Chapter 4
Key issues
4.1
The previous chapter considered evidence the committee received about
the challenges facing many communities in regional Australia. While there were
differing views on the seriousness and extent of the rural debt and access to
finance, there is no doubt a major problem exists in rural Australia that requires
government intervention. In this chapter, the committee considers whether the
proposed ARDB is the most appropriate solution to the current debt situation in
rural Australia and, longer term, to the ability of farmers to access finance
that would allow them to withstand poor seasons. As part of its consideration,
the committee also looks at the detail contained in the bill on the proposed
ARDB, the general understanding of how the proposed ARDB would work, how the
ARDB would fit within the RBA and the implications for the RBA's role as a
central bank.
The ARDB and the RBA's 'rural reconstruction and development policy'
4.2
As noted in Chapter 2, the ARDB would be 'a specific entity tasked with
examining, reconstructing and improving the financial status of the Australian
agricultural sector and its associated industries and infrastructures'. The
bill seeks to empower the ARDB to do this by determining and giving effect to
the RBA's 'rural reconstruction and development policy'.[1]
4.3
For many submitters, the establishment of the ARDB would alleviate the
distress suffered by farmers struggling to keep their business viable. The
first priority would be to address crippling debt and stabilise the sector.[2]
Some saw the current debt burden as 'a chronic problem' and attributed the
situation to 'overlending and overborrowing' that warranted 'an adjustment'.[3]
For example, Mr Walton argued that the situation in rural Australia was a
serious problem, which needed to be rectified and could not be stabilised by
holding it on course. According to Mr Walton an important early-stage action
was reconstruction—"'fix the problem, stop it in its tracks, and get it
sorted"; then we need to fix the problem'.[4]
One of the principal problems stemmed from the falling capital values as Mr Rowell
Walton explained:
...when I wrote all my loans, and when everybody else who is in
trouble wrote their loans, it was based on net equity. Net equity could include
profit, but it did not necessarily include profit. A lot of the net equity was
on the back of capital growth.
...
So what we have now is a system where capital values are
falling and nobody knows where the bottom is.[5]
4.4
Mr Walton noted further that he knew of operators who had not missed a
solitary payment but their loan to value ratios (LVRs) got 'out of whack' and they
were called in by the lender for discussions.[6]
In his view:
The operation of the ARDB will remove the severe pain, the write-downs
will be less than otherwise and a modicum of confidence will begin to establish
itself in the various areas most disrupted, dignity will return to the
adjustment process, losses limited, viability and sustainability enhanced.[7]
4.5
Mr Rees similarly explained the devaluation of assets:
When the capital markets started to look closely at the
quality of the assets that were being presented, they decided some were toxic
and some were okay. They did not want the toxic ones. Those ones became
devalued in the eyes of the capital markets, and that flowed back to the real
asset, which was the farm—rural lending. So farm values collapsed. And they are
down about 40 per cent.[8]
4.6
According to Mr Rees a recent sale in the Condamine district was sold
for $680 an acre, which a few years ago could have commanded between $1,000 to
$1,200 an acre. He noted that people who had been secure and solvent were
suddenly faced with that sale and questions asked about their solvency and
their level of debt. He referred to a young man from Western Australia who had
the same problem—had met all his payments and had not had a problem:
The bank called in and started to ask questions about his
solvency because the rural lands in that area had been devalued and his level
of debt suddenly posed him a risk under these new valuations.[9]
4.7
Dr McGovern agreed with this view that 'even farms that meet all
commitments can be caught as equity (or LVRs) fall across a sector'.[10]
In his words, the main trouble was:
...you have lots of farmers who are up for sale and asset
prices are still falling. If we look at where they have fallen, 50 per cent
would be an average across a number of areas—some are up higher, some are less,
some are lucky...Now can you imagine what that does to your LVRs—it completely
stuffs up the security of the banks. It then imperils the banks themselves
because on their own assets they have problems.[11]
4.8
With assets declining in value, Dr McGovern explained further that the
banks have 'covenants which they have to enforce...We have a system which is
going to drive this crisis until something effective changes'.[12]
According to Dr McGovern, the source of the debt problem stemmed from the early
2000s when lending from about 2003 on was suspect, because of the way lending
was structured—'the inferior products now in today's market'.[13]
In his assessment, the ARDB would provide a way to actually tackle this problem
of inappropriately issued funds.[14]
4.9
The Queensland Murray-Darling Committee (QMDC) advised that it 'supports
the intent' of the bill 'based on the recognition that some sections of the
agricultural industry are currently operating on an unsustainable basis':
In QMDC's opinion, these sectors are facing a systemic
failure. QMDC therefore supports the reconstruction of the industry by
collaboration with the industry, government, [natural resource management]
bodies and other key stakeholders.[15]
4.10
Wayne and Sandra Birchmore believed that the proposed ARDB was the only
way to stabilise the situation, 'while policies are formulated &
implemented to enable a return to profitability'. They explained:
Current returns can no longer sustain the industry &
without some government intervention, it will surely collapse, with massive
repercussions for all the businesses that depend on it. The current drought is
simply the final nail in the coffin, following years of poor returns
exacerbated by the live cattle export ban imposed by the Federal Labor
Government. While we all pray for rain to save our cattle, if returns do not
improve, there will be no saving of the northern cattle industry.[16]
4.11
Another farmer burdened with debt, Mr Robert Walton, stated that should
the ARDB get started, 'we would be adjusted to make a profit again'.[17]
And yet another informed the committee that the ARDB would make a huge
difference to his business. He stated, 'without it I fear we will be caught in
a downward spiral unable to break out of debt that is crippling us'.[18]
Mr Pete Mailler, a grain and cattle farmer, saw the establishment of the ARDB
as 'a key opportunity to provide a relatively independent stabilising agent in
the current financial turmoil in the agricultural sector'.[19]
4.12
While the purpose of the bill garnered strong support, the actual
mechanics of how the ARDB would achieve this objective of debt relief was
unclear, prompting a number of submitters to speculate on how the ARDB would
carry out its functions. Most submitters, however, as noted earlier, did not
question the details of how the ARDB would perform its tasks and were prepared
to endorse the intention of the proposed legislation without requiring detail
on its implementation. Mr Rowell Walton, however, provided the following
explanation on the proposed ARDB's operation:
The Board would receive applications from potential customers
for acceptance into the facilities of the reconstruction board, by way of an
application form signed off by the financial advisor, accountant or banker of
the customer. It will be necessary to fit the guidelines set by the board to be
accepted as a client.
If the customer is in default with its funder a conversation
will be had between the banker or his representative and the ARDB as to a
buyout of the mortgage, a discount may apply in the event there is no
expectation of full recoupment of the outstanding funds. However it should be
clear that the likely settlement would be greater than achievable through the
regular sell down process. The result that the bank will have its capital loss
minimised, while the customer will be far more able to repay the new mortgage
at appropriately priced money, commensurate with anticipated and historically
received profits.
Of upmost importance is the agreement on a viable or
sustainable level of debt, the ARDB will not under any circumstances accept a
level of debt which may make a customer unviable or unsustainable.[20]
4.13
Mr Rees was another proponent of the ARDB who offered an explanation on
how the ARDB would work in practice. He envisaged that the ARDB would purchase
low quality financial assets from private sector financial institutions at a
current market valuation:
The current market valuation effectively provides what is
commonly called a 'haircut' to the nominal value of the mortgages issued in
more robust times. The 'haircut', provides debt relief to the mortgagor and
enhances credit worthiness. The haircut also becomes the penalty of
shareholders and their financial institutions that practised imprudent rural
lending.
