Additional Remarks - Senator Andrew Murray: Australian Democrats
Senate Standing Committee on Economics: Inquiry into the Tax Laws Amendment
(Simplified Superannuation) Bill 2006 and five related bills
The Bills
1.1
The
Tax Laws Amendment (Simplified Superannuation) Bill 2006 and five related bills
implement the Coalition Government's simplified superannuation reforms
announced in the 2006 Budget. They are sweeping reforms, and as the main report
notes, they will potentially (and materially) affect over 10 million people,
1.3 million employers and more than 310 000 superannuation funds. The new
system will apply from 1
July 2007.
Summary of my
conclusions
1.2
I
have titled this minority report 'Additional Remarks' because I support the
Committee Report and do not dissent from it. I welcome the Government's package
as a genuine attempt not only to simplify and streamline a complex system, but
to provide considerable incentives to encourage increased levels of work and
saving.
1.3
That
does not mean that I am without caution. In part, that caution is prompted by
the difficulty I have in fully assessing the consequences of these changes.
Unlike the 'New Tax System' that brought in the GST and related reforms, there
is a decided lack of modelling, cameos and detailed projections from the
Treasurer and Treasury. Treasury has not provided a long range forecast of tax
revenue effects beyond the forward estimates period, which is obviously needed,
so there is much uncertainty as to how these measures will affect Australia's financial future.
1.4
In
part my caution arises from the question of priority. Is spending $7.2 billion
on superannuation over the next four years the right priority? That is a hard
question to answer, given the competing demands on taxpayer funds. By their
nature, these reforms are selective in impact. Not everyone benefits or
benefits equally. Taxpayers over 60 years of age will benefit most, and
wealthier retirees will benefit more than the less wealthy.[1]
In my opinion these are not faults of themselves. What is important is whether
there are strong compensating programmes and reforms that will significantly
improve the lot of Australians who are not in these retirement categories.
1.5
In
part too, my caution is prompted by the sense of a lack of policy balance.
These reforms will benefit many Australians, but will particularly benefit
better-off Australians. Policy balance and equity requires structural reform in
the rest of the income tax system, particularly to benefit low and middle
income earners, that should accompany and follow these superannuation tax
reforms.
1.6
While
recognising that Australians will be grateful for tax relief provided in the
2006 Budget, the Democrats are disappointed that the Government has failed to
provide a strategic income tax reform plan. Structural tax reform is essential
to make the tax system simpler, fairer and transparent. Our income tax system
is complex, inequitable and inefficient. It is widely criticised for its
churning effect.
1.7
The
Treasurer has adjusted rates and thresholds within the existing system. He
needs to change the system to be simpler, broader based and more equitable. The
Democrats say a structural income tax reform plan should include raising the
tax free threshold significantly to take millions of Australians out of the income
tax system; indexing the rates to account for bracket creep; broadening the
base by cutting out tax concessions that are inequitable, inefficient,
outdated, unnecessary, or distortionary; reforming the tax welfare intersects
to encourage welfare to work and remove inequities; and ensuring nominal and
effective tax rates remain fair and competitive.
1.8
One
frequently expressed concern has been the large potential revenue foregone as a
result of this reform. I have however been intrigued by the prospect of this
reform being a large revenue-earner, rather than a large revenue-loser.
Unfortunately I do not have the means to model this theory, but I will cover
these thoughts briefly below.
Is this
'super' reform also going to be a big revenue earner?
1.9
Demographically
speaking, we are an ageing population. This social phenomenon throughout the
developed world presents a number of specific challenges. Perhaps the most
challenging of these challenges is the means by which an increasing number of
retirees are able to fund their existence at an affordable public cost.
1.10
The
combination of retirement, an ageing population and retirement funding dilemmas
are all inextricably linked. The role of Government in managing this complex
socioeconomic trend is twofold. It must ensure policies and regulatory
mechanisms are in place to enable Australians to effectively save for their
retirement, whilst at the same time ensuring that increased concessions to
superannuation do not jeopardise future government revenue that will pay for
our nation’s healthcare, education, infrastructure and other expenses.
1.11
Has
the Tax Laws Amendment (Simplified Superannuation) Bill 2006 and related bills
struck the right balance? Does it offer the best system to partly and wholly
self-funded retirees, low income pensioners and taxpayers alike? How will it
fit within Australia’s regulatory and tax
framework?
