CHAPTER 7

Consideration of the Workplace Relations and Other Legislation Amendment Bill 1996
Table of Contents

CHAPTER 7

Changes to Registered Organisations

Introduction

7.1 The existing industrial relations legislation provides mechanisms to balance the public interest in the orderly conduct of industrial affairs, the protection of individuals and the desire to limit, as much as is possible, the interference of the state in the internal affairs of industrial parties. These goals are as important today as they were when the first conciliation and arbitration Act was passed in 1904.

7.2 Protection for individuals has been provided for by the recognition and encouragement of organisations, which individuals were free to join, and which were recognised and resourced so as to enable the representation of members' interests. Given that the interests of the members of such organisations extended to the wages and conditions of non-members, these organisations were capable of being parties to awards which provided for fair and appropriate wages and conditions for all employees in the industry with which the union was associated regardless of membership.

7.3 To ensure the viability of such organisations to allow them to undertake their representative functions, the system provided a number of protections including exclusive membership coverage, and the ability to access preference.

7.4 The balance for this recognition was, however, the requirement to be accountable to its members and act in a way consistent with the need for orderly industrial relationships. Thus the price for registration was to regulate the rules of associations to ensure membership accountability, such as the requirement for elections, the requirement for proper accounting and the requirement that the unions rules not be oppressive, unreasonable or unjust (section 196(a)). Similarly, registration and recognition were used to impose some order on the industrial parties by reducing the prospect of destructive demarcation disputes and discouraging behaviour inconsistent with the public interest. There is a symmetry of providing a premium on the registration of organisations where that recognition is a means by which the public interest can be preserved.

7.5 Having struck this balance, the system leaves it to the industrial parties to conduct their affairs within these parameters.

The Government's Proposals

7.6 The Workplace Relations Bill will substantially alter the way this balance is struck. The provisions most relevant include:

7.7 For the most part, employer groups welcomed the changes that the Bill will make to the role of registered organisations. They claim that trade unions have frequently used their powers to impede or obstruct the actions of business enterprises, and they see the curtailment of unwarranted union activities as necessary and long over-due. As stated by ACCI, the legislation is an attempt to `bring some balance into a labour relations system which has hitherto been heavily weighted in favour of trade unions'. [2] This would be so particularly for small businesses which may be confronted with having to negotiate against the power of large unions.

7.8 The particular provisions which were suggested would assist business were:

7.9 In general, the unions expressed concern about these changes and there concerns are set out below.

Conveniently Belong and section 118A

7.10 For an association of employees to be registered under the Act, or for a registered organisation to extend its membership coverage, the organisation must demonstrate that there is no other (registered) organisation to which the members could conveniently belong [paragraph 189(1)(j) and section 204]. This reduces the opportunity for organisations which compete for the same coverage as unions that are already registered.

7.11 The Workplace Relations Bill repeals the 'conveniently belong' requirement.

7.12 The Government argues that this is consistent with their view of freedom of association. In their pre-election policy the Government indicated that its principle of freedom of association meant 'the choice to be in a union, the choice of which union and the choice not to be in a union'. In its submission, the Department of Industrial Relations put the position thus:

7.13 Integral to this argument is the view that these provisions give unions a privileged position and that they should be exposed to the rigours of competition.

7.14 The Government's position is supported by some employer organisations such as the ACCI:

7.15 Despite this strong position, the Government has maintained general powers to award a particular union industrial exclusive coverage of a particular class or group of employees (or to order that a union does not have such coverage). The Commission may only make such orders where there is a demarcation dispute and it is satisfied that the conduct of one of the unions is preventing the performance of work or is harming the business of an employer or such consequences having ceased, are likely to recur or are imminent (proposed Subsection 118A(1A)). The matters which the Commission must consider (in deciding whether or not to make such an order) have been significantly amended to include:

7.16 The union movement for its part (except for the SWUA [5]), indicated considerable opposition to the removal of the 'conveniently belong' rule. The ACTU noted in its submission that the `conveniently belong' rule had assisted unions to achieve viability and, more importantly, to lessen demarcation disputes. It argued that these provisions have served the public interest and the interests of industrial parties including employers and employer organisations.

7.17 The unions pointed to an apparent inconsistency between removing 'conveniently belong' provision on the grounds of ensuring freedom of association and maintening the power under section 118A to grant exclusive coverage for a union or unions because of difficulties associated with the exercise of this freedom of association. Thus for instance the Shearers and Rural Workers Union noted:

7.18 In fact, the unions argued that the ability of employers to influence union membership through this mechanism was fundamentally at odds with the freedom of association principle. They said that the combination of the removal of `conveniently belong' provisions and the promotion of disamalgamation may encourage the establishment of many small unions. The ultimate outcome, as argued by the ACTU, will be that `employers will be in a position to encourage the registration of one or more enterprise unions in the workplace, and then seek, through section 118A, the removal of the representational rights of the union with traditional coverage'. [7]

7.19 While some employer groups supported the Government's proposals, some saw that problems may arise as a result of the removal of the 'conveniently belong' provision and the registration of enterprise branches.

7.20 As argued by Mr David Steel of the South Australian Employers Chamber of Commerce and Industry:

7.21 Some employers also envisaged problems arising if the number of unions proliferated beyond a manageable number: As stated by Mr Gerry Pels, Manager, Industrial and Employee Relations, Victorian Automobile Chamber of Commerce (VACC):

7.22 Mr Mark Carter, National Director of the Australian Road Transport industries Organisation, argued against these provisions and asserted that the recent process of amalgamations had benefited industry:

7.23 Similarly, Mr Roger Boland, Director of Industrial Relations with the Metal Trades Industry Association, stated:

7.24 And Mr Nickolas Geronimos, Western Australian Council of Retail Associations stated:

7.25 Other employers suggested that deleterious effects of competition for members among unions may result from these proposals. For instance, Mr Kevin Redfern, Deputy Executive Director of VACC commented:

7.26 The Metal Trades Industry Association, whilst accepting that the abolition of the conveniently belong rule might theoretically lead to greater competition between unions, suggested that the more likely outcome (at least in the short term) was that existing unions would seek to expand their existing coverage into new areas:

7.27 Some employers expressed concern about the link between the conveniently belong rule and the viability of organisations to represent the interests of their members. Thus Mr Redfern made the point that:

7.28 While these comments are raised in the context of employer organisations they have equal application to employee organisations.

Conclusion

7.29 The majority of the Committee recognises that recognition rules for unions represent a balancing of the often competing interests of ensuring appropriate representation for employees and providing for the orderly conduct of industrial relations. We do not accept that best means of ensuring appropriate representation is to provide open slather choice but then have it overridden when it provides some difficulties for employers in the form of demarcation disputes. It seems incongruous that the Government creates the problems of demarcation disputes only to retain section 118A to solve them. The proper balance depends on the relative needs associated with providing choice and the need to avoid the adverse effects of competition. In our view, the existing system represents a better balance of these issues than the Government's proposals. In coming to this view, the following considerations have been taken into account.

7.30 Firstly, there is little, if any, evidence to suggest that the present arrangements have prevented access to appropriately constituted and organised unions. It has been pointed out in evidence to the Committee that the conveniently belong rule has been applied in a way that seeks to ensure the viability of an organisation that can adequately and appropriately represent the interests of employees. Thus Creighton and Stewart note:

7.31 Secondly, to the extent that this rule provides 'protection' in some sense to an existing organisation, this is not a reason in itself to remove that protection. The suggestion that this rule provides a 'privilege' to a special class ignores the fact that often legislative protection is provided to groups or organisations where this provides a public interest. Thus, companies, for instance, are sheltered from being responsible for debts beyond the value of the shares issued. The 'privilege' of limited liability exists because there is a public interest in the encouragement of investment capital that results from capping such liability. The question is not therefore one of unjustified privilege but rather public interest; in this case, the public interest of avoiding the adverse consequences of excessive union competition.

7.32 On this point, the evidence is quite strong. There are considerable harmful effects of such competition. As is indicated above, this extends beyond actual demarcation disputes. The problem associated with dealing with a multiplicity of unions is clearly a considerable one for employers and for the broader public interest in ensuring orderly industrial relations.

7.33 The recognition that comes from 'conveniently belong' is part of the reason why the legislation heavily regulates the internal affairs of these organisations. If there is to be restricted choice in relation to the viability of unions, there is a public interest in ensuring that there are sufficient accountability requirements to ensure that the special position is not abused.

7.34 The majority of the Committee therefore recommends that this proposal (the repeal of paragraph 189(1)(j) and subsection 204(4)) should not be implemented.

7.35 The Australian Democrats Member of the Committee supports these conclusions and recommendations but has made additional recommendations in his Supplementary Report.

7.36 The Government members of the Committee disagree with the conclusion and oppose the recommendation.

Enterprise Unions

7.37 The Bill encourages the registration of small enterprise unions. This will be the effect of provisions that:

7.38 The Government's rationale for this approach is 'so that registered unions can allow members in enterprises, or geographical parts of enterprises, to form enterprise branches with autonomy in matters which affect only the interests of the members at that enterprise or part of an enterprise'. [18]

7.39 According to the ACTU, these moves appear to be designed to encourage the formation of many small, poorly resourced, enterprise-based unions, the viability of which will be highly questionable. [19] This view was supported in a number of submissions which suggested that this was not a desirable outcome either from the employees' or the employers' point of view. [20]

7.40 Thus for instance, The Honourable J M Riordan AO (a former Senior Deputy President of the AIRC) highlighted the beneficial role that professional, well-organised unions play in exercising a moderating influence on the demands of members. A role that could be lost in smaller, enterprise based unions with inexperienced, under-resourced negotiators.

7.41 The possible effect of these provisions on business was also raised by the Victorian Automobile Chamber of Commerce when Mr Kevin Redfern, the Deputy Executive Director, said:

7.42 In addition, it was suggested by the Finance Sector Union that the proposal to reduce registration requirements for unions could lead to the creation of unions which are effectively dominated by the employer. In evidence, the Union described how Metway Bank in Queensland sought to exclude the Australian Bank Employees Union (now a part of the FSU) and the Federated Clerks Union (now the Australian Services Union) by encouraging the development of a separate enterprise based staff association with which the Bank would negotiate over terms and conditions of employment. [23]. A ballot of employees voted in favour of the staff association. However, when the ballot was challenged, the AIRC found that 'the main ingredients of the campaign to gain support for the staff association had been secrecy, surprise and denigration of the [ABEU] union'. [24]

7.43 In conclusion, Deputy President Macbean of the AIRC, found that the Metway Bank staff association had showed 'an appalling lack of competence in approaching the task of properly representing the interests of members to management on an issue of fundamental importance, namely the wages of members'. [25]

7.44 In addition, to these concerns, the evidence suggests that the constitutionality of these provisions is open to question. This is discussed in Chapter 10.

Conclusions

7.45 The Government's proposals on this issue are based on the premise that the present registration requirements prevent, in some unspecified way, a form of collective organisation that may provide for superior results (for members) than that provided by existing union structures. Given that the Government has not indicated what specific benefits it expects will result from these changes, the manifest problems which have been identified lead the majority of the Committee to seriously question their inclusion.

7.46 In relation to a minimum number of members required for registration, the Government seems to accept that there is a need for some minimum level. It fails, however, to demonstrate why the present limit is a problem and how the reduction to 20 will overcome that. If the argument is that is that small enterprise unions are better able to represent their members, there are serious flaws in the reasoning. Firstly, there is no evidence that a union that is exclusively centred on one enterprise can, assuming it is adequately funded, better represent the interests of members than existing structures. There has not been any evidence presented to the majority of the Committee claiming this.

7.47 More importantly however, the minium number of members is crucial to ensuring a viable financial base of an organisation. The ACTU estimates that a membership of 20 will, on present trends, represent an annual income of approximately $4000. It is impossible to believe that an organisation with that level of resources would be able to meet its statutory reporting and accounting requirements, let alone undertake any activities representing the industrial interests of members. The majority of the Committee heard no evidence of an optimal number of members which would reasonably ensure an adequate resource base to allow it to undertake its functions. However, every indication is that it should be a higher rather than a lower minium. Given this, the majority of the Committee recommends that the proposed reduction in this minimum membership requirement be rejected. The extent to which the existing minimum of 100 provides a sufficient base, should be the subject of further investigation.

7.48 The lifting of the income limit for exemption from certain accounting requirements is clearly a recognition of the difficulties that small organisations (which could gain registration under the proposals) will have in meeting the existing accountability requirements. Given the importance of ensuring that all registered organisations properly account to their members, it seems disproportionate to displace such a fundamental protection just to facilitate the registration of such organisations.

7.49 Removing of the requirement that a registered organisation be capable of creating an interstate industrial dispute is clearly to allow enterprises which operate solely within one State to establish their own Federally registered unions. In addition to the general concerns about enterprise unions, this proposal presents the majority of the Committee with two difficulties.

7.50 Firstly, there is no explanation as to why there should be a class of registered organisation which can not be a party to a Federal award or represent its members in award proceedings as a matter of right.

7.51 Secondly, the removal of this requirement represents a major incursion of Federal regulation in an area usually the preserve of State jurisdictions. All State jurisdictions regulate the activities of State unions by either registration or recognition requirements. Currently, such associations of employees can only avoid these State requirements and seek Federal registration where they are capable of creating an interstate industrial dispute. The effect of these provisions is to effectively allow any organisation to seek Federal registration and lift itself out of the State system. Without any national interest at stake, there is no justification for this. If a union only operates within a State, there seems no reason why it should not be regulated by that State's provisions.

7.52 Thirdly, as the evidence demonstrated there is at least some doubt about the constitutional validity of the registration of such an organisation given that the registration provision have been held to be incidental to the constitutional power allowing for the prevention and settlement of an interstate industrial disputes by conciliation and arbitration.

7.53 As a result of these concerns, the majority of the Committee recommends that the requirement that an organisation be capable of creating an interstate industrial dispute to obtain Federal registration be retained.

7.54 The Australian Democrats Member of the Committee supports these conclusions and recommendations but has made additional recommendations in his Supplementary Report.

7.55 Government members of the Committee disagree with all of the above conclusions and oppose the recommendations.

Autonomous Enterprise Branches

7.56 The Workplace Relations Bill requires the rules of any registered organisation to provide for the establishment of enterprise branches, and their autonomy (proposed section 201A). Division 6A provides for their establishment on the application of a certain number of members in an enterprise, following a successful ballot.

7.57 The Government's rationale for this proposal is to allow a greater degree of choice for employees in the selection of a registered organisation to represent them.

7.58 Two principal concerns about these provisions were expressed in evidence to the Committee. Firstly, some witnesses argued that these provisions represented an unwarranted intrusion into the internal affairs of trade unions. Secondly, it was said that the provisions were complex and ambiguous.

7.59 For example, Mr Joseph Ludwig, Senior Industrial Officer of the Australian Workers Union of Employees, stated in evidence to the Committee: .

7.60 The submission from the Law Council of Australia was particularly critical of this aspect of the Bill:

7.61 The Council also suggested that the extent of 'autonomy' guaranteed to branches should not be a matter left to regulations (as proposed in section 201A(b)). [28]

7.62 The Metal Trades Industry Association (MTIA) questioned the need for autonomous enterprise branches, arguing that the provisions were more likely to encourage renegade groups to organise themselves into legitimate bodies, fragment existing employee organisations at the enterprise which might be working quite effectively, and make harmonious working relations more difficult to achieve [29]. On this point there was an exchange between Mr Boland of the MTIA and Senator Mackay:

Conclusions

7.63 Like the other proposed amendments to registered organisations, the requirement for autonomous enterprise branches is based on the proposition that the decision-making structures of existing registered organisations arbitrarily impose decisions on their members at an enterprise rather than allowing members to make their own decisions on matters which affect their enterprise . Again this argument is flawed.

7.64 In the existing Act, there are elaborate provisions that require the rules of an organisation to ensure proper elections, regular and proper financial reporting, and provide for a fair and appropriate representation of individuals within its decision-making structures. There has been little evidence suggesting that these provisions do not provide fair and adequate representation. In particular, there was very little that suggested that decision making didn't appropriately take account of the views of members at individual workplaces. Where unions do not act on the concerns of members at the grass roots, there is an obvious solution - members use their democratic rights to elect officials and delegates who will do so.

7.65 There are a number of other difficulties with the proposals. We agree with the criticisms that the provisions lack clarity. Many questions about the operation of these provisions remain unanswered. In particular, the effect that the `autonomy' requirement will have on the relationship between the autonomous branch and other constituent units of the union is unclear. This question is vital for the resolution of such issues as financial accountability, participation in wider organisational decision making and the autonomous branch members' entitlements to services provided by the rest of the union.

7.66 In addition, the proposal ignores the important interaction between union members on site and other parts of the organisation. The need to account to a wider membership than simply that at one work site may provide a mechanism for broader considerations of isses. Such interactions force a more complete perspective than simply what is happening at an individual enterprise. This means that actions that may affect other sites or areas are taken into account when decisions are made. It also ensures that issues of concern to all workers in an industry (such as occupational health and safety) are not treated in an ad hoc or inconsistent manner.

7.67 The majority of the Committee finds great merit in the argument by the MTIA that autonomous enterprise branches may provide a haven for renegade groups to organise themselves into legitimate groups. We are concerned that one consequence may be an increase in industrial disputation, particularly in areas where renegade groups have substantial bargaining power because of the strategic position of the employees that they represent.

7.68 Of particular concern, given the above, is that the proposal fails to appreciate the way the existing arrangements provide for accountability. Corporate personality (for unions) means that there is an single entity which can be held to account for actions (of all the members and officials) taken in its name. Many of the provisions of the Act either make the organisation accountable in the form of fines or penalties or by the ability to withdraw registration. The effect of these provisions is that the union, as an entity, is accountable for actions taken through the decision making processes of the union.

7.69 At best, the Government's proposals undermine the effectiveness of this accountability. More likely however, the proposals make the scheme of the Act unworkable. Guaranteeing 'autonomy' to a constituent unit of the organisation means that that part of the organisation should only be held liable for its actions. This is, however, inconsistent with the single corporate personality of the organisation. The constituent unit (the enterprise branch) does not hold any assets that can be attached; it does not have registration that can be removed. Responsibility for the actions of an autonomous enterprise branch cannot lie with the rest of the union which cannot control those actions. By divorcing responsibility/control from the entity, it becomes impossible to hold the entity liable for actions taken by the autonomous branch. As a result, these arrangements could become havens for the taking of action for which there is no accountability. This is clearly contrary to the public interest.

7.70 The majority of the Committee therefore recommends that this proposal (proposed Division 6A of Part XI) should not be implemented.

7.71 The Government members of the Committee disagree with the conclusion and oppose the recommendation.

Disamalgamation

7.72 The Workplace Relations and Other Legislation Amendment Bill 1996 allows for the disamalgamation of certain federally registered unions into their pre-amalgamation constituent parts or, into branches of the pre-amalgamation constituent parts.

7.73 The Government's rationale for this is that it: 'recognises that amalgamations occurred after 1991 in the context of pressured circumstances'. [31] The unions disagreed with this claim.

7.74 The ACTU is opposed to the provisions contained in the Bill for disamalgamation and argued in evidence to the Committee that because of the complexities of the process of disamalgamation, such action will most likely result in protracted and expensive litigation, the costs of which will be borne by members for little benefit. [32]

7.75 The Queensland Branch of the Australian Workers Union (AWU) suggested that if disamalgamation were to occur, then it should require a vote of all members as was the case for amalgamation in the first place. [33]

7.76 The Australian Road Transport Industries Organisation did not support the proposal to disamalgamate unions. It believes that amalgamation has been an important process, and the downsizing of unions in recent years has been a credit to the Australian Council of Trade Unions. [34]

7.77 Where a disamalgamation is approved, the Court must make orders apportioning the assets and liabilities of the amalgamated organisation between the new parts. [35] Lawyers for Industrial Justice question how a court is to fairly apportion the assets where only a small number of members of the constituent part participate in the vote:

Conclusions

7.78 The majority of the Committee considers that there was not a great deal of evidence given on this issue.

7.79 The Government's rationale for this proposal is unconvincing. Perhaps the only organisations that could have been 'pressured' into an amalgamation were the 'small organisations' that otherwise faced deregistration prior to amendments to the Industrial Relations Act made in 1995. Yet the Government's proposals go significantly further than this.

7.80 While the majority of the Committee does not oppose the disamalgamation of organisations in the circumstances outlined by the Government (subject to one issue discussed below), it does question some of the important detail on disamalgamation contained in the Bill.

7.81 Firstly, the voting arrangements that applied to amalgamation under the Act should also apply to a disamalgamation proposal. This has a number of implications.

7.82 The majority of the Committee queries why all those who have an interest in the disamalgamation are not entitled to participate in the plebiscite proposal? Given that a disamalgamation will affect both the members of the disamalgamating constituent unit and the remaining members of the union, there is a strong argument that all members of the amalgamated union should be able to vote.

7.83 Secondly, given that, for an amalgamation to have occurred, at least 25% of all members of both unions must have voted and more than 50% of those votes had to be in favour (except where a 'community of interest' was found to exist), the majority of the Committee queries why this should not also be the case with a disamalgamation.

7.84 Finally, and very importantly, the majority of the Committee has firmly concluded that unions should not be able to disamalgamate beyond their pre-existing constituent unions. This means that the majority of the Committee opposes the proposals that allow for a break up of a pre-amalgamation union into its constituent State branches. The Government's rationale relates only to amalgamations resulting for the legislative changes in 1991. As a result, these provisions are inconsistent with the Government's stated intention. Any provision going further than this, the majority of the Committee believes, should be rejected.

7.85 The majority of the Committee therefore recommends that the disamalgamation proposals (proposed Division 7A of Part IX) should be implemented, except for the proposal to permit unions to disamalgamate beyond their pre-amalgamation constituent unions.

7.86 The Government members of the Committee disagree with the conclusion and oppose the recommendation.

Encouragement Of Collective Organisations and Preference

7.87 The Government's stated policy position is to encourage freedom of association. In the legislation this is effected by:

7.88 The Bill proposes to amend the principal object of the Act be removing references to:

7.89 The Commission, in exercising its functions, will therefore no longer be required to have regard to these matters.

7.90 In relation to Freedom of Association, in addition to the above initiatives, various offences are created which are designed to 'ensure that employers, employees and independent contractors are free to join industrial associations of their choice or not to join industrial associations' (see Schedule 16). A variety of remedies are available from the Federal Court for contravention of the Division; including a monetary penalty of not more that $10,000 for bodies corporate and $2,000 for individuals; an order of reinstatement or re-engagement; an order requiring the payment of such amount as the Court thinks necessary; and injunctions to stop conduct (proposed section 298U). Proposed section 298V reverses the onus of proof in relation to an allegation that conduct was or is being carried out for a particular reason or with a particular intent. Thus, the presumption is that the conduct was carried out for the alleged reason or intent unless the person accused proves otherwise.

7.91 In relation to closed shops, the AIRC does not have the power to order compulsory unionism. Any informal arrangements of that nature exist outside the formal industrial relations system. The effect of the provisions is to outlaw such informal arrangements by imposing large monetary penalties on anyone who discriminates against a person because of their refusal to join a trade union.

7.92 Whether or not these provisions will have the actual effect of outlawing informal closed shop arrangements is not clear. Roger Boland, Industrial Relations Director with the MTIA, while supporting the removal of the provisions in principle, stated that:

7.93 In relation to preference, employer groups welcomed the abolition of `preference' and `closed shop' arrangements. ACCI argued that `preference' is not consistent with the concept of `merit' in employment decisions and is a form of discrimination on grounds other than merit. [38]

7.94 In response, the ACTU noted in its submission to the Committee that the repeal of preference provisions in the Act `will disturb long standing arrangements in relation to membership and will have substantial consequences'. [39] It will place employers in the position of having to decide whether to honour previous proven arrangements, or to abide by the new prohibitions; a choice potentially between a serious industrial dispute or penalties for not complying with the new Act. Further, in relation to the ACCI issue of merit, the ACTU made the point that most preference provisions were subject to 'the all other things being equal' qualification. The effect of this is that only when the candidates are equal in all other respects will preference operate.

7.95 The ACTU noted that the new arrangements are more likely to affect less militant unions which rely on preference arrangements and may result in a reduction in their membership. It predicts that ultimately the repeal of preference arrangement will result in an increased level of industrial disputation. [40]

7.96 The Health Services Union of Australia noted that preference clauses have usually been inserted into awards following proven cases of employers discriminating against union members, and that it never has been a simple matter to convince the Commission to insert such clauses. Because there has always been good reason for their inclusion, they should be allowed to continue to operate. [41]

7.97 The Honourable J M Riordan AO reinforced this principle stating that awards of preference have never been made without good and careful reasons being given and that the Commission has been cautious in its approach to the award of preference making it clear that every application is to be decided on its merits. [42] In the mining industry, `preference' serves as a strong support mechanism which protects the integrity of the whole mining community. For example, if a mine is exhausted then employees have preference in re-employment thus keeping workers within their own community. [43]

7.98 In noting that the Bill seeks to remove preference clauses and closed shop provisions, the Shop Distributive and Allied Employees' Association (SDA) suggested that where an employer and a union agree to encourage union membership amongst employees, this should be possible. The SDA noted that this possibility had been excluded by the Bill and that there was no rationale as to why that sort of a clause should not be permitted if all parties endorse such an inclusion. [44]

7.99 The MTIA, although in principle supporting the removal of the power to award preference clauses, also seemed to agree that, where such clauses are the result of genuine agreements between employees, their union and the employer, they should be able to come to such an agreement.

Conclusions

7.100 The industrial relations system in Australia encourages the collective arbitration of disputes and development of organisations of employees and employers. This is the context within which the provisions encouraging the development of registered organisations, including preference operate. This is not so much a repudiation of the rights of the individual but is rather a judgment that the best way to protect the rights of all employees is to provide for strong and viable registered organisations.

7.101 There are a number of ways in which the needs of individuals are taken into account in relation to this framework.

7.102 Firstly, Mitchell, in a study of preference clauses, has described what may be termed a 'system-oriented' approach to the insertion of preference clauses by the Commission in recent years. This recognises that the system has a need for effective unions and that preference should therefore be granted only to those unions which need it. [46] Thus preference is power usually awarded where collective arrangements have or are breaking down.

7.103 Secondly, Subsection 122(3) provides that, notwithstanding an award of preference, an employer is not required to give preference to a unionist over a person who holds a 'conscientious objector' certificate under section 267 of the Industrial Relations Act.

7.104 It is important to understand that the 'principle' of freedom of association as described in the Bill is not identical with the ILO's standards of freedom of association. As Creighton and Stewart note: 'It is clear the these standards neither condone nor condemn union security arrangements, including closed shop or preference'. [47]

7.105 The Labor members of the Committee therefore recommends that the proposal prohibiting preference arrangements (proposed section 94) should not be implemented, and that preference arrangements should be permitted where the parties agree that there should be a preference arrangement or where the Commission determines that a preference arrangement is appropriate.

7.106 The Australian Democrats member of the Committee disagrees with these conclusions and recommendations and makes additional recommendations in his Supplementary Report.

7.107 The Government members of the Committee disagree with the conclusion and oppose the recommendation.

Footnotes

[1] Submission No. 1017, Overview p. 3, ACTU.

[2] Submission No. 905, p. 4, ACCI.

[3] Submission No. 1016, p.164, DIR.

[4] Submission No 905, pp. 49-50, ACCI.

[5] The SRWU has not sought Federal registration presumably because of the existence of the AWU's coverage.

[6] Submission No. 1311, p. 4, Shearers and Rural Workers Union.

[7] Submission No. 1017, p. 35, Australian Council of Trade Unions.

[8] Evidence, p. E 1734.

[9] Evidence, p. E 143.

[10] Evidence, p. E 773.

[11] Evidence, p. E 779.

[12] Evidence, p E 789.

[13] Evidence, p. E 1393.

[14] Evidence, p. E 147.

[15] Submission No. 1157, p. 11, Metal Trades Industry Association.

[16] Evidence, p. E 152.

[17] Creighton, B. and Stewart A, Labour Law - An Introduction, The Federation Press, 1994 p. 229.

[18] Submission No. 1016, p. 11, Department of Industrial Relations.

[19] Submission No. 1017, p. 36, ACTU.

[20] See for example, Submission No. 1341, p. 29, The Honourable J.M. Riordan AO.

[21] Submission No. 1341, p. 29, The Honourable J.M. Riordan AO.

[22] Evidence, p. E 151.

[23] Submission No. 1245, p.9, Finance Sector Union.

[24] Submission No. 1245, p. 9, Finance Sector Union.

[25] Decision - Clerical Officers (Administrative Services) Interim Award 1987, 1991, 10 CAR 517 at p. 552 cited in Submission No. 1245 at p.9.

[26] Evidence, p. E1154.

[27] Submission No. 1293, p. 2, Law Council of Australia.

[28] Submission No. 1293, p. 2, Law Council of Australia.

[29] Submission No. 1157, p. 11, Metal Trades Industry Association.

[30] Evidence p. E786.

[31] 'The Reform of Workplace Relations' Legislation Guide May 1996, paragraph 4.14. Appended to Submission No. 1016, Department of Industrial Relations.

[32] Submission No. 1017, p. 38, ACTU.

[33] Submission No. 1139, p. 28, Australian Workers Union, Queensland Branch.

[34] Evidence, p. E 773.

[35] See proposed section 253ZP (Schedule 15 - Registered Organisations).

[36] Submission No. 914, p. 46, Lawyers for Industrial Justice.

[37] Evidence p. E. 787.

[38] Submission No. 905, p.50, ACCI.

[39] Submission No. 1017, p. 46, ACTU.

[40] Submission No. 1017, p. 42-48, ACTU.

[41] Submission No. 866, p.12, Health Services Union of Australia.

[42] Submission No. 1341, p. 34, The Hon. J.M. Riordan AO.

[43] Evidence, p. E 909.

[44] Submission No. 367, pp. 45-47, SDA.

[45] Evidence, p. E 787.

[46] Mitchell, R.J., The Rise and Fall of the Preference Power: The Practice of the Federal Commission, 1070-1987, 1 Australian Journal of Labour Law 224.

[47] Creighton, B. and Stewart A, Labour Law - An Introduction, The Federation Press, 1994, p. 249.