections 45 and 46 of Part IV.[10]
(The issue of price discrimination is covered in more depth in Chapter 4.)
3.6
It was suggested to the Committee that the differential between the
branded price and generic price (ie the extent of price discrimination) is
higher for milk than for other products:
That 33 per cent difference does not occur in any other
generic product...[11]
...of all the home brands of products which are shelved in the
supermarket, milk appears to be the one with the highest margin.[12]
3.7
Table 3.1 shows the differences between branded and generic versions of
a range of products. In many cases there are now two generic versions. From
this admittedly small sample, the price differences between the generic and
branded product do not seem larger for milk than for other products (although
there may be larger quality differences between generic and branded products
for other goods).
Table 3.1: Generic
price as per cent of branded product price
Major supermarket chain,
Canberra, 6-12 March 2010
Milk |
57-67 |
|
Toilet paper |
54-72 |
Butter |
52-80 |
|
Pasta |
26-73 |
Yoghurt |
76-92 |
|
Corn flakes |
57-86 |
Cheese (cheddar) |
61-86 |
|
Weetbix |
42-83 |
Bread |
28-69 |
|
Tuna |
30-92 |
Sugar |
45-75 |
|
Tomatoes (diced) |
41-65 |
Flour |
37-84 |
|
Beetroot (sliced) |
43-66 |
Juice (fresh) |
28-47 |
|
Baked beans |
43-70 |
Juice |
54-70 |
|
Soda water |
53 |
Source: Secretariat.
The demand for milk
3.8
The total demand for milk is quite stable and predictable. The demand
for milk at an individual store or chain may be more elastic to the extent that
customers are able or willing to shop around. While milk is only one of a large
number of products sold by supermarkets, it is a staple product that most
customers buy. Supermarkets then need to think about whether high milk prices
may deter customers from shopping at the store and thereby lower overall sales.
3.9
A UK study found that, once in a given store, the own–price elasticity
of milk is -0.6. (By comparison, the demand for other goods is around -1,
suggesting milk has a relatively inelastic demand.) As milk constitutes around
5 per cent of the value of the average British supermarket shopper's basket or
trolley, the effect of milk prices on the choice of store is not large, but
including this effect raises the total elasticity to -0.8.[13]
Competition
3.10
As well as the elasticity of customer demand, the retail price will
depend on whether there is any collusion between supermarkets. A UK study
concluded that supermarket prices for milk there were consistent with what
estimated elasticities would imply would occur in a competitive market.[14]
This may not necessarily translate into the Australian environment as the UK
has many supermarket chains with a significant market share whereas Australia
has essentially only two. As noted in Table 3. 6 below, retail prices for
branded milk are higher in Australia than in the UK.
Variations in retail prices
3.11
Retail milk prices differ across states, as discussed further below
(Tables 3.8 and 3.9). Prices also vary to a lesser extent across outlets within
cities (Table 3.2), and differ between different sizes of milk cartons (Table 3.3)
and across varieties of milk (Table 3.4).
Table 3.2: Retail
milk prices across Canberra
(cents per litre for
'Canberra milk', 2 litre; 10 October 2009)
One major supermarket
chain |
|
|
Other major supermarket
chain |
|
|
Independent stores |
|
Gungahlin |
184 |
|
Gungahlin |
187 |
|
Civic |
189 |
Manuka |
184 |
|
Dickson |
187 |
|
Kingston |
185 |
Jamison |
184 |
|
Kippax |
187 |
|
Florey |
197 |
Belconnen |
184 |
|
Belconnen |
187 |
|
|
|
Curtin |
184 |
|
Kambah |
187 |
|
|
|
Source: survey by Secretariat
3.12
The variation across outlets within a city has diminished as the major
chains have responded to pressure to reduce geographic price discrimination.[15]
3.13
Milk (like most products) is cheaper when bought in larger quantities.
This is at least partly a reflection of cost differences: the packaging and
handling costs per litre are higher for smaller containers. Whether the cost
differences are as large as the price differences is open to question. It may
be the case that this is another form of price discrimination.
Table 3.3: Retail full
cream milk prices by quantity
(a major supermarket
in Canberra, 26 January 2010, cents per litre)
|
Branded milk |
Generic |
300 ml |
320 |
|
600 ml |
222 |
|
1 litre |
197 |
137 |
2 litres |
184 |
124 |
3 litres |
176 |
122 |
Source: Secretariat
3.14
Similarly, higher prices are charged for milk with various additives
such as omega 3, calcium and flavouring, or with less fat (Table 3.4). It is
questionable whether the cost of additives such as flavouring is anywhere near as
much as the difference in price. This may again be a matter of using the
additives to sort consumers into those who are price–responsive and charged a
lower price and those who are less price–sensitive and are charged a higher
price.
Table 3.4: Retail
milk prices by type, 2008-09
|
Branded milk |
Generic milk |
|
Price (cpl) |
(% of market) |
Price (cpl) |
(% of market) |
Regular whole |
186 |
(14) |
118 |
(32) |
Reduced fat |
210 |
(16) |
135 |
(15) |
No/low fat |
214 |
(5) |
164 |
(0) |
Flavoured |
371 |
(6) |
212 |
(0) |
UHT |
190 |
(8) |
119 |
(4) |
Source: Dairy Australia, Australian
Dairy Industry in Focus 2009, p. 43.
Milk as a 'loss leader'
3.15
Some witnesses claim milk is used as a 'loss leader'; sold under cost to
attract customers into stores:
We also see widespread smaller retailers using the two litre
milk as a discount leader to try to get more people through their stores. Milk
being the product that it is, basically purchased every day in every household,
is an attraction for a retailer or a major fruit shop to put a big sign out the
front, saying, ‘Cheap milk: come and get the cheap milk.’ That milk is
sometimes sold under cost price to that outlet. It is sold to the outlet and
the outlet will sell it under cost price.[16]
The other thing certain stores do is to look at a product
like milk as a way of building traffic, so once you are in the store you buy
other things which are at a higher margin.[17]
...I got some prices today from one of the major retail outlets
in Brisbane, and one has just announced a price reduction on the weekend for a
two-litre bottle of whole milk down to $2.09 for their private brand and the
advertising was structured in a way that you could possibly term it as a loss
leader strategy in terms of marketing as a reduction to get people through the
front door of the supermarket.[18]
3.16
In Western Australia milk is sometimes sold at less than a dollar per
litre.[19]
3.17
The major supermarkets denied using milk as a 'loss leader':
Senator MILNE—...Can you tell me: do you ever use milk as a
loss leader to attract customers to Coles?