Once ownership of the mortgage is transferred from the
financial institution to the public entity, the once low quality asset/mortgage
takes on the characteristic of a public security. As such, it can form the
basis of an asset pool from which derivative securities can be sold into the
capital market thereby generating a self-funding program. It is the process of
ownership transfer from the retail financier to the public entity where asset
enhancement occurs as the low quality asset transforms to a higher quality
public sector asset. Interest rates on the mortgage should then reflect the
interest rates of government paper as opposed to commercial penalty rates of
the private sector.[21]
4.14
As noted in the quote, Mr Rees argued that the ARDB's activities could
become self-funding through the sale of derivatives backed by the pool of
assets the ARDB would acquire. Mr Rees also envisaged that the ARDB
would provide development finance.[22]
4.15
While the proponents of the ARDB argued that the immediate task facing
the proposed new RBA Board was to rectify the debt burden, they also recognised
the need for the board to take on the longer term role of a development bank.
Longer term—Reserve Bank as lender
4.16
Many individuals pointed to the need for long-term adjustments to
support their argument that some form of government intervention was warranted.
For example, the Boothulla Pastoral Company argued that the ARDB was required
not only to solve the current problem but 'to ensure long term stability'.[23]
Mr Rees argued that agriculture was 'an industry facing imperfect markets'
with 'farm businesses operating under decreasing returns to scale'. Mr Rees
concluded:
Decreasing returns to scale imply that an optimum production
level will be reached beyond which profit levels decline until continued
production generates losses. It follows that rural adjustment policy under a
deregulated industry structure, could never be successful over the long term
under decreasing returns to scale and the withdrawal of government
intervention.[24]
4.17
Dr McGovern argued that the 'systemic failures' in the financing of
Australian agriculture can only be rectified by 'prudent government
intervention':
Structural defects, market failures and policy oversights
have impoverished rural Australia needlessly. Without reserves or realistic possibilities
of building them, agricultural enterprises will remain at the mercy of the
seasons, speculations and imperfect markets.[25]
4.18
In his view, the Reserve Bank has the ability to change the nature of
products. Mr Rowell Walton suggested that the appropriate response was to have
'a public institution that provides competitive finance and provides effective
arrangements so that the other banks need necessarily to compete with better
arrangements'.[26]
Dr McGovern explained that the ARDB would provide an institutional
rejuvenation. He stated:
If we look at what happened once upon a time, the RBA used to
arrange export funding. From reading the RBA's submission, there seems to be
almost an assumption we are going back to that sort of thing, but no; we are
not. We are basically talking about the Reserve Bank acting as a lender of last
resort in its proper, full sense, not as a party which favours a banking
crisis. It should favour the welfare of the Australian people and its
prosperity; that is in its charter. It should look at this across the whole
financial arrangement so it can bring balance to the equation, and that is the
sort of thing that I cannot do—a commercial banker cannot do—and the government
is not well placed to do it. But the charter responsibility of the Reserve Bank
is to do exactly those sorts of things, and it has not been doing it.[27]
4.19
It should be noted, as mentioned in chapter 2, the RBA is chartered with
ensuring that its statutory powers are exercised in a manner as will best
contribute to, inter alia, the economic prosperity and welfare of the people of
Australia.[28]
4.20
According to Dr McGovern:
The problem with the farm loan arrangement is that government
is basically getting funds at retail rates to cover a debt, so it is actually
acting a bit like a banker through its intermediary like QRAA. It would be far
better, and this is the whole point of the ARDB, to get wholesale funds through
a bank—and the Reserve Bank is a bank, even though it needs a few bankers in
there—and to actually operate it as a financial arrangement separate from the
Commonwealth budget.[29]
4.21
Mr Pete Mailler considered it would be essential for the ARDB to provide
'structural support' that is 'long term and focussed on chronic issues around
viability and economic resilience'. Mr Mailler added that effective structural
support often mitigated the need for short term direct support such as disaster
relief.[30]
He concluded:
...it is imperative that ARDB does not drift into welfare
provision and/or dealing with treating short term symptoms in lieu of the
longer term and more structural issues that underpin the sector.[31]
4.22
The Government of South Australia expressed support for the
proposed ARDB, although it emphasised that the ARDB should not duplicate
existing programs and services.[32]
AgForce Queensland similarly observed there was a need to avoid 'duplication
and inconsistent policy' after it noted that the National Rural Advisory
Council already existed and several other government agencies collected rural
data. However, AgForce informed the committee of its 'in principle and
qualified support' for a board within the RBA focused on rural policy. It
suggested that such a board would assist in highlighting issues affecting the
agricultural sector within broader RBA policy settings.[33]
4.23
Furthermore, a number of witnesses referred to overseas practices
whereby some countries subsidise agriculture. Dr McGovern thought that there
was an average of three or four development banks per nation—but Australia had
none. In his view, the ARDB could include a development bank and that was 'the
way you would manage the banking in a responsible way—as a development bank in
its own right'.[34]
Concerns regarding the bill in its
current form or opposition to the bill
4.24
The submitters unconvinced of the merits of establishing the ARDB
included the Australian Bankers' Association (ABA), which questioned the need
for an ARDB. The ABA took the view that Australia did not have 'a national or
even widespread debt crisis and saw no need for the proposed ARDB.[35]
Furthermore, the ABA:
-
maintained that the Rural Adjustment Act 1992 currently
existed for the specific purposes of enabling the Australian Government to
provide directly or indirectly, grants and loans to farmers, for purposes
related to rural adjustment.[36]
-
was uncertain from commentary from the proponents of the Bill
whether the purpose of the Board was for dealing with rural assistance issues
in the rural sector today or providing a vision, direction and helping with
policy on the future of the sector.[37]
-
noted that while the bill did not identify a policy to be implemented,
proponents had advocated that the proposed Board would implement a policy that
aims to reduce the debt levels of farmers to sustainable levels, at subsidised
interest rates—the ABA thought there appeared to be an expectation that banks
would forgo debt owing to them, on problem loans, to a level that would achieve
this.[38]
If that were the expectation, the ABA suggested there were a number of
problems, including that lending to farmers was generally well secured and a
bank would be unlikely to forgo debt when there was security available to cover
the debt owing.[39]
-
suggested that if this requirement to forgo debt were to become a
practice then it would 'likely be factored into the pricing of debt, potentially
affecting all producers irrespective of the resilience and management
capability within their operations. It would be difficult to avoid penalising
the better operators at the expense of those struggling to run viable
businesses'.[40]
-
indicated that to avoid consequences such as the banks having to
forgo debt and hence penalising the better operators at the expense of those
struggling to run viable businesses, 'the proposed Board would have to buy out
the debt from the bank, in effect refinancing the customer at a lower level of
debt'. In doing so, the Board would take a loss upfront in providing the
refinance. In addition to this loss, the Board would also incur costs relating
to the raising of funds and meeting prudential capital and loss requirements. Assuming
that the interest rates charged by the Board were subsidised, this policy
appeared to be unsustainable.[41]
4.25
Indeed one of ABA's principal concerns was that the ARDB would force the
banks to write off debt. Thus, according to Mr Münchenberg,
'we have to assume that the risk of all customers has increased, and that is
potentially going to increase the capital that we have to carry for those
loans'.[42]
He explained in detail:
...for every loan that we write in Australia to any farmer we
will have to factor in the risk that at some point in the life of that loan,
whether it is in a year, five years or 15 years, that farmer may get into a
situation such that, without the agreement of the bank, the board will come in
and force us to write down 25 per cent of that loan. So, we would have to
factor that in to every loan we write. There is no other way of doing it. If we
could predict in advance which customers are going to go bad, we would be
making even more profits.[43]
4.26
Mr Münchenberg
emphasised his view that the proposed legislation as it currently stood was
'incredibly vague as to what it does, so we can only take the evidence that is
available to us'.[44]
4.27
Treasury was not in favour of the bill. As the proposed ARDB would have
'similar characteristics to a state‑owned bank', Treasury argued that the
proposal raised 'substantial concerns for businesses, individuals and the
government':
Direct lending via a government-owned Development Board is
likely to reduce competition and innovation across the economy by crowding out
private providers of credit.[45]
4.28
According to Treasury, other jurisdictions with state‑owned banks
generally find the presence of such banks 'hampers economic growth and distorts
the financial system'.[46]
Treasury added in order to achieve ARDB's objectives, the RBA would be involved
in providing financial assistance to a wide range of businesses facing
financial difficulty. It suggested that:
Doing so would likely result in the RBA making large losses
on the credit it provides, which could ultimately have negative impacts on
government's fiscal position.[47]
4.29
Furthermore, Treasury suggested that the proposal placed 'the prospect
of receiving dividends from the RBA at jeopardy'.[48]
Noting that the proposed ARDB would have the task of 'reducing or eliminating
the debilitating impact of financial arrangements', Treasury then indicated
that the effect of this proposal depended on how the Board would achieve this
objective. It surmised:
If financial institutions are required to cancel loans and
incur a loss, financial institutions will be unwilling to lend to businesses in
the scope of the proposed board’s remit. This could result in reduced
competition in credit provision and encourage industries to become dependent on
the government for finance.
If the RBA cancels loans and compensates lenders to ensure
there is no loss to financial institutions, then lenders could be encouraged to
relax lending standards and borrowers would be encouraged to take on excessive
debt.[49]
4.30
According to Treasury:
-
an extension of credit to sectors that are indebted and poorly
performing is likely to increase that sector's leverage without any necessary
improvements in their operation and business conditions; and
-
the misallocation of capital directs funding away from other more
sustainable businesses, even within the agriculture sector, that have better
prospects for contributing to Australia's long-term economic growth.[50]
4.31
The RBA also found flaws with the proposed ARDB. In its submission, the
RBA stated that the addition of a third Board to the RBA's governance structure
would risk blurring responsibilities and creating confusion over the RBA's
policy objectives.[51]
Furthermore, the RBA did 'not possess the requisite expertise in regular
commercial lending'.[52]
Overall, the RBA concluded that Australia has a mature financial system and
capital markets and that the Australian banking system had:
...sufficient capacity and expertise to service the financing
needs of rural producers at a price that is appropriately adjusted for the
risks that the lenders assume. Thus, the RBA's assessment is that...a commercial
lending function is not appropriate for a central bank...The private financial
system can satisfy the normal commercial demand for finance by the rural
sector, and the provision of finance from this source dwarfs any public
provision under current arrangements.[53]
4.32
The RBA advised the committee that it already monitors conditions and
developments in the rural sector as part of its analysis of economic trends. The
RBA argued, however, that any official financial support for a particular
industry should be part of the government's budget process:
To the extent that there is a market failure, or that
subsidies are deemed to be appropriate, or that there is a case for financing
at concessional rates for a particular purpose, the RBA respectfully submits
that best practice would be for these issues to be addressed through an
appropriately resourced and governed process, and transparently costed as part
of the Commonwealth Budget. This promotes effectiveness, equity and
accountability.[54]
4.33
Mr Christopher Aylmer, RBA, restated the RBA's position that if there
were market failure or a need for a subsidy or concession that such measures
should be taken through the appropriate vehicle, which was the Commonwealth
budget.[55]
4.34
The Western Australian (WA) Government did not support the bill. In
its submission, the WA Government argued that establishing the RBA as a lender
of last resort 'with limited grounds for prudent economic decisions' would
be inconsistent with policies it has pursued and an intergovernmental agreement
on national drought program reform agreed to by all states in May 2013. Furthermore,
it advised that in 2011 it decided not to provide a loan scheme where it would
act as a lender of last resort. The reasons for this decision followed concerns
that:
-
government 'would be required to assume risk that commercial
lenders have rejected, with financiers referring risky clients so as to both
limit their own exposure and avoid adverse publicity of debt recovery';
-
the 'level of arrears and bad debts are often substantial and can
be exacerbated if future seasons are also adverse'; and
-
lender of last-resort schemes 'are distortionary and encourage
unviable activity, artificially holding up land prices and delaying orderly
restructure and adjustment'.[56]
4.35
WAFarmers stated its belief that the proposed legislation in its
entirety was not the solution, 'but only a short-term safety-net to a greater,
more complex issue around insufficient profitability within the industry'.[57]
4.36
The NFF was of the view that there was 'an ongoing need to investigate
options for the farm sector to continue to access affordable capital, improve
global competitiveness and innovation'. It suggested that transparency in
the banking sector, tax-based mechanisms for investing in regional Australia,
and education and awareness among farmers of risk‑management tools should
be considered.[58]
Moreover, the NFF advised that it had 'only an equivocal and broad
understanding' of the implications of establishing an ARDB and argued that the
proposal:
...requires considerable investigation and analysis
particularly in relation to the impact any such entity might have on the
broader financial markets, farm sector financial instruments and risk management
strategies.[59]
4.37
Farmers NSW also highlighted the need for the role of the ARDB to be
'publically clear and well understood to avoid confusion'. For example, it
stated that it was unclear how the ARDB would interact with the broader
