Chapter 2
Key issues
2.1
As noted in chapter 1, the bill contains four schedules that propose to
amend various taxation laws to:
-
abolish the mature age worker tax offset (schedule 1);
-
abolish the seafarer tax offset (schedule 2);
-
reduce the rates of the tax offset available under the research
and development tax incentive (R&D tax offset) by 1.5 per cent (schedule
3); and
-
update the list of specifically listed deductible gift recipients
(schedule 4).
2.2
This chapter examines schedules 2 and 3 to the bill on which the
committee received evidence. The committee did not receive evidence on
schedules 1 and 4.
Schedule 2—abolishing the seafarer tax offset
Stakeholder views on schedule 2
2.3
In their submissions, the Australian Shipowners Association (ASA),
Shipping Australia Limited (SAL), the Maritime Union of Australia (MUA) and
Farstad Shipping expressed the view that the seafarer tax offset should not be
abolished.
2.4
The ASA explained that the seafarer tax offset was part of a range of
measures introduced in 2012 that combined:
...to provide the opportunity for Australian businesses to
participate in our international shipping activity and in doing so add value to
the economy, secure major trade routes and grow employment opportunities for
the most highly trained Australian maritime staff.[1]
2.5
In its submission, SAL argued that the shipping industry needs
regulatory stability. They raised concerns that the removal of the seafarer tax
offset may have
the effect of discouraging future investment in the Australian shipping
industry
and possibly discouraging the employment of Australian seafarers in the future.[2]
SAL stated:
Australia is an island nation that is absolutely dependent on
maritime trade for its economy and indeed its survival. International shipping
companies operate on a global commercial basis and will only chose to register
their vessels in Australia if tangible benefits encourage them to do so. The
economic benefits to Australia of becoming a successful shipping registry are
likely to significantly outweigh the costs of implementing effective
incentives.[3]
2.6
The MUA also raised concerns about the need for certainty in shipping
policy.[4]
Benefits to employers
2.7
In its submission, the ASA emphasised that the seafarer tax offset is a
rebate to employers, not employees, whose take home pay remains unchanged.[5]
2.8
Both the ASA and MUA noted that the seafarer tax offset was in line with
similar income tax arrangements offered to employers in many other developed
countries (including Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,
Netherlands, Norway and Spain). The ASA and MUA argued that repealing this
measure would greatly reduce the employment prospects of Australians in highly
skilled maritime roles.[6]
Low take up rates
2.9
The MUA noted in their submission that the low uptake of the seafarer
tax offset reflects the fact that there are very few eligible taxpayers
(shipowners) that would be entitled to the seafarer tax offset.[7]
2.10
Farstad Shipping noted that if the seafarer tax offset were available to
their organisation, it would greatly enhance the training and career
opportunities that they are able to provide to their staff. In their
submission, they advocated for a broader application of the seafarer tax
offset.[8]
Review of coastal trading
2.11
Some submitters noted that the government was currently undertaking
a coastal shipping review.[9]
On 8 April 2014, the government announced an options paper on approaches to
regulating coastal shipping in Australia. The Department of Infrastructure and
Regional Development sought views from stakeholders and is currently in the
process of reviewing submissions received.[10]
2.12
In its submission, SAL argued that it may be better to wait until the
review is finalised before making the decision to abolish the seafarer tax
offset. SAL noted:
Changes to coastal shipping regulations made as a result of
this review may have an impact on the employment of Australian seafarers in the
international trade; thus the retention of the offset may yet have the
opportunity to deliver on its original intent.[11]
2.13
MUA expressed a similar view, arguing that abolishing the seafarer tax
offset before the outcome of the review would 'demonstrate a piecemeal approach
to shipping policy and create further uncertainty for ship investors.'[12]
Committee view on schedule 2
2.14
The committee notes the concerns expressed in the submissions, and would
like to draw the issues raised in the evidence to the attention of the
Department of Infrastructure and Regional Development for its consideration in
finalising its review of coastal trading regulation.
2.15
Given the need to repair the budget, the committee recognises that
savings have to be returned to the budget. Schedule 2 of the bill, if passed,
would go some way to achieving this objective by delivering $12 million in savings
over the next four years.
Schedule 3—rates of the R&D tax offset
Stakeholder views on schedule 3
2.16
Innovation Australia is an independent statutory body which provides
oversight for the R&D tax incentive as well as providing strategic advice
to the Australian government. In its submission, Innovation Australia argued
that the R&D tax incentive provides crucial support for innovation in
Australian industry as well as support for developing new technology and
industry. According to Innovation Australia, in the 2012–13 financial year the
amount claimed under the program grew by 10 per cent.[13]
2.17
Innovation Australia noted and supported the decision not to extend
the amendments to the R&D tax incentive proposed in the bill beyond changes
to the reduction in the rate of the offset. For example, Innovation Australia
supported
the fact that the eligibility criteria of companies claiming the R&D tax
offset; the way the incentive is claimed; and the administration of the R&D
tax incentive would not be changed by the bill.[14]
2.18
Research Australia noted that the R&D tax offset provides:
...an incentive for innovative companies to spend money on
R&D in areas they determine, without the Government mandating what areas
the R&D should apply to or 'picking winners'.[15]
Policy certainty
2.19
Innovation Australia noted the need for policy stability and certainty,
as research which results in the development of new technologies and
breakthrough advances generally requires longer term investments.[16]
2.20
AusBiotech submitted that the 'constant threats and tweaks to the
R&D Tax Incentive are unsettling for business and undermine business and
investor confidence at a time Australia can least afford it'.[17]
They explained:
The negative impact that uncertainty of funding support has
on product development/innovation companies is destabilising and the
Government's program changes cause one of the greatest costs, in practical terms.
As well as making it more difficult to attract investment, uncertainty strikes
companies in two ways: firstly companies are not sure whether the measures they
have put in place, the deals they have struck and the investments made are
going to receive the benefit(s) the Government previously pledged; and
secondly, those that have not made commitments yet are sure to hesitate and
wait for a more stable environment.[18]
2.21
AusBiotech also advised that they have received feedback from overseas
investors that they 'intended to invest in Australian innovation but saw the
regular changes to policy as discouraging risk'.[19]
Link to the company tax rate
reduction
2.22
Innovation Australia observed that the 1.5 per cent reduction in the
company tax rate is not scheduled to commence until 1 July 2015, while the bill
proposes to reduce the rate of the R&D tax offset from 1 July 2014. This will
have the effect of creating a short term reduction in the R&D tax offset
for the 2014–15 financial year.[20]
2.23
Innovation Australia suggested that, in order to eliminate the
uncertainty created by the short term reduction in the R&D tax offset, the
commencement date for the reduction in the rate of the R&D tax offset be
postponed until at least 2015, when the lower company tax rate comes into effect.[21]
2.24
Ernst & Young raised similar concerns in its submission. Ernst &
Young also expressed concern that there was no guarantee that the company tax
rate reduction would be passed into law at the proposed time. As such, if any
delays or changes were to occur this would prolong the reduction in the net
benefit for R&D entities.
Ernst & Young raised concerns that 'this type of inconsistency can
discourage R&D investment by both small and large companies within
Australia'.[22]
2.25
Research Australia also expressed concerns about the potential for
delays in the implementation of the reduction in the company tax rate.[23]
2.26
PricewaterhouseCoopers noted that one of the reasons for the 2011
decision to shift from an R&D tax concession to a tax credit regime was to
ensure that any revision to the corporate tax rate did not affect the
incentive.[24]
2.27
The BioMelbourne Network also advocated delaying the changes to the
R&D tax incentive until the reduction in the company tax rate was enacted.
In addition, the BioMelbourne Network recommended that the R&D tax
incentive be maintained at 45 per cent for companies in areas of
'identified comparative and competitive advantage, such as medical technology
and pharmaceuticals'.[25]
Companies permanently impacted by
the rate reduction
2.28
PricewaterhouseCoopers noted that for some companies the negative impact
of the proposed changes would not be limited to the 2014–15 financial year. Instead,
the rate reduction would effect them on a permanent basis. PricewaterhouseCoopers
explained that at least two significant sets of companies would permanently
sustain the full 1.5 per cent rate reduction. These companies are:
-
companies with more than $5 million in taxable income, and
-
small and medium enterprises (SMEs) and startups with carry
forward income tax losses.[26]
Companies with more than $5 million
in taxable income
2.29
PricewaterhouseCoopers noted that companies with more than $5 million in
taxable income will be required pay 1.5 per cent in tax upon the introduction
of the government's Paid Parental Leave Scheme. For these companies, the 1.5
per cent corporate tax cut will be effectively neutralised by the introduction
of a 1.5 per cent levy linked to the Paid Parental Leave Scheme.
PricewaterhouseCoopers noted that as such the R&D tax offset rate reduction
would be a permanent reduction for these companies.[27]
2.30
Research Australia raised similar concerns, noting that the only
companies that may not be adversely affected by the change in the R&D tax
offset would be companies with an annual turnover in excess of $20 million that
are not liable for the Paid Parental Leave levy.[28]
SMEs and startups in a tax loss
position
2.31
Innovation Australia noted in its submission that SMEs with turnover
below $20 million where the offset is in excess of a company's income tax
liability would be adversely affected beyond the 2014–15 financial year.
Innovation Australia stated:
This will adversely impact these firms' cash flows and could
result in a reduction in their R&D activity. In the experience of
Innovation Australia, cash flows are important to such entities as they tend to
be heavily constrained while devoting all their resources to developing their
innovations.[29]
2.32
Research Australia submitted that the most significant component of the
R&D tax incentive is the refundable R&D tax offset, which is only
available to smaller companies with an annual turnover of less than $20
million. Research Australia noted that these entities had received $4.96
billion in support for R&D from 2011–12 to 2013–14. In comparison, over the
same period the non-refundable R&D tax offset provided $2.53 billion in
support to companies with annual turnover of more than $20 million.[30]
2.33
Research Australia noted that the reason for the inclusion of the
refundable component in the R&D tax incentive is that many smaller
companies operate at a loss for many years as they develop products for market,
and therefore pay little or no income tax. Research Australia noted:
In this situation, the reduction in the rate of the R&D
tax incentive is not 'revenue neutral', and in fact results in a direct
reduction in the support provided to small innovative companies in their early
stages when [they] need it most.[31]
2.34
The Chief Scientist for South Australia did not support the changes to
the R&D tax offset. The Chief Scientist submitted that:
South Australia is particularly vulnerable to any such
reduction. As an SME-dominated state facing enormous challenges with the loss
of the automobile industry, and potentially also defence manufacturing, we
cannot afford to put further pressure on our innovative SMEs.[32]
2.35
The BioMelbourne Network expressed concern that the proposed amendment
would have a disproportionate impact on the smallest and most vulnerable
companies, as the R&D tax incentive is:
...particularly critical for start-ups, spin-outs and SMEs who
are in tax loss, as the cash refund has allowed these entrepreneurial
enterprises to maintain consistent R&D programs for longer.[33]
2.36
AusBiotech expressed a similar concern that the changes will
'discriminate against small start-up biotechnology and other R&D-based
companies'.[34]
2.37
Innovation Australia did not advocate for a different rate to apply to
these firms. However, it submitted that the adverse impact on them should be
noted, 'especially as these are likely to be the companies with the highest
growth and employment prospects in the future'.[35]
Subdivisions 355-G and 355-H of the
ITAA 1997
2.38
In its submission, BDO Australia provided an explanation of subdivisions
355-G and 355-H of the ITAA 1997. It noted:
Subdivision 355-G operates to 'clawback' the incentive
through an increase in tax payable where a Government grant has been received.
Subdivision 355-H makes an adjustment to assessable income to 'clawback' the
incentive received on feedstock inputs where a company sells or otherwise
applies to its own use a marketable product it has created. In effect, these
provisions are designed to clawback the 10% incentive component afforded under
the current 40% non-refundable tax offset.
2.39
In relation to subdivisions 355-G and 355-H of the ITAA 1997, the Explanatory
Memorandum states:
For simplicity, no change has been made to the provisions
providing for the adjustment of tax benefits in respect of eligible research
and development expenditure, where the entity obtains a recoupment for the
expenditure or sells feedstock to which the expenditure relates. Following the
proposed reduction in the company tax rate, the tax outcomes for entities to
which these provisions apply will be largely the same as before these
amendments.[36]
2.40
BDO Australia expressed concern that the bill does not make any
provision for consequential amendments to subdivisions 355-G and 355-H of the
ITAA 1997, nor Section 12B of the Income Tax Rates Act 1986, which
establishes the rate of extra income tax for recoupments of R&D activities,
for the period before the corporate tax rate is reduced.[37]
2.41
BDO Australia noted that the Explanatory Memorandum indicated that the reason
no change had been made to these provisions was 'for simplicity'. However, BDO Australia
pointed out that:
...reducing the incentive component to 8.5% and not amending
these provisions creates an absurd situation where companies may in fact be
penalised for undertaking eligible R&D activities.[38]
2.42
With regard to subdivision 355-G relating to income tax recoupments of
R&D activities, Ernst & Young expressed concern about the decision not
to amend this rate so that it was in line with the reduction in the rate of the
R&D tax offset. Ernst & Young's submission stated:
We are not aware of any intention in the Tax and Super Laws
Amendment Bill to amend or update this 10% rate. This suggests that an
unintended consequence of the reduction of the R&D tax offset rates is a
negative 1.5% outcome for R&D entities that access the 38.5% non-refundable
R&D offset and also obtain a recoupment from government for the
expenditure. In this scenario the entity would potentially be facing 10%
recoupment tax but only receive 8.5% net R&D benefit.[39]
2.43
KPMG raised similar concerns, noting:
Each of these adjustments can also be impacted by the timing
of the expenditure compared with the timing of the adjustment as these can
occur in different income years. Given this increased level of complexity, the
most sensible approach would be to make any reduction to the R&D offset
rate at the same time as the reduction in the corporate tax rate. This would
potentially also avoid the need for further amendments to these adjustments
when the corporate tax rate is reduced.[40]
2.44
Ernst & Young recommended that, if it is not possible to align the
changes to the R&D incentive and company tax rate, that Section 12B of the Income
Tax Rates Act 1986, which establishes the rate of extra income tax for
recoupments of R&D activities, be amended to reflect the proposed change in
the R&D offset rates.[41]
Taxation White Paper
2.45
A number of submitters, including Reproductive Health Science, Redarc
Electronics, the Australian Wine Research Institute, and De Bruin Engineering
noted that the proposed reduction in the R&D tax offset immediately
precedes the tax white paper. They expressed the view that this serves to
'generate unwarranted confusion, uncertainty and unpredictability in the
government's approach to taxation'.[42]
2.46
Innovation Australia advised that as part of the forthcoming taxation
white paper, it anticipates a review of the performance of the R&D tax
incentive program. It explained:
Anticipation of the review and subsequent changes is creating
uncertainty among industry stakeholders and could result in reduced expenditure
or postponement of R&D projects. This is another reason for limiting the
changes being made to this program, at least by postponing the proposed
reduction in rate of the R&D Incentive until 1 July 2015.[43]
Committee View on Schedule 3
2.47
The committee acknowledges that the submissions raised a number concerns
regarding the reduction in the rate of the R&D tax offset and the need for
policy certainty. The committee considers that the upcoming taxation white
paper will provide a useful opportunity for wide consultation to be undertaken
relating to R&D and government incentives to encourage R&D. However,
the future scheduled reviews do not mean that the R&D tax incentive cannot
be amended in the meantime if necessary.
2.48
The committee draws the government's attention to the concerns raised by
a number of submitters, including Innovation Australia, regarding the
discrepancy between the commencement dates for the reduction in the rate of the
R&D tax offset (1 July 2014) and the proposed company tax rate cut (1 July
2015).
2.49
The committee notes however that the reduction in the rate of the
R&D tax offset is a savings measure. This measure will provide a gain to
the Budget of $620 million in fiscal balance terms over the forward estimates
period. In underlying cash terms this is a gain to the Budget of $550 million
over the forward estimates period.
Recommendation 1
2.50
The committee recommends that the Senate pass the bill.
Senator Sean
Edwards
Chair
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page