Mr Mara—Not to my knowledge.[20]
Senator O’BRIEN—Does Woolworths use milk as a loss leader?
Mr Dunn—No, not at all.[21]
3.18
They do, however, claim that others engage in the practice:
Packaged milk products are now used in many segments of the
non‑supermarket retail as a loss leader – to attract customers to make
other store purchases.[22]
Wholesale prices
3.19
The supermarket chains buy milk from the processors. The prices paid by
the supermarkets, and consequently the profits earned by the processors, are
quite different for branded and generic milk but, as noted below, both
processors and retailers were reluctant to provide much information about the
difference.
3.20
Supermarkets typically have tenders to determine from which processors
they will buy the generic milk. The contracts typically run for two to three
years.[23]
The large supermarket chains generally prefer a single processor for each state
or region, or perhaps even a single national supplier.[24]
Combined with there only being two major supermarket chains, this preference
encourages consolidation within the processing sector as only large processors
can credibly bid for the contracts and without any such contract half the
drinking milk market is effectively closed to a processor.
3.21
It may be the case that small processors would lack the economies of
scale to put in competitive tenders to supply even some of the generic milk for
supermarkets in a region. In addition, the scale of the contracts make it very difficult
for some smaller processors to participate.
3.22
The highest price processors can secure is limited by the supermarkets'
ability to source milk from the next closest source of supply.[25]
The lowest price the supermarkets can extract is the marginal cost of producing
milk. Where the price settles between these limits will depend on the relative
bargaining power of the processors and the supermarkets.
3.23
The outcome of the tendering process is that the wholesale price for
generic milk may be 20-40 per cent lower than for branded milk, and processors
are less able to pass on cost increases to the supermarkets for generic milk
than for branded milk.[26]
3.24
Processors prefer to concentrate on making their own branded products,
on which they earn much higher profits, and would not bid for a generic
contract if it meant reducing production of the branded product.[27]
As the retail markets increasingly move towards sales of generic milk, however,
they may not be able to sell their whole production run as branded product and
the generic milk contracts will become ever more important to them.
3.25
A UK study looked at the market for generic milk and concluded the large
supermarkets have substantial buying power due to the existence of substantial
economies of scale.[28]
The presence of large powerful supermarkets encourages processors to install
technology with increasing returns to scale, in turn making smaller
supermarkets less attractive customers for the processors.
Slotting charges
3.26
It is advantageous for the processors to have their branded milk
prominently displayed at eye-level on supermarket shelves. This may be achieved
by the processors paying an explicit 'slotting' fee to the supermarkets for
favourable product placement:
The ACCC in their grocery inquiry recognised that the chains
charged slotting fees—that is, if you want to slot your product on their shelf,
you pay them.[29]
If you are selling you own product that is a different story
because, there, you are placing your product on the shelf and you would do your
normal negotiations with the buyer. In those negotiations you would have your
pricing and there would be a little bit of negotiation on promotions, ullage,
shelf space and all the other things that go along.[30]
...joining the retail business and seeing how supermarkets
operate, is that if you really want to sell your product you have to promote it
heavily and pay massive promotions back to them...[31]
3.27
Woolworths denied such explicit fees existed:
The suggestion, for instance, that there are slotting fees in
the marketplace: as far as Woolworths is concerned, that was specifically
stated not to be the case to the ACCC...[32]
3.28
Alternatively, the same effect could be achieved implicitly by processors
being granted more favourable placement on the shelves in return for offering
their branded milk at a lower price to the supermarkets.
3.29
More controversially, favourable placement on supermarket shelves for
branded milk may be conditional on providing generic milk to the supermarkets
at a low price. If this occurs, it would represent an exercise (arguably an
abuse) of the market power of the major supermarkets.
'Waterbedding' effect
3.30
It has been suggested that the market power of the major supermarket
chains means that they can force down the price they pay processors for generic
milk, and that this leads to the processor charging a higher price on its other
sales: generic milk to other retailers, branded milk and other products such as
yoghurt.
3.31
This is termed the 'waterbedding effect':
The 'waterbed effect' is the term used to describe the result
when a large player in a market demands lower wholesale prices from suppliers,
forcing those suppliers to increase prices to other customers to bring earnings
back to a sustainable level. The large body in the middle of the waterbed
forces up smaller bodies on the sides.[33]
3.32
It has been described as follows:
A typical explanation for this is a cost shifting narrative. This
explanation relies on suppliers incurring certain fixed costs. If the suppliers
recover fewer of these fixed costs from the large buyer (which forced their
input price down by bargaining power) or none of them if the powerful buyer
negotiates to pay marginal costs, according to the argument the suppliers must
recover more of these fixed costs from other buyers. It is argued that the
suppliers must shift more or all of their fixed costs onto smaller/weaker
buyers, thereby increasing the total price paid by those weaker buyers.[34]
3.33
The ACCC, however, argue there is a logical flaw in the waterbedding
argument:
A common objection is that this sort of cost-shifting
violates standard axioms of profit maximisation – if the supplier is able to
charge higher prices of the smaller retailers after the decrease in price
charged of the powerful buyer, why didn't they do so before?[35]
3.34
The ACCC also point out:
Further, even if a waterbed type effect exists and results in
weaker retailers paying higher input prices, it is far from clear from the
economic modelling what the impact will be on downstream prices. This...will
depend partly on the state of competition in the downstream retail sector.[36]
3.35
Independent retailers, however, told the Committee they believed this
effect operated:
...the waterbedding effect in the dairy industry...has worked in
two ways: I pay more than the contract price for house brand milk to Fonterra
and to National Foods. They have to charge me more so that they can, at the end
of the day, make money. I am, in effect, subsidising the supply of house brand
milk to those people [major supermarket chains]... I believe we are [also] seeing
this waterbed effect in other dairy products.[37]
The track record of private label milk is that its price
growth has been less than inflation. The track record of branded milk price is
that it is higher than inflation...The waterbed effect is demonstrated by that
graph. But, as Mr Cummings said, it is also demonstrated by the fact that the
price of other dairy products—the yoghurts and cheese and so on—have also gone
up.[38]
3.36
Some independent witnesses' study of the dairy industry led them to the
same conclusion:
...the removal of the Price Discrimination provisions of the
Trade Practices Act... enabled the major supermarket chains to force their milk
suppliers to supply their home brand milk at a considerably lower cost than for
branded milk, which...seems to result in a “waterbed effect” and growing price
differential between branded and generic products.[39]
Clearly, there is a level of return that a milk processor
requires and, therefore, the lower the prices paid by Coles and Woolworths for
generic milk, the higher the prices that milk processor will charge smaller
retailers for branded milk to make up for the lower returns or shortfall from
Coles and Woolworths.[40]
3.37
Despite the ACCC refuting the occurrence of waterbedding, both Fonterra
and National Foods gave evidence that suggests it is a reality in the dairy
industry:
Senator COLBECK—...Is there a balancing act, if you like, that
has to be conducted with respect to returns that you are going to get on the
house‑branded produced versus your brands?
Mr Mallinson—Ultimately, we will value the import price of
the milk going in and what we get on a global quantity basis. So it would have
to be a value over and above a global commodity sale. When we look at house
brand contracts, we will look at our factory capacity—in particular, with
cheese and butter—and whether we can actually produce that sort of volume.
Senator COLBECK—So it almost can be done on a marginal price
rather than a base price?
Mr Mallinson—Yes.
Senator COLBECK—...I am just trying to get a sense of those
processes...the power to draw through and the cost to the overall business of
drawing through on that marginal cost of production and who actually ends up
paying that price. It has an impact across the entire business, doesn’t it?
Mr Mallinson—Yes.
Senator COLBECK—If you are getting a flat rate of margin
across all products—and I know that it is going to vary depending on the
product margin—and you are putting one particular chunk through at a marginal
rate, that has to be made up in other areas.
Mr Mallinson—Without giving too much away, we will never do a
house brand where we have only enough capacity to do our own brands.
...
Mr Mallinson—It will
always be secondary or subservient.[41]
Senator COLBECK—...a fair proportion of your product must be
going through into those generic brands because it is a large chunk of what the
supermarkets are selling. So that premium obviously impacts across the rest of
the business and it has to be recouped in some way...how that is amortised
across the business and what the cost of that is to the other product. We heard
evidence before—and I know you are in a slightly different situation—that a
decision was made not to sell a generic product in a circumstance where they
had a quality brand product. You are in a very different situation because you
are trying to do both.
Mr Evans—I think, again, as Mr O’Malley has suggested, there
is a portfolio of brands that we make available to retailers and obviously some
will be more profitable than others, but obviously to give detail on that is
obviously highly sensitive.[42]
3.38
It is also noted that in responding to questions on notice at Estimates on
'waterbedding', the ACCC provided conflicting opinion when the organisation replied:
During the course of the ACCC's 2008 Grocery Inquiry, the
ACCC received mixed evidence of the extent to which processors increased the
price of branded products to offset cost increases associated with providing
private label products. Some processors indicated that they did not engage in
this practice. However, others indicated that increased costs for branded
products have been able to be recovered in a 'more timely manner' and that
prices of branded products have sometimes been increased to offset overall cost
increases, both for branded and private label products.[43]
Price discrimination
3.39
It is argued that it is unfair, and potentially detrimental to
consumers, that processors sell at lower prices to the major supermarket chains
than to other retailers (or to vendors who on–sell the milk to small retailers):
Clearly, there is a very real danger that price
discrimination in the market for milk is deterring or preventing competitive
conduct within that market in a way that is substantially detrimental to
consumers. In short, price discrimination can be anti-competitive in that a
smaller retailer is simply unable to compete as aggressively as possible in the
market because of the price discrimination it faces. Consequently, consumers
are denied the benefits of vigorous competition between large and small
retailers. Needless to say, if smaller retailers are unable to be competitive
because of higher milk prices they pay in comparison to Coles and Woolworths,
there is a further and very real danger that the smaller retailers will go out
of business, thereby further reducing competition.[44]
3.40
The Committee also received evidence from a Dairy Farmers' (affiliated
with National Foods) franchisee outlining that their franchisor:
-
forces us to sell milk cheaper than we buy it for;
-
forces us to breach the Trade Practices Act – as franchisees we collude
in regards to pricing for dairy farmers negotiated rebate customers;
-
uses us to prop up their losses in other parts of their business; and
-
competes against us (Coles, Woolies and Foodservice) and offers better
terms, product range and pricing.[45]
3.41
NARGA also reflected that competition may be improved by the restoration
of prohibitions on price discrimination in the Trade Practices Act 1974.[46]
This is discussed further in Chapter 4.
3.42
Looking ahead, some witnesses feared that generics could ultimately
displace branded milk from supermarket shelves as the price difference between
them widens:
So there is quite a significant price differential and that
differential now, with this latest marketing strategy by the major retailers,
is actually increasing. So that is a real concern for us, because at the end of
the day, as that major supermarket chain share increases and more milk goes
into the private label volume away from proprietary brands, it means that there
is less return back down the value chain to the processor and thus back down
the value chain to the farm gate. That situation is an extreme concern for us
and we question whether it is sustainable long term. If you were to ultimately
follow that sort of branding strategy through to where potentially proprietary
brands were not viable any more, the consumer actually could be faced with the
situation of having a reduced choice and one could also ask the question about
what would happen to the actual pricing to the consumer if there were not a
choice and it was only a choice between a number of supermarket brands on the
shelf. We do not know the answer to that, but it is certainly a question we
would like to see the ACCC investigate more.[47]
Committee view
3.43
The Committee, in its deliberations, noted with concern the apparent
discriminatory practices that are occurring in the sale of generic and branded
milk in Australia's supermarkets. The Committee is of the view that the long
term viability of the domestic dairy industry may be in jeopardy if steps are
not taken to curb these practices, although it recognises the complexities
associated with government intervention in the market.
Recommendation 1
3.44
The Committee recommends that the Government requests that the National
Competition Tribunal reviews the effectiveness of section 46 of the Trade
Practices Act in preventing price discrimination and consider reinstating anti‑price
discrimination provisions, particularly to protect those parties participating
in industries dominated by multinational corporations.
Farmgate prices
3.45
Processors buy their milk from the farmers. In some cases the prices are
negotiated with individual farmers and in some cases with collective bargaining
groups. Years ago, many of the processors were cooperatives owned by farmers
which would just be aiming to cover the processing costs. Murray Goulburn
remains a cooperative, but most of the processors are now foreign-owned
companies seeking to maximise their profits.
3.46
For ease of comparison with retail prices, milk prices in this chapter
are quoted in cents per litre. As a rule of thumb, a farmgate price of 50 cents
a litre is equivalent to a price of around $6.75 per kilogram of milk solids.[48]
3.47
In the short run the marginal cost of milk is almost zero in the sense
that a farmer's costs do not drop if his milk is not sold as he cannot 'turn
off' the cows. Thus in the short term the market power is all with the processors.
3.48
In the medium term, the market power of the milk processors over the
farmers is limited by the farmers not only selling milk to the drinking milk processors.
In addition to these sales of what is often termed 'market milk', farmers sell
a significant proportion of their milk as 'manufacturing milk', used in the
production of cheeses, milk powders, butter and dairy spreads, primarily for
export. The proportions differ across the country, as those areas better suited
to dairying (mostly in the southern states) will tend to produce more milk than
needed for local drinking milk.
3.49
In the former, heavily regulated, market it was possible for the prices
for market and manufacturing milk to be quite disconnected, with the former
reacting to domestic conditions and government preferences and the latter to
global commodity prices. In the current deregulated market, the prices should
be much closer, although there will be a premium paid by the drinking milk
processors to ensure that they receive a steady supply of milk throughout the
year.
3.50
While deregulated, the market for milk is far from perfectly competitive
due to the limited (and diminishing) number of processors (as discussed further
in Chapter 4).
3.51
The Committee heard claims that the farmgate price is set in global
markets and has little to do with domestic conditions:
About half of Australia’s milk production is exported and, as
a result, the Australian farmgate price for milk is directly set off the world
market price.[49]
The decline in farm–gate prices in Australia reflects lower
international dairy prices in the wake of the global financial crisis, and the
reintroduction of export refunds by the European Union in January 2009.[50]
The pricing structure in Australia domestically is as much
driven by international factors.[51]
The price is set as an international commodity price...[52]
Milk prices in Tasmania are linked to the international
market, despite the fact that the majority of milk products are sold
nationally.[53]
If you look at what is driving it [the Tasmanian farmgate
price], which is what the international commodity prices have done in the last
two months...they pretty well correlate... It is not driven off what happens in
Tasmania; it is driven off what happens in Victoria. Victoria is two–thirds of
the national milk production where most of the milk goes into export markets,
driven off international prices, and that just flows through.[54]
...since deregulation, as you would have expected, prices
received by dairy farmers are more closely aligned with what is happening in
international markets.[55]
...the Australian dairy industry is integrated into the global
market. The main influence on the manufacturing milk price that companies like
Fonterra can offer farmers is the global price of commodities set in US dollars.[56]
3.52
This is hard to reconcile with the differences in farmgate prices across
the country (Table 3.7). It was also vehemently rejected by some witnesses and
treated sceptically by others:
...it is an absolute anachronism that you expect returns at
farmgate in Australia to be benchmarked to the vagaries of the international
pricing. This is ridiculous.[57]
...it is not a global milk commodity price. It is a localised
regional price that obviously is largely driven not by international price
demands but by regional price changes and supply and demand in the region.[58]
Mr Tennant—...The company are referencing export prices as a
basis for setting the prices that they actually pay us. I understand that
[although] in Fonterra’s case somewhere between 60 and 65 per cent of their
production actually goes into the domestic market....The price is always quoted
on the basis of the export market price.
Senator O’BRIEN—I can tell you that Fonterra say that end of
the market is, in their view, an international price competitive sector because
they compete with imports.
Mr Tennant—I think they should be made to prove that. I think
it should be a visible process.[59]
...in a state where the vast majority of your product is for
domestic fresh milk production, the fact that it is artificially linked to one
of the lowest farmgate milk prices in the world is an indication of market and
market power abuse.[60]
3.53
Dairy Australia comment in their annual review that 'international
markets prices are the major factor determining the price received by farmers
for their milk' but immediately below Chart 3.1 shows large divergences between
farmgate prices across countries, with Australian farmers generally being paid
less than those in other advanced economies.[61]
Chart 3.1:
International farmgate milk prices
Source: Dairy Australia, Australian
Dairy Industry in Focus 2009, p. 10.
3.54
It may be more useful to think of the global price (after allowing for
transport costs) as setting both bounds on the price that farmers will accept
in the medium term for their milk and that processors will pay. If the sum of
the world price plus the cost of shipping milk offshore (either directly or
after transformation into products such as cheese) is greater than domestic
processors will pay, then the farmers will not supply milk to the processors.
Conversely if the price demanded by the farmer is greater than the world price
plus the cost of importing milk, the processors will import milk rather than
buy from domestic farmers.
3.55
Whereabouts the price settles between these bounds in the medium term
will depend on the relative bargaining power of the processors and farmers.
When, as for example in Tasmania, one or two processors face large numbers of
farmers, the bargaining power of the processors is much higher and the price is
likely to settle closer to the lower bound. In the UK, a study concluded that
milk processors have more bargaining power than farmers' cooperatives, with the
processor securing twice as much margin as the farmers.[62]
3.56
In practice, it is unlikely to be economic for processors to import raw
milk. Currently the only dairy product imported in any significant quantity is
cheese.[63]
The effective ceiling on the farmgate milk price is the maximum price that the
supermarkets are willing to pay the processor.
3.57
The Committee was intrigued by the way price–setting was described.
National Foods appeared to set their prices based on those set by Fonterra, who
in turn had based their prices on those set by Murray Goulburn:
...normally Murray Goulburn sets the base price and everyone
else pays a cent or half a cent more.[64]
3.58
This system of 'cascading' prices does not sound very competitive. It
appears the followers are effectively promising Murray Goulburn that their
rivals will not attempt to outbid them thereby enabling Murray Goulburn to be
more conservative in the opening price they offer farmers.
3.59
Questioned about this, the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission reflected:
Where you have a market or somebody like Fonterra with that
much of the market that it is buying into it, it would not be at all unusual to
see that. Again, the collusion issue would be much more obvious if they got
together and talked about keeping their price down...It is something that you
would see across a range of industries given some of the market dynamics. I
would not see it as a form of collusion but there is no doubt that it is the
result of the market structure...[65]
3.60
The Committee again noted with interest the ACCC's response when asked at
Additional Senate Estimates in February 2010 to clarify the difference between
price leadership and predatory pricing to which they responded:
Price leadership is a general economic term used to refer to
pricing behaviour of a dominant firm.
Price leadership is not of itself likely to raise TPA
concerns unless the pricing behaviour satisfies the elements of the prohibition
against predatory pricing...or is undertaken in contravention of other TPA
provisions prohibiting anticompetitive agreements.[66]
3.61
These concerns have been exacerbated as the processing industry has become
more concentrated (the challenges this poses are discussed further in the
following chapter). As Associate Professor Zumbo puts it:
...mergers are typically justified on the basis of allowing
efficiencies or a reduction in costs to be achieved, but such efficiencies, if
any, will only be beneficial to consumers if they are passed onto them. Indeed,
the danger of mergers is that any efficiencies or reduction in costs that may
be realised through a merger will not be passed onto consumers for the simple reason
that as mergers remove competitors from the market, there will be fewer
competitors left to take an independent stance to drive down prices to
consumers...[67]
Who bears the risk of price fluctuations?
3.62
The preceding analysis implicitly assumed global and domestic demand and
supply was quite stable. When there are fluctuations in supply (due for example
to drought) or demand (due for example to recessions), the price in a spot
market for farm milk would fluctuate. This volatility in prices, which could be
followed by volatility in the domestic demand for and supply of milk, could
make forward planning difficult for both farmers and processors. In practice,
therefore processors have longer term contracts with their supplying farmers.
3.63
The question in designing these contracts is whether these contracts
should specify a fixed price for the coming year (in which case the farmer has
more certainty and the processor bears the risk); or whether the contracts
should allow for prices to vary (giving the processor more certainty of profit
and shifting the risk onto the farmer).
3.64
It might be argued that the small number of large processors are much
better placed than the many individual farmers to manage risks. As well as
having operations diversified across the world, and large capital reserves, the
processors are able to access derivatives markets to manage risk.
3.65
In practice, contracts seem to be a mix of the two. The Committee heard
in Tasmania that there was a base price which could be 'stepped up' if global
demand and prices rose. It may also be 'stepped down' in certain circumstances.
The problem was that the conditions that trigger these movements did not appear
to be very clear.
3.66
As discussed further in Chapter 5, the Committee found that the
distribution of risk was obscured further in the Tasmanian market by the
complexity of the contractual arrangements with features such as 'model farms',[68]
28 or 35 day months, differing regimes for different half-years, prices paid by
one processor tied in complicated ways to those paid by other processors,
actual versus theoretical litres, bonuses and penalties, conditional
retrospective payments and so forth, which a number of witnesses characterised
as 'smoke and mirrors'.[69]
Recommendation 2
3.67
The Committee recommends that contracts with farmers should offer a clear,
consistent formula for milk pricing with unambiguous conditions.
3.68
The terms of negotiation between farmers and processors are discussed
further in Chapter 5.
Costs faced by farmers
3.69
The seasonal nature of dairy farming conflicts with the need for year
round milk supply for drinking milk, the tension between these factors
significantly affecting the cost of production for dairy farmers and resulting
in discrepancies between the different regions.
3.70
The Tasmanian Suppliers Collective Bargaining Group provided the Committee
with evidence from a number of sources that typical costs for farmers in that
state were around 40 cents per litre.[70]
It was suggested that costs on Tasmanian dairy farms vary within a range of
between 32 and 45 cents per litre.[71]
One reason is some farmers are supplying milk all year round (for the drinking
milk market) while others vary production (for the manufacturing milk market).
3.71
A breakdown of costs was provided to the Committee by the Tasmanian
Government, shown in Table 3.5.
Table 3.5: Costs and
profitability of Tasmanian dairy farms (cents per litre)
|
2005-06 |
2007-08 |
2009-10(f) |
Animal costs |
3 |
3 |
3 |
Feed costs |
13 |
19 |
16 |
Overhead costs |
14 |
15 |
15 |
Finance costs |
3 |
5 |
4 |
Production costs |
32 |
42 |
38 |
Milk price |
34 |
49 |
31 |
Other income |
3 |
2 |
2 |
Total income |
38 |
52 |
33 |
Earnings before tax |
6 |
9 |
-5 |
Source: Tasmanian Department of
Primary Industries, Parks, Water and Environment, Submission 12, p. 6.
3.72
Costs are generally lower in Tasmania than elsewhere:
There is absolutely no question that our input costs to
produce milk are among the best in the world in terms of being low. We have a
climate that can grow grass. We have very good farmers. They are extremely well
organised and they are switched on. We have had a lot of people come to
Tasmania because of this.[72]
Tasmania is the most competitive dairy region in the country
in terms of its production cost.[73]
Tasmania is an ideal dairy area. It is the best dairy area in
Australia bar none. We have got good water resources and we have got good land
soils...[74]
Tasmanian dairy farmers also have the lowest cost of
production in Australia.[75]
3.73
The small Western Australian dairy farming region is also claimed to be more
efficient than the northern regions, but views differ about how this translates
into farm costs:
We have a fantastic climate and a fantastic amount of land.
We can produce milk here at a cost–effective price compared with just about
anywhere else in the world...the cost of production for our farm is 28c a litre.[76]
In Western Australia, we are producing one of the best
quality milk products in the world...I understand the average cost of production
in Western Australia under Red Sky was 35c a litre.[77]
At the farm level, the costs of production are similar to
elsewhere in Australia.[78]
3.74
Queensland is acknowledged as less suitable for dairying:
We do get paid on average more money than the southern
producers, but running a farm in our part of the world is a higher cost system...[79]
3.75
Therefore, although it is less suitable for dairy farming, arguably as
the supply is predominantly for the drinking milk market, the fewer dairy
farmers receive a higher price to produce milk on a year round basis.
3.76
Some South Australian dairy farmers estimated their costs at around 36
cents per litre.[80]
Quantifying the shares of the milk price
3.77
The ratio of the farmgate price (lower line in Chart 3.2) to the retail
price (upper line) has declined over time.
Chart 3.2: Retail and
farmgate milk prices (cents per litre)
Retail
price is simple average of prices in Sydney and Melbourne. Source: Secretariat,
based on data from ABARE, Australian Commodity Statistics 2009, tables
81 and 82.
3.78
It is not an easy matter to apportion the typical supermarket price of
milk (around $1.75 per litre for a branded product and $1.25 per litre for
a generic) between the costs and profit margins of the various players in the
chain. Key witnesses such as National Foods were notably silent when asked
about this.[81]
3.79
The most useful piece of information was provided by Coles. They gave an
estimate by FreshLogic that as of 2008, around 20 per cent of the retail price
accrued to the retailer, 45 per cent to the processor and 35 per cent to the
farmer.[82]
3.80
Based on this and various other estimates provided to the Committee,
Table 3.5 represents the Secretariat's attempt at allocating the
supermarket shelf price. It was not possible from the information provided to
allocate the components fully. There was a residual 'unclaimed' component to the
price; a kind of commercial 'dark matter'. (If this is accruing to the participant
with most market power, then it is likely the supermarkets' profits are being
understated in the table. An odd result is that the numbers in the table
suggest that the supermarkets are making less from generic than from branded
products, which seems inconsistent with their push towards generics.)
3.81
The Committee is aware that processors and/or retailers may disagree
with these estimates but the onus is then on them to provide the actual
numbers.[83]
This would then form the basis for a better informed discussion.
3.82
Better disclosure of this information would be welcomed by many
witnesses:
Transparency would go a long way [towards a fairer
distribution of market power]. For instance, I would love the fresh food people
to tell us how much they make out of a litre of milk and how much the farmer
and the processor make. Then we would see what the public reaction is.[84]
...there has to be some way that the consumer realises that the
$2 per litre that they are paying for liquid milk is broken up into those four
sectors: farm, processor, distribution and retail sectors.[85]
So I agree with those people who say we should require the
ACCC to use their prices surveillance powers to check the margins in the supply
sector, especially of the dairy industry but also of other industries.[86]
Table 3.5:
Estimated components of the cost of full cream milk (cents per litre)
in south-east
Australia, late 2009/early 2010
|
Branded product |
Generic product |
Farmers' costs |
40a |
40a |
Farmers' profit |
2b |
2b |
Transport costs – farm to processor |
3c |
3c |
Processing costs – packaging |
20d |
19e |
Processors' costs – other processing |
15f |
15f |
Processors' costs – advertising |
3g |
0 |
Processors' profit |
30h |
1i |
Transport costs – processor to supermarket |
2j |
2j |
Supermarket operating costs |
21k |
21k |
Supermarket profit |
14m |
4l |
Unallocated residual |
25 |
18 |
Supermarket shelf price |
175n |
125n |
Sources: aTasmanian
Suppliers Collective Bargaining Group, Submission 27; an estimate of
32-45 cpl was provided by Mr Mark Fergusson of the Tasmanian Institute of
Agricultural Research, Committee Hansard, 6 November 2009, p. 67. bDairy
Australia, Australian Dairy Industry in Focus 2009, p. 14 says the
typical farmgate price in 2008-09 was 42 cpl. cMr Kevin Tesselaar,
Australian Milk Producers Association, Committee Hansard, 18 January
2010, p. 22; and Mr Robert Wilson, Committee Hansard, 5 November 2009,
p. 38. dMr Robert Wilson, Committee Hansard, 5 November
2009, p. 38. Mr Richard Bovill estimates the distribution cost as 'less than 20
cpl'; Committee Hansard, 6 November 2009, p. 5. eThe cost
is assumed to be a little less for generic milk as the labels are simpler. fMr
Robert Wilson, Committee Hansard, 5 November 2009, p. 38. Mr Richard
Bovill estimates the distribution cost as 'less than 15 cpl'; Committee
Hansard, 6 November 2009, p. 5. gMurray Goulburn spend the
equivalent of 4 per cent of sales on advertising, according to their 2009
annual report. hMr Richard Bovill estimates 'National Foods’ margin
on Pura milk to be somewhere in excess of 70c a litre'; Committee Hansard,
6 November 2009, p. 6. iBased on accounts in ACCC (2008, p. 384) and
elsewhere that profit margins are generally very low on generic milk. Mr Bovill
said that National Foods' 'margin' is 30 to 50 cpl; Committee Hansard, 6
November 2009. If this is taken to refer to the difference between the farmgate
price and the wholesale price, it would be consistent with this estimate. It is
also consistent with the estimate from Mr Cummings, NARGA, Committee Hansard,
4 February 2010, p. 13 that the contract price for 2 litre milk was
'slightly less than $1.70' and his view that there is not a processor who can
afford to just sell generic milk (p. 17). Mr Lawson referred to processors
selling generic milk at a 'break-even price'; Committee Hansard, 18
January 2010, p. 15. jMr Richard Bovill estimates the distribution
cost as 'less than 5 cpl'; Committee Hansard, 6 November 2009, p. 5. kWoolworths'
overall selling, general and administrative expenses plus rent were the
equivalent of 19 per cent of sales in 2009. The average milk retail price of
$1.50 multiplied by 19% gives 28 cents. Milk is refrigerated but not freezed,
handled in bulk and while it possibly has a below average value/shelf space, it
turns over rapidly so operating costs are likely to below the average for total
supermarket sales. For this table, it is assumed they are three-quarters (if
they are less, then supermarket profit is understated in the table). lColes
and Woolworths both claim they have a gross profit margin on generic milk of
around 24‑25 per cent; Mr Dunn, Woolworths, Committee Hansard, 4
February 2010, pp 32, 39; Mr Mara, Coles, Committee Hansard, 4 February
2010, p. 7. mWoolworths said 'we make a very similar gross profit
margin...on branded products and on private label products'. This is assumed to
refer to a percentage mark-up rather than an amount in cents. nTable
3.9.
Recommendation 3
3.83
The Committee recommends that the Government requests the Australian
Competition and Consumer Commission to use its information‑gathering
powers, and draw on its work for its recent report on grocery pricing, to
provide more accurate estimates of the proportions of the retail price of milk
that reflect (i) the costs and (ii) the profits, of farmers, processors and
retailers and requests that the results of that review be published by 30
September 2010.
Committee view
3.84
Notwithstanding the degree of uncertainty around the estimates, it seems
clear that the farmers' profits from sales of drinking milk are much smaller
than those accruing to the supermarkets (especially for generics) and the
processors (especially for branded products). This does not seem a fair
reflection of the effort required and risks undertaken by the various parties
involved in producing the milk which consumers buy at a supermarket.
3.85
The difference between the price of branded and generic milk also seems
much larger than can be explained by differences in marketing and labelling
costs or economies of scale. The difference appears symptomatic of the exercise
of market power by the major supermarket chains, as discussed further in the
following chapter.