1.12
Time
will tell.
1.13
Striking
a balance between protecting taxation revenue and establishing taxation
concessions to encourage Australians to save for their retirement is a
delicate, difficult and important task. Although not immediately obvious, this
trade-off is representative of the socioeconomic divide that continues to grow
within our nation.
1.14
On
the one side of the divide exists Wealthy Australia that is empowered to save
for their future through a superannuation system that is now well designed for
this purpose. On the other side of the divide is Low Income Australia, in retirement reliant
upon welfare via a means tested general age pension.
1.15
To
fund the retirees of Low Income Australia and to subsidise the retirees of Wealthy
Australia, taxes must be generated. The critical issue with regard to this
funding dilemma is how the Government proposes to generate the requisite tax
income from a projected shrinking taxable working population, to meet the
expenses of a retiring population which is forecast to grow substantially.
1.16
The
prospect of raising corporate or personal income taxes on a tax base maintained
by a smaller proportion of the population is an alternative that is both
politically unsavoury and economically unviable.
1.17
A
more politically and economically sound alternative is to generate additional
tax revenue through incentives to encourage Australians to save for retirement
and to work beyond the traditional retirement age of 60.
1.18
Core
measures contained within this bill such as the removal of taxation on
superannuation benefits from taxed funds after 60 years of age and scrapping
the compulsory superannuation payout provisions certainly encourage Australians
to work longer and save harder, but this is only half of the story.
1.19
While
many of the provisions contained within this bill will encourage more savings
to flow into superannuation accounts and Australians working longer will delay
the shrinking tax base, the problem that must ultimately be faced by Government
is how to fund a growing unfunded general age pension and how to subsidise the
growing cost of our hospitals, schools, roads, ports and other resources upon
which Australians universally depend.
1.20
Does
this ‘Simplified Super’ bill possibly establish a channel that can, in part,
bridge the divide between rich and poor Australia? Surprisingly, and from a counter-intuitive
perspective the answer to this question could be yes.
1.21
By
removing the benefits tax on superannuation which only applies to wealthy
retirees and making a number of other structural changes, the Government is
also removing a significant hurdle to investment in superannuation. With
significantly greater investment in superannuation the Government could stand
to gain substantially from taxation revenue through both the once-off
contributions tax, and a tax on earnings with concessional rates of 15 per
cent, at an estimated 7.1 per cent[2]
return respectively.
1.22
This
could mean that with money pouring into super and a vast sum of money invested,
(which will grow to 'trillions'), the Government has potentially crafted a
growing ‘taxable’ base that could dwarf the present personal income tax base.
1.23
The
generosity and clarity of the ‘Simple Super’ bill is intended to encourage a
massive injection of funds into superannuation, which could turn out to be a
very significant revenue earner. In turn it could provide the mechanism by
which the Government proposes funding the ‘savings gap’ of low income retirees
and the accompanying plethora of subsidised social costs.
1.24
An
obvious question arises: if this is so, why has the Government not expounded
more on the forecast growth of investment (and therefore tax revenue) in
superannuation as a result of the changes contained within the ‘Simple Super’
bill?
1.25
The
answer may be a simple one – until the behavioural effects become apparent, one
would have to be cautious in predicting the consequence of enhanced saving
investment, particularly if it is thought the investment effect might be modest
if funds are simply switched from existing investment vehicles to others in
superannuation.
1.26
Scrapping
the benefits tax and cleaning up the legislation are the two big ‘carrots’ that
have been proffered, both of which could carry a negligible expense relative to
the tax gains that stand to be made from a burgeoning and taxable national
superannuation pool. Maybe this is the government’s secret future cash cow.
Maybe not.
1.27
Time
will tell.
1.28
From
a big picture perspective, what Australia could progressively experience is a
conversion from a taxation system focused on revenue raising via personal
incomes with a tax base estimated at $450 billion presently,[3]
to an increased reliance on a superannuation system forecast to have $2 trillion
plus under management by 2015 and growing rapidly. The system works because
superannuation is a function of both personal income and growing capital; it is
a much bigger taxable base, so that it can be taxed at a lower 'concessional'
rate and still cover the forecast shortfