Chapter 4
Competition in the dairy industry
4.1
There has been a trend towards increased concentration among both
processors and retailers of milk in Australia. This is not just a coincidence; the
increase in concentration among retailers has been an important driver of the
increased concentration among processors and this looks likely to continue. The
victims of this increased concentration are the farmers and the consumers.
4.2
As stated in Chapter 1, this experience raises concerns much more
broadly than just in the dairy industry, as similar problems have, or could,
arise in other areas given the dominance of the two large supermarket chains in
the retail sales of so many products.
Competition in the retail and wholesale markets
4.3
As noted in previous chapters, the two major supermarket chains, Coles
and Woolworths, sell about half the drinking milk sold to consumers, and over
half of this is in the form of generic milk. Both these proportions appear to
be increasing, with attendant risks to competition.
4.4
The provision of generic milk to supermarkets has become a very
important component of sales for processors. As noted in the previous chapter,
the large supermarket chains tend to want a single processor for each state or
region, or perhaps even a single national supplier.[1]
This preference encourages consolidation within the processing sector as only
large processors can credibly bid for the contracts, and a processor without
such a contract cannot realise economies of scale.
Possible policy responses
4.5
Removing this anti-competitive impetus requires reducing the dominance
of the large supermarkets and/or reducing their use of generic milk and its
impact on processors.
Reducing the dominance of the large
supermarket chains
4.6
In Australia mergers which would lead to a 'substantial lessening of
competition' are (supposed to be) prohibited by section 50 of the Trade
Practices Act. This has not, however, prevented mergers such as the
National Foods takeover of Dairy Farmers which, the Committee heard evidence,
had substantially affected the competitive dynamics of the Tasmanian dairy
market.
4.7
This is because the courts have adopted a very demanding test of what
constitutes a 'substantial lessening of competition', effectively requiring
that after a merger the new company must be almost a monopoly. Associate
Professor Zumbo submitted:
The “substantial lessening of competition” test requires that
in order for the merger or acquisition to be considered in breach of the test,
the merged entity must have the ability to raise prices without losing business
to rivals.[2]
4.8
Given the test is so demanding, it is unsurprising that the ACCC
approves over 95 per cent of proposed mergers and acquisitions which it
considers.
4.9
Even with its shortcomings, Section 50 would presumably prevent a merger
between Coles and Woolworths, and probably prevent them taking over the
Australian operations of ALDI or buying up simultaneously a large number of
independent grocers. But preventing a substantial lessening of competition does
nothing to deal with an existing state of inadequate competition. For this
additional measures are required.
4.10
The most direct approach would be 'trust busting' – requiring
divestiture by chains that have an 'excessive' market share or market power. As
one witness put it:
I think Senator Xenophon suggested they split the two majors
into four—bloody good idea![3]
4.11
Associate Professor Frank Zumbo would like to:
...amend the Trade Practices Act to provide for a general divestiture
power whereby a Court can, on the application of the ACCC, order the break up
of companies (i) having substantial market share; and (ii) where either the
characteristics of the market prevent, restrict or distort competition; or the
companies have engaged in patterns of conduct that are detrimental to
competition and consumers.[4]
4.12
He comments:
Unlike the United Kingdom or the United States, Australia
does not provide for a general divestiture power to deal with highly
concentrated markets having characteristics that prevent, restrict or distort
competition in those markets. In the United Kingdom a very sophisticated
framework has been enacted to allow for highly concentrated markets to be
reviewed with the purpose of assessing the level of competition in a market and
for taking steps to remedy market distortions having a detrimental impact on
competition and consumers.[5]
4.13
A dissenting report by a minority of the Senate Standing Committee on
Economics in 2008 suggested:
We need to enact a divestiture power which allows the Court
to break up corporations that dominate markets by acquiring a substantial
market share to the detriment of small businesses and consumers...Consideration
should be given to enacting a divestiture power under the Trade Practices Act.[6]
Creeping acquisitions
4.14
One way in which the major supermarkets increase their market share is
through 'creeping acquisitions'; a series of takeovers, each of which is
individually too small to 'substantially lessen competition' but which
cumulatively may do so.
4.15
The Senate Economics References Committee examined this topic in the
context of its report on the Trade Practices Act 1974 in 2004 and
concluded:
The Committee considers that provisions should be introduced
into the Act to ensure that the ACCC has powers to prevent creeping
acquisitions which substantially lessen competition in a market.[7]
4.16
The ACCC's 2008 report on grocery prices noted that concerns about
creeping acquisitions persisted in the supermarket sector. It conceded that its
powers to prevent them may be limited:
While s. 50 of the Act applies to individual acquisitions,
the application to potential ‘creeping acquisition’ issues is more problematic.
The ACCC takes the view that, while it can assess under s. 50 the competitive
issues associated with an individual acquisition, s. 50 is unlikely to allow it
to examine the cumulative impact of a series of acquisitions of smaller
competitors over time that individually do not raise competition issues... The ACCC considers that the
supermarket industry is one where creeping acquisitions could potentially
become a concern...[8]
4.17
Shortly afterwards, the Senate Standing Committee on Economics revisited
the topic while inquiring into the Trade Practices (Creeping Acquisitions)
Amendment Bill. The bill sought to amend the Trade Practices Act 1974 so
that an acquisition would be deemed to lessen competition substantially if it
and other acquisitions over the previous six years would have that effect. The Committee
concluded:
...concerns about the impact of 'creeping acquisitions' on
competition are valid. It agrees that the current provisions of section 50 of
the Trade Practices Act are insufficient to address the problem
adequately.[9]
4.18
The majority of the Committee, however, preferred to defer consideration
of the bill until the Government presented its own legislation. The Government
subsequently released two discussion papers canvassing various options. But so
far, the only legislative change the Government has foreshadowed is to clarify
that substantial lessening of competition could refer to a local market,
not just a national market.
4.19
A new investigation of creeping acquisitions is now being conducted by
the Senate Economics Legislation Committee as part of its inquiry into the Trade
Practices Amendment (Material Lessening of Competition-Richmond Amendment) Bill
2009.[10]
This bill would amend section 50 of the TPA such that a corporation which
already has a substantial share of a market must not directly or
indirectly merge with or acquire shares or an asset which would have the effect
of lessening competition in the market.
Committee view
4.20
In recent times the Committee has increasingly been referred inquiries which
seek to examine issues concerning the operation of the Trade Practices Act
1974. The evidence that the Committee has collected throughout those
inquiries together with the information that has been uncovered during the
dairy inquiry has left the Committee with concerns and questions in relation to
the state of competition in the Australian marketplace.
Recommendation 5
4.21
The Committee recommends that the Productivity Commission reviews and
evaluates the effectiveness of the national competition policy and requests
that it publish its report by 30 April 2011.
Recommendation 6
4.22
The Committee recommends a moratorium on further takeovers and mergers
in the milk processing industry until the Productivity Commission has published
its report on the effectiveness of the national competition policy.
Misuse of market power and price
discrimination
4.23
Section 46 of the TPA aims to promote competition by preventing
corporations who have substantial market power from abusing that power and
specifically prohibiting those entities from using their market power to
eliminate or damage a competitor, prevent entry of others into the market or
prevent or deter others from engaging in competitive conduct in a market.[11]
4.24
As noted in Chapter 3, the processors provide milk at a lower price to
the large supermarket chains than to smaller supermarkets. To some extent, this
reflects economies of scale in dealing with the larger chains. It may also,
however, reflect the market power of the large chains.