agricultural policy areas that affect the profitability of the industry and
what consultative process and communication would operate between the board and
the general public.[60]
4.38
The Australian Dairy Farmers similarly indicated that the bill and
Explanatory Memorandum required more detail on the exact nature of the
financial structures that would be used to achieve the bill's aims.[61]
It also suggested that ABARES and the Australian Farm Institute could undertake
the facilitative task to be assigned to the proposed ARDB.[62]
4.39
Finally, the recent Financial System Inquiry report similarly noted the
call on government to establish a government-owned bank to direct funding to
particular causes, such as rural business. It stated clearly that it did not
support this approach, indicating that 'to maximise the efficiency of the
financial system, policy makers should not set out to favour one particular
funding destination over another'.[63]
4.40
As noted above a number of submitters saw no need for the proposed ARDB
and referred to existing measures designed to assist farmers manage their debt
and to gain access to necessary funding to develop their business. In the
following section, the committee considers views on the adequacy of
Commonwealth assistance to the rural sector.
Current rural assistance and
development policies
4.41
The RBA noted that various government agencies 'provide eligible farmers
with access to a range of assistance packages, including concessional loans for
productivity enhancements and disaster recovery'. On 30 June 2013, according to
the RBA, lending by government agencies amounted to around $2.2 billion'.[64]
4.42
A useful starting point when considering how government rural assistance
and development policies have evolved is the 1992 National Drought Policy (NDP)
agreed to by Commonwealth and state ministers. The objectives of the NDP were
to:
-
encourage primary producers and other sections of rural Australia
to adopt self-reliant approaches to managing climatic variability;
-
maintain and protect Australia's agricultural and environmental
resource base during periods of extreme climate stress; and
-
ensure early recovery of agricultural and rural industries,
consistent with long‑term sustainable levels.[65]
4.43
The NDP stated that:
During severe downturns, governments will act to preserve the
social and physical resource base of rural Australia, and will provide
adjustment assistance in the recovery phase. Support will be available to those
with sound prospects who are temporarily in financial difficulty.[66]
4.44
In 2008, a national review of drought policy was undertaken[67]
and through the Council of Australian Governments' Standing Council on Primary
Industries, work on a new National Drought Policy commenced.[68]
In 2013, the Intergovernmental Agreement on National Drought Program Reform
was signed.[69]
Under the agreement, the Commonwealth's role was described in the following
terms:
The
Commonwealth is responsible for:
- funding and delivering a time-limited farm household
support payment based on individual need, including
-
reciprocal obligations aimed at
driving behavioural change
-
case management to support
reciprocal obligations
- providing continued access to primary producer
taxation concessions that support farmer risk management, including the [Farm
Management Deposits] Scheme
- delivering Commonwealth programs under this agreement
- developing a Commonwealth implementation plan in
consultation with the states and territories
- monitoring and assessing the delivery and performance
of Commonwealth programs under this agreement
- reporting on the delivery of Commonwealth programs and
the contribution of these programs to the achievement of outcomes as set out in
this agreement.[70]
4.45
The Department of Agriculture has published the following advice about
changes to drought assistance that commenced from 1 July 2014:
The new approach, which will replace the existing Exceptional
Circumstances arrangements, will help farmers prepare for and manage the
effects of drought and other challenges, rather than waiting until they are in
crisis to offer assistance, as well as supporting viable farms during prolonged
or severe droughts. It is designed to deliver a more productive agriculture
sector by helping farm businesses to make informed decisions and capture future
opportunities.[71]
4.46
In response to the prolonged drought affecting Queensland and
New South Wales, on 26 February 2014[72]
the Australian government announced additional assistance to support farming
families, farm businesses and rural communities.[73]
In particular, the government supplemented the existing Farm Finance program
with an additional $280 million for concessional loans to eligible drought‑affected
farm businesses. The loans could be used for debt restructuring, operating
expenses and drought recovery activities.[74]