3.86
The Committee is sympathetic to the views on relative market power
expressed by a witness as follows:
The national tendering process and the amount of volume sold
through the big supermarkets enables supermarkets to squeeze the processors,
because with that volume it becomes an imperative part of those processors’
business to ensure that they do not lose those tenders...The only thing left for
the processors to do then is to in turn squeeze the dairy farmer, and the only
thing left for the farmers to squeeze is the cow’s tit.[87]
International comparison
3.87
Comparing Australia to the United Kingdom (Table 3.6), farmgate prices
are similar, but the costs and/or profits of processors and retailers appear to
be considerably higher. Similarly, the Southern Sydney Retailers Association
argues that while farmgate prices are higher in the United States than in
Australia, American retail prices are lower.[88]
Table 3.6: Comparison
of branded full cream milk (cents per litre)
|
Australia |
United Kingdom |
Farmgate price |
42 |
44 |
Processing costs – packaging, bottling |
20 |
9 |
Processing costs - other |
15 |
6 |
Transport costs – farm to processor |
3 |
5 |
Transport costs – processor to supermarket |
2 |
9 |
Processors' profit |
30 |
3 |
Supermarket gross margin (residual) |
63 |
45 |
Supermarket shelf price |
175 |
121 |
Sources: For Australia, Table
3.5; for UK, mostly pence per litre in 2005 from Howard Smith and John
Thanassoulis, The Milk Supply Chain Project, January 2008, University of
Oxford, pp 20, 23, 31 scaled up by 8 per cent for inflation from 2005 to 2009
and multiplied by exchange rate of 1.80 cents per penny; farmgate price from UK
Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs; retail price from
my.supermarket.co.uk.
Price controls and supports
3.88
While the best longer term response to the simultaneous existence of low
farmgate prices and high retail prices for milk is increasing the competition
between retailers and between processors, in the medium term a possible
response would be to cap the retail price and possibly relate it to the
farmgate price. It has been suggested for example that it would be reasonable
to limit the retail price to a maximum of three times the farmgate price, as is
done in New York.[89]
3.89
The simplest form this could take would be a price ceiling on retail
milk, which could be varied annually depending on the average farmgate price in
the previous year. This would be subject to the usual arguments about the
welfare losses resulting from price controls. It might keep prices down for
consumers but would not increase prices for farmers.
3.90
A more complex approach, with more subtle effects, would be to tie the
retail price of individual supermarket chains to the farmgate prices paid by
the processors who supply them. This would introduce a new dynamic whereby a
supermarket would prefer to buy from a processor that pays a higher farmgate
price. This may then lead to both lower prices for consumers and higher prices
for farmers, at the expense of retailers and processors.
3.91
An alternative approach would be to impose a levy on the retail price and
funnel that back to the farmers. A similar scheme was in place for a number of
years after deregulation:
If you go back a little bit, we had a system here in the
Australian industry of having a support, a market milk levy, which assisted
farmers that were being driven out of the industry by drought and deregulation.
That levy was administered at a federal level, and the levy was some 11c a
litre on all market milk. It was in place for a period of years. In my
experience of many years, that has been one of the easiest mechanisms to comply
with, as a processor. It worked well. It was audited well. The price gained at
retail was brought back and paid back into the industry, to farmers. If you
were to look at something similar, to support what I am saying, to get a better
yield out of the Australian market, you would have to look at that sort of
mechanism.[90]
3.92
A levy was supported by some witnesses:
...I would support a levy and that it should be set up over about
a four‑year period. But, to stop people coming in to make a killing on
the side when they are not entitled to, you would need to base it on the
production of, say, the 2008–09 season.[91]
3.93
The levy would be likely to be borne partly by retailers and partly by
consumers, and perhaps to some extent passed back to processors. The experience
of the earlier levy was that it did not affect farmgate prices.[92]
3.94
Another approach would be to set a floor on the farmgate price.[93]
Just banning sales at below a certain price may make matters worse for farmers
if it meant that their milk was not being sold at all.
3.95
Alternatively there could be a price/income stabilisation fund, as has
been used in the past for agricultural commodities, where farmers pay in during
good years and receive support in bad years. A variant would be a loan scheme
for farmers with milk price‑contingent repayments. A problem with such
schemes is that they require a good estimate of the long-run trend in prices to
determine whether a fall in price represents a short-term or long-term event.
(Chart 6.1 shows that forecasting longer‑term prices is, to put it
mildly, an inexact science. The spike in milk prices in 2008 was unexpected,
and once it occurred it was erroneously expected to continue.)
3.96
An example of such a proposal, which could be run by Dairy Australia or
a similar body, was set out by a Victorian dairy farmer:
All product consumed domestically...would have a pricing
structure completely separate from the exported product. The authority would
set a minimum pricing structure to apply to all domestic product. The authority
would determine from the amount of milk that is produced...the component that was
consumed within Australia...and this would set the percentage or the amount of
the farmer’s production to be paid at the rate set by the authority...It would be
done in a similar way to the way that the Dairy Structural Adjustment Program
Scheme was struck, so that it does not allow people to suddenly come in and
flood the market and receive a high percentage. A compulsory levy would be
applied to all dairy farmers to help fund the operation of the authority. This
is not unusual; it is similar to the research and development levy that
currently applies through Dairy Australia. Therefore, this mechanism would be
less dependent on government funding for its operation. A farmer could produce
as much milk as he chose to, but only a component would be paid at a rate to
reflect that consumed domestically.[94]
3.97
In the short to medium term the government could boost the returns to
dairy farmers by buying milk, converting it to powder, and providing it to poor
and/or drought-afflicted countries in exchange for commitments by them to
environmentally sustainable practices. This would have a budgetary cost but
could achieve simultaneously a number of objectives. A proposal along these
lines was presented to the Committee by some South Australian farmers:
We note AusAid is currently at $3.7b. The inclusion of dairy
product, i.e. skim milk powder could give the government an opportunity to
underpin the industry without it being seen as a subsidy.[95]
Committee view
3.98
The Committee is concerned about the increases in milk prices that do
not seem to reflect farmgate prices, or be obviously related to other cost
increases. At present, however, the Committee believes this can be better
addressed by improving competition in markets rather than by direct regulation
of retail prices. Should alternative approaches fail, the Committee believes
that price controls could be reconsidered.
3.99
The Committee observed the UK model which relies on a formula to set the
retail price although ruled out such a response in Australia given the
prohibitive level of regulation it would introduce and the different
composition of the Australian market.
Varying prices in different states
3.100
Both retail and farmgate prices vary across the country, but not in a
directly related way. The variation in farmgate prices is shown in Table 3.7. Over
the medium term, prices tend to be lower in the southern states where climatic
conditions are more conducive to dairy farming.[96]
Table 3.7: Typical farmgate
prices (cents per litre)
|
2008–09 |
Average 2002–03 to
2008–09 |
Queensland |
57 |
41 |
New South Wales |
52 |
38 |
South Australia |
45 |
35 |
Tasmania |
41 |
35 |
Victoria |
39 |
34 |
Western Australia |
49 |
33 |
Source: derived from data in Dairy
Australia, Australian Dairy Industry in 2009, p. 14.
3.101
The prices received across states may also vary according to how the
milk is used in the market place:
...if you are in an area which supplies mainly drinking milk
then prices tend to be higher—for example, in northern New South Wales and
southern Queensland. If you are in an area where the preponderance or the bulk
of the production is manufacturing milk that will ultimately go to export, then
prices tend to reflect what is happening more closely with what is happening in
the world market.[97]
In Queensland there has been a contraction of farms and milk
over the last 10 years since deregulation. It has only been in the last year
that that decline in milk, which was compounding at about six per cent per
year, has actually started to come back up. Now, obviously, pricing signals
needed to be put in place in those areas to ensure that there was a fresh milk
supply in Queensland for everyday milk. In the Queensland market, most of the
manufacturing capability in that state has now ceased and it is really a market
milk, predominantly state.[98]
Queensland milk producers have received higher prices...than
their southern counterparts because of the nature of the Queensland industry.
The industry is structured around the fresh milk market and is not strongly
influenced by export market fluctuations.[99]
3.102
However this interpretation was also questioned by one witness:
Yes, one price buys all milk. We do not get differential
pricing. It is interesting: if companies are in different products, you would
think there might be a variation of farm-gate price, but there is not.[100]
3.103
One interpretation was that the differences reflected previous attempts
to lock in longer term contracts:
...one of the issues that we have been well aware has been
brought up in this discussion has been where one region has been paid
substantially more than another. That is not necessarily driven by the
circumstances of today but by the circumstances of 18 months or two years ago,
where some of those regions were experiencing very harsh seasonal conditions
and the companies made judgments about their long–term ability to source milk.
Out of the discussions and negotiations at that time they went into contractual
arrangements, which is not uncommon. They went in in good faith in that
discussion with the producers and the groups involved in the companies and put
contracts on the table for a period of time which they felt secured a base in
their milk supply.[101]
3.104
In the shorter term, farmgate prices will reflect differences in the
keenness of competition. The Committee heard that National Foods was offering
farmers in New South Wales 44 cents per litre while only offering Tasmanian
farmers 33 cents per litre.[102]
A Tasmanian expert gave the following explanation:
Mr Smith—The costs of production are probably higher in New
South Wales because they are generally having to bring in more feed. We can
grow feed more cheaply here.
Senator MILNE—So you think it is because there is competition
in the marketplace in New South Wales [that prices there are higher].
Mr Smith—Yes.[103]
3.105
National Foods also referred to differences in competition, albeit
somewhat more obliquely:
...in Tasmania, Victoria or South Australia it is a different competitive
set in terms of procuring milk...[104]
3.106
The Australian Bureau of Statistics measure average retail prices for
milk in the capital cities, shown in Table 3.8. It is notable that the lower
farmgate prices in the southern states appear not to be translated into lower
retail prices.
Table 3.8: Retail
milk prices across cities
(cents
per litre for 2 litres whole milk; December quarter 2009)
Sydney |
174 |
|
Perth |
158 |
Melbourne |
179 |
|
Hobart |
185 |
Brisbane |
159 |
|
Canberra |
186 |
Adelaide |
172 |
|
Darwin |
213 |
Source: ABS, Average Retail
Prices of Selected Items, Eight Capital Cities.
3.107
The ABS data in Table 3.8 refers to the average price paid for milk so
will be influenced by differences in the proportions of branded and the cheaper
generic milk in each city; and differences between the proportions of milk sold
in supermarkets as opposed to convenience stores, milk bars and service
stations.
3.108
Alternative sources, distinguishing between the prices of branded and
generic milk, and not subject to these compositional effects, were used to
compile Tables 3.9 and 3.10.
Table 3.9: Retail
milk prices across cities
(cents
per litre for 2 litres full cream milk; 7 February 2010)
|
One major chain |
Other major chain |
|
Generic milk |
Branded milk |
Generic milk |
Branded milk |
Sydney |
124 |
188 (df) |
133 |
199 (pr) |
Newcastle |
124 |
188 (df) |
124 |
177 (pr) |
Canberra |
124 |
188 (df) |
124 |
187 (cm) |
Melbourne |
124 |
170 (pl) |
133 |
186 (pr) |
Brisbane |
124 |
159 (df) |
124 |
170 (df) |
Cairns |
na |
na |
124 |
175 (pl) |
Adelaide |
124 |
173 (df) |
na |
na |
Perth |
124 |
176 (hf) |
na |
na |
Hobart |
na |
na |
120 |
187 (pr) |
Launceston |
na |
na |
120 |
187 (pr) |
df: Dairy Farmers; pl: Pauls;
hf; Harvey Fresh; pr: Pura; cm: Canberra
Milk.
Source: Secretariat based on
supermarkets' online shopping websites.
Table 3.10: Retail milk
prices across cities
(cents
for 1 litre full cream milk; February — April 2010)
|
One major chain |
Other major chain |
|
Generic milk |
Branded milk |
Generic milk |
Branded milk |
Sydney |
137 |
224df |
137 |
224df |
Melbourne |
|
|
137 |
239re |
Brisbane |
|
|
137 |
191pl |
Perth |
137 |
218pr |
137 |
218pr |
Adelaide |
|
|
137 |
208pr |
Hobart |
|
|
137 |
208pr |
Darwin |
137 |
219pl |
137 |
227pl |
df: Dairy Farmers; pl: Pauls;
hf; Harvey Fresh; pr: Pura; re: REV. Source: visits to supermarkets.
3.109
There is still no clear pattern of milk being cheaper on the supermarket
shelves in areas where the farmgate price is lower, suggesting it may be
competition (or lack thereof) in various retail markets that determines the
prices charged there. This was conceded by Woolworths:
But the retail price will move more often in those three
years than the cost price will and it will move between stores and between
regions and between areas, even though the cost may not change. That is just an
effect of competition.[105]
3.110
Questioned on the difference in prices between cities, Coles replied:
...the major difference in state prices could be attributed to
the different timing of contract negotiations which applies for us at different
times in different states.[106]
Committee view
3.111
The Committee brings to the attention of government the inconsistencies
in price setting at the farmgate and retail levels of the domestic drinking
milk market.
3.112
Throughout the course of its inquiry the Committee heard evidence of the
established practice of Murray Goulburn effectively acting as a price leader,
announcing their farmgate price and then being followed by the remaining
processors of National Foods and Fonterra despite the different markets to
which the companies sell.
Recommendation 4
3.113
The Committee recommends that the Government requests the ACCC to
undertake monitoring of the pricing practices within the dairy chain with a
view to establishing whether predatory pricing or misuse of market power is
occurring.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page