4.25
Similarly, the processors charge a lower price to the major supermarkets
than they do to vendors who on-sell milk to small retailers such as milk bars,
take-away food outlets and other small stores to whom milk is an ancillary line
of business. One vendor told the Committee they paid around $1.40 a litre for
milk.[12]
This is more than the supermarket's shelf price for generic milk and more –
probably considerably more – than the supermarkets pay the processors for
branded milk.[13]
4.26
Similarly, another vendor submitted:
National Foods were...responsible for the ordering, pricing,
billing and collection of milk sold to customers who are delivered to by
Parmalat Distributors in NSW. We can prove that these customers are paying less
than our cost for product... General wholesale price for a two litre milk is
$3.51...Given many coffee shops and small businesses can go to Woolies and Coles
and but three litre generic milk for $3.16 – how can I compete with that?[14]
4.27
There are suggestions that the Trade Practices Act should be
strengthened to prevent such price discrimination:
With smaller retailers at a substantial competitive
disadvantage because of the higher prices they pay for branded milk, Coles and
Woolworths need not compete as aggressively on price as they would have to if
the smaller retailers were able to provide a stronger competitive constraint on
Coles and Woolworths... Where anti-competitive price discrimination is present,
it should be dealt with under the Trade Practices Act. Given the continued
ineffectiveness of s 46 it is appropriate to amend the Trade Practices Act to
deal specifically with anticompetitive price discrimination. A number of
international precedents are available including the United States Robinson‑Patman
Act of 1936 and s 18 of the United Kingdom Competition Act 1998.[15]
4.28
The TPA formerly included an explicit 'price discrimination' provision.
Section 49(1) had stated:
A corporation shall not, in trade or commerce, discriminate
between purchasers of goods of like grade and quality in relation to
(a) the prices charged for the goods;
(b) any discounts, allowances, rebates or credits given or allowed
in relation to the supply of goods;
(c) the provision of services in respect of the goods;
(d) the making of payments for services provided in respect
of the goods if the discrimination is of such magnitude or is of such a
recurring or systematic character that it has or is likely to have the effect
of substantially lessening competition in a market for goods, being a market in
which the corporation supplies, or those persons supply, goods.
4.29
Section 49(2) had listed two defences to 49(1). The first was where the
price differences reflected differences in the cost or likely cost of
manufacture, distribution, sale or delivery resulting from the different places
to which the goods are supplied to purchasers. The second defence was where the
discrimination was constituted by the doing of an act in good faith to meet a
price or benefit offered by a competitor of the supplier.
4.30
The repeal of section 49 was recommended by the Swanson Committee
(1976), the Blunt Committee (1979) and the Hilmer Committee (1995) and it was
repealed in 1995. In 2003, the Dawson Review recommended that the effect of
price discrimination on competition be considered on a case-by-case basis,
arguing that section 46 is the most appropriate means to tackle anti‑competitive
price discrimination. Further, the Review considered that there are reasons for
differences in wholesale prices in the grocery industry which do not involve
anti-competitive practices.[16]
4.31
A review into Parts IV and VII of the TPA in 2004 examined whether
section 46 required amendment to deal better with price discrimination
(previously addressed by section 49) and concluded that section 46 was
adequate.[17]
4.32
The Senate Economics Legislation Committee again examined the operation
of section 46 as part of its inquiry into the proposed Blacktown Amendment. A
number of submissions argued that, as interpreted by the courts, section 46 is
ineffective in providing protection against anti-competitive conduct.[18]
The Boral case, in particular, is widely seen as having vitiated section 46 by
ruling that only conduct by a firm with 'substantial market power' is
prohibited and then setting the standard for 'substantial market power'
unrealistically high.
4.33
The ACCC Chairman, for example, commented:
The High Court decision in the Boral case, in our view—and in
the view of senior counsel—has given a legal interpretation to the wording of
section 46, which indicates that parliament did not achieve its intention. The
use of the words ‘substantial degree of market power’ did not lower the threshold
below that of dominance...[19]
4.34
The restoration of an explicit provision against price discrimination in
the TPA would empower the ACCC to act and the Australian Competition Tribunal
to review. It is advocated by former senator Margetts:
To remove the prices discrimination, as an example, from the Trade
Practices Act and then have so much evidence provided to the ACCC grocery
price inquiry about price discrimination that related to branded products, home
brand products and the pressure that has been put on suppliers shows, in my
view, that there is a clear problem with the removal of the prices
discrimination provision.[20]
Committee view
4.35
From evidence taken during the course of its inquiry the Committee takes
the view that the current operation of section 46 is inadequate and is not
providing protection against price discrimination. The major supermarkets appear
to be using their dominant market positions to drive down the farmgate price
through the sale of generic products which puts pressure on processors who are
forced to compete with their own products.
4.36
The Committee takes the view that this will negatively affect
competition and therefore consumers as it will lead to less product choice and
fears that the current interpretation of section 46 will enable these large
players to escape allegations of misusing their market power.
4.37
The Committee considers that this situation needs to be addressed to
ensure the long term viability of Australia's dairy industry.
4.38
The precursor to the Committee has weighed the advantages and
disadvantages of using market share as a proxy measure of market power in an
earlier report, concluding that it was justified.[21]
4.39
It is a matter for judgement what market share might be regarded as
raising potential concerns about market power. The European Commission takes
the view that a firm would generally have a dominant position
once it reaches a market share of 40‑45 per cent and may
achieve a dominant position in the region of 20-40 per cent.[22]
4.40
This is broadly consistent with approaches in some individual European
countries. The Austrian Cartel Act places the burden of proof on a company to
show it is not dominant where its market share exceeds 30 per cent. In Germany
a market share of a third is taken as indicating dominance. The corresponding
threshold in Bulgaria is 35 per cent and in Croatia, Estonia, Lithuania, Poland
and Serbia 40 per cent. In Malta a company with a 40 per cent market share is
deemed dominant unless it provides evidence to the contrary. In Sweden a market
share of 40 per cent is regarded as indicative of dominance. Latvia and Slovakia
have removed their previous 40 per cent thresholds for defining dominance.[23]
A firm would, of course, have some market power well before reaching dominance.
4.41
The US Department of Justice's benchmark for challenging mergers is
where the sum of the squared percentage market shares of the merging companies
exceeds 1800.[24]
This would occur if two firms each having a 30 per cent market share wanted to
merge; or a firm with a 40 per cent market share wanted to take over a
competitor with a 14 per cent market share.
Recommendation 7
4.42
The Committee recommends that the Trade Practices Act be amended to
reinstate specific anti-price discrimination provisions and inhibit firms
achieving market power through takeovers or abusing market power and that
'market power' be expressly defined so that it is less than market dominance
and does not require a firm to have unfettered power to set prices. A specific market
share, such as, for example, one third (based on international practice), could
be presumed to confer market power unless there is strong evidence to the
contrary.
Contracts for generic milk
4.43
The Greens believe there is a strong case for banning large supermarket
chains from selling generic milk (and other generic products). This should lead
to branded products from a wider range of processors, large and small, jostling
for space on the shelves and a more competitive processing industry.
4.44
The knee-jerk reaction to such a proposition is that it would be
denying consumers access to the cheaper products. But this would only be an
immediate reaction. Over time, the same price discrimination tactics applied by
the supermarkets would be applied by (some) processors with some milk being
packaged in a 'cheap and tatty' way and sold at a lower price and more
prestigious brands (even if they are actually the same milk) being sold at a
higher price. Consumers may end up in much the same position but with some of
the profits from price discrimination being shifted from the supermarkets to
the processors (and possibly on to the farmers). In the longer term, consumers
may benefit by avoiding a situation where there is little competition as each
supermarket offers only its own generic products.
4.45
A milder step would be to continue allowing supermarkets to sell generic
milk but require them to have multiple tenders, accepting bids from more and
smaller processors.
4.46
The ACCC told the Committee they had not looked into generic milk
contracts in depth.[25]
Committee view
4.47
The Committee is concerned by the growing market share being acquired by
supermarkets through the sale of their own brand generic products. The Committee
recognises that this trend is occurring across the majority of grocery items,
not just drinking milk, and given the evidence it has heard from dairy farmers
throughout this inquiry believes the effect this practice is having on other primary
industries should be thoroughly investigated.
Recommendation 8
4.48
The Committee recommends that the ACCC conducts further study into the
implications of increasing shares of the grocery market being taken by the
generic products of the major supermarket chains. The Committee recommends that
the terms of reference of any such inquiry include not just the current and
future impact on prices paid by consumers but also the needs of Australia in terms
of food security and economic and environmental sustainability, as well as the
economic viability of farmers and processors. The Committee requests that the
findings of these reviews be reported by 30 April 2011.
Competition in the market for raw milk
4.49
As described in Chapter 2, the number of processors has reduced over
time. From a variety of local processors, often co-operatives, the market is
now dominated by subsidiaries of international corporations (Chart 4.1).
Chart 4.1:
Consolidation of dairy processing operations
Source: Dr Shane Broad, Submission
5, p. 3.
4.50
This has left some farmers facing an effective monopsony:
In the south of the state, Fonterra will not come down and
pick up our milk...We have one option in the south of the state—National Foods.[26]
There really are only two processors for liquid milk in
Tasmania, National Foods and Betta Milk. Betta Milk were supplied by Lactos,
the cheese makers, prior to National Foods buying Lactos. So we had a situation
where the only competitor to National Foods was being supplied with its liquid
milk by National Foods...the fewer the number of processors in Tasmania the
greater is their power.[27]
4.51
The vastly unequal bargaining power that results leads to problems in
negotiating price. The negotiations themselves are discussed in the following
chapter. This chapter is concerned with trying to even up the bargaining power.
4.52
The Committee heard a lot of criticism of the ACCC for allowing National
Foods to take over Dairy Farmers. Notwithstanding some required divestitures,
this has resulted in a significant reduction in competition, notably in
Tasmania:
Who in their right mind would approve National Foods taking
over Dairy Farmers? ...That would have to be the biggest blunder that has ever
happened to the Australian dairy industry.[28]
...it seems extraordinary to us as ordinary dairy farmers that
the ACCC allowed the takeover of Dairy Farmers by National Foods, which in a
sense is almost creating a monopoly.[29]
...that Dairy Farmers acquisition which really leaves huge
questions for the ACCC to answer.[30]
...quite frankly I think the ACCC, through Mr Graeme Samuels,
was really asleep at the wheel in allowing National Foods to buy Dairy Farmers
in the first place, as it was a direct competitor to them in the marketplace...
He was also asleep at the wheel when he allowed National Foods to buy Lactos.[31]
We never envisaged, because of the dominance of National
Foods and Dairy Farmers in that state, that the ACCC would allow one to buy the
other.[32]
4.53
Asked about this approval, the ACCC replied:
We conducted a very extensive review into that matter and
found that there were going to be substantial competition problems that would
breach the act in South Australia and in New South Wales in a number of
markets, including the supply of fresh whole milk, the supply of flavoured
milks and also in relation to a market for the acquisition of milk from dairy
farmers in central New South Wales and South Australia. So we would have
opposed that merger but for a divestiture that was forced upon National Foods.
It was required to divest some processing facilities, depots, brands and
licences to enable another competitor to restore the competition that would
have otherwise been lost in those markets...Following the undertaking, the
commission was satisfied that there was not going to be any substantial
lessening of competition in those markets where it found that it would have
otherwise occurred.[33]
4.54
After the Committee's public hearings were concluded, the ACCC released
a 'statement of issues' concerning the proposed acquisition of Warrnambool
Cheese and Butter by Murray Goulburn Co-operative, expressing the view that it
would be likely to substantially lessen competition and estimating that 'establishing
a new plant of a size that could constrain the merged entity would cost in
excess of $100 million'.[34]
4.55
Some of those who criticise the National Foods takeover of Dairy Farmers
want legislative changes that would prevent any such mergers in the future.
Associate Professor Frank Zumbo recommends amending the TPA so that instead of
preventing takeovers which substantially lessen competition, the bar be
lowered to preventing mergers which materially lessen competition.[35]
4.56
Professor Zumbo's suggestion is encompassed in the Trade Practices
Amendment (Material Lessening of Competition-Richmond Amendment) Bill 2009,
which is currently the subject of an inquiry by the Senate Economics
Legislation Committee. Some evidence before that inquiry raises doubts about
whether courts may distinguish between 'material' and 'substantial' changes to
competition; suggesting that either an alternative wording may be needed or the
intention spelled out very clearly in the legislation and/or explanatory
memorandum.
4.57
A problem identified in the operation of the ACCC is that it is both
umpire and player. It approves a merger and then assesses whether competition
is adequate after the merger:
Being a both a regulator and policeman is a problem but the
ACCC is a peculiar policeman. The ACCC doesn’t fight crime independently. It
doesn’t search for evidence...The ACCC is a stay-at-home policeman, only called
out after the crime has been alleged or committed.[36]
Senator MILNE—...that the ACCC’s powers be divided so that, if
they stay as the approving body for mergers, the adjudication on the impacts of
mergers be taken to another administrative body. Would you support that?...
Mr Oldaker—Yes, ...They need to be made accountable, and if
that is what you have to do then that is what has to happen.[37]
4.58
The ACCC replied:
We would not see such a conflict of roles...In most competition
law enforcement authorities there is a combination of a merger function and an
enforcement function. They are necessarily different because one is forward
looking and one is backwards looking. But they are two tools to achieve
essentially the same goal, which is to enhance the welfare of Australian
consumers. So, rather than being in conflict, they complement each other. I
should say that the staff who conduct the merger reviews are wholly separate to
the staff who conduct the enforcement activities of the commission. They sit in
separate divisions. [38]
4.59
It has also been suggested that the ACCC should have a dedicated small
business branch.
4.60
The Committee also asked the ACCC about barriers to new processors
entering the market. Their view was:
We would like to think that in general the barriers to entry
are reasonably low. For a participant who is serious about entering the market
there are no real legal barriers, but you have to get the plant and
manufacturing processes. I think one of the biggest barriers would be getting
the contracts from farmers. A lot of those are sewn up. We do not try to make
light of those problems but the barriers to entry are probably not as high as
we see in some of the other sectors.[39]
Committee view
4.61
The Committee expresses grave concerns about claims of anti-competitive
conduct by supermarkets. In particular, it appears that the growing dominance
of generic products in the retail market is having detrimental effects on both
consumers and farmers.
4.62
A combination of narrow interpretations by the courts of expressions in
the Trade Practices Act 1974 and the repeal of section 49 mean that the
Act fails to provide adequate protection against excessive market concentration
and abuse of market power. There is inadequate assessment of whether markets
have become excessively concentrated because the agency assessing this (the
ACCC) is the same agency that approved the mergers leading to the high degree
of concentration. The Committee is also concerned that the 'public interest'
which the ACCC seeks to protect appears to be restricted to consumers and it
does not pay sufficient attention to ensuring that farmers get a fair deal.
4.63
The Committee would like to see restrictions placed on creeping
acquisitions by the major supermarket chains, but will leave to the current
inquiry by the Senate Economics Legislation Committee whether this should be by
the proposed Richmond Amendment or legislation shortly to be introduced by the
Government.
4.64
The majority of the Committee is reticent to interfere in commercial
decisions to the extent of banning the sale of generic products by the major
supermarket chains, and would prefer its concerns be addressed by other
measures to promote competition. If the large supermarket chains continue to
sell generic products, the Committee would like to see smaller processors able
to bid to supply them.
Recommendation 9
4.65
The Committee recommends the Productivity Commission considers, in its
review of national competition policy, the appropriateness of separating the functions
and powers of the ACCC with the effect that separate agencies are responsible
for the approval of mergers and the assessment of whether concentration is
subsequently excessive.
Recommendation 10
4.66
The Committee recommends that the topic of competition and pricing in
the dairy industry be again referred to the Senate Economics References
Committee in May 2012 to assess whether progress has been made or whether
tougher and more interventionist measures need to be adopted.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page