4.47
In addition to the Drought Concessional Loans Scheme and Farm Finance
Concessional Loans Scheme, assistance programs currently available include:
-
the Farm Household Allowance;
-
Farm Management Deposits; and
-
the Rural Finance Counselling Service.[75]
Concessional loans
4.48
The Agricultural Competitiveness Green Paper noted the
government's concern about rural debt levels and the farm debt servicing
difficulties that some farmers were experiencing. In response, according to the
Green Paper, the government has introduced farm finance at concessional
interest rates through the Farm Finance Concessional Loans Scheme to facilitate
the restructuring of debt for long-term viable farms. It explained that under
this scheme, eligible farm businesses could apply 'to refinance up to half of
their existing commercial borrowings in the form of a loan with a reduced
interest, or concessional, rate for a maximum of five years'.[76]
4.49
For example, the Drought Recovery Concessional Loans Scheme recently
opened in Queensland and New South Wales to provide financial assistance to farm
business to help businesses recover from unprecedented drought conditions.[77]
This loan scheme together with two other concessional loan packages—the farm
finance and the drought concessional loans—provide funding of $700 million for
farmers to restructure their debt or undertake productivity enhancements'.[78]
Ms Anna Willcock, Department of Agriculture, informed the committee of the
following current variable interest rates:
-
Farm Finance Concessional Loan Scheme 4.34 per
cent;
-
Drought Concessional Loan Scheme 3.84
per cent; and
-
Drought Recovery Concessional Loan Scheme 3.21 per
cent.[79]
4.50
While recognising the value of assistance through additional government
funding, such as concessional loans, a number of witnesses thought that the
loans were 'too slow and too small and some of them were to be repaid in too
short a time'.[80]
Dr McGovern was of the view that the Rural Adjustment Act 1992 was
expensive and limited compared to other measures that Australia could adopt. In
his words, 'it may have been relevant in 1992 but not anymore'.[81]
One farmer with no debt, but no income for multiple years because of drought,
argued that recent government policies such as the exceptional circumstances
program were not effective:
Historically we have been drought declared a number of times
and have received minimal assistance due to the structure of drought relief and
exceptional circumstances (EC). My observations of EC in the past, especially
the interest subsidy, is that it hasn't helped many genuine farmers who have
gotten into difficulty due to drought. It has mainly gone to those who have
structured it into their business plans as a safety net or simply used the
provisions to borrow more heavily than otherwise would have been prudent. These
businesses, often quite large ones, who can attract publicity, are usually the
first able to seek assistance. The current call for interest subsidies or the
transfer of debt to the Commonwealth would do little to assist most land
holders without many other issues being considered. In fact this is a type of
smoke screen or shield from the serious underlying problems of sustainability.[82]
4.51
In addition, Mr Rowell Walton suggested that the recent Farm Finance
Package demonstrated that some states 'do not have effective machinery for
delivery; many have lost the ability or simply refuse to participate'.[83]
Alternatives
4.52
When asked about overseas institutions that provide finance to their
rural sector, such as Farm Credits Canada and Farmer Mac in the United States
of America, Mr Nico Padovan, Department of Agriculture, informed the committee
that the department was aware of these models when setting up the concessional
loan and other schemes.[84]
He explained further:
There are key areas of difference, so the work that we do
around things like the Drought Recovery Concessional Loans Scheme, as I
understand it, is unique to the Australian context. They are special-purpose
loans for those in a particular circumstance, whereas farm finance is probably
more akin to the Canadian and US models, where it is a much more generic loan
for debt restructure and productivity enhancement. That is very much by
negotiation with the states in terms of what is available in each of the
states. One of the challenges we have in answering some of your questions is
that the individual agreements we have with the states, the level of admin
costs and some of the other attributes of those loans are tailored to those
particular states.[85]
4.53
The Department of Agricultural provided additional information on Farm
Credit Canada; on the US Farm Credit System (FCS); and the US Federal
Agricultural Mortgage Corporation, commonly known as 'Farmer Mac' which is part
of the FSC. This information is at Appendix 4.
4.54
According to the RBA, the substantial variability of rural debt and
rural asset values across the country and sectors raised the question whether
this was 'a problem for which you would look for an insurance solution'.[86]
Mr Aylmer explained:
It is the volatility in cash flow that is the issue here, and
the way you would normally look at that...'suggests maybe it is an insurance
solution rather than a concessional loan solution.' And then there is the
question: would the private sector actually be prepared to provide that? I do
not know. In risk-adjusted terms, the premiums may well just be so high that
you could not get an effective private solution.[87]
4.55
Treasury indicated that it was aware of new products being available to
the rural sector to manage various risks:
We are aware of multi-peril insurance products and, indeed,
some other innovative forms of lending. There are some new lenders in the
peer-to-peer market that we are aware have started to think about the
agriculture sector. If those innovations moved into the agriculture sector, in
our view that would be a good way to provide different sources of funding and
ways of managing risk.[88]
4.56
Mr Rees also noted the many options available under the WTO Agreement on
Agriculture that allows rural assistance 'lay untapped', including crop
insurance, which, according to Mr Rees, many countries use. He noted
however, that such insurance would have to be subsidised because it was
unprofitable due to the risk level. Mr Rees also mentioned payments that could
be made for 'stewardship of the land'.[89]
Conclusion
4.57
There is no doubt that sectors of Australia's farming communities are
under financial stress and require Commonwealth assistance to help them return
to a sustainable and financially viable position. For many submitters the
proposed ARDB would enable struggling rural communities to build the resilience,
capabilities and financial viability required to sustain profitable farming and
withstand the effects of natural disasters, market failures and inadequate
commercial arrangements. There were others, however, who expressed concerns
that the proposed ARDB was not the appropriate solution.
4.58
One of the principal concerns about the proposed ARDB was the lack of
detail on how it would operate. For example, the NFF had 'only an equivocal and
broad understanding' of the implications of establishing an ARDB and Farmers
NSW spoke of the need for the role of the ARDB to be 'publically clear and well
understood to avoid confusion'. The Australian Dairy Farmers wanted more detail
on the exact nature of the financial structures to be used to achieve the
bill's intentions, while, based on the available evidence, the ABA described
the proposed legislation as 'incredibly vague'.
4.59
This lack of detail and certainty in the drafting of the proposal to
establish an ARDB prompted a number of government agencies, rural organisations
and the ABA to surmise on possible outcomes should the entity be established.
The ABA referred to concerns that banks would be compelled to forgo debt or
that the ARDB would buy out debt from the bank to refinance the customer at a
lower level of debt. Treasury expressed concerns about reduced competition and
innovation by crowding out private providers of credit. It referred to the possibility
of ARDB making large losses on the credit it would provide. Treasury suggested
that if the ARDB cancelled loans and compensated lenders then lenders could be
encouraged to relax lending standards and borrowers to take on excessive debt.
Moreover, the RBA formed the view that the current banking system had 'sufficient
capacity and expertise to service the financing needs of rural producers at a
price that is appropriately adjusted for the risks that the lenders assume'.
4.60
In light of the lack of detail and confusion about how the ARDB would
function in practice and the likely adverse consequences should it be
established, the committee cannot support the passage of the bill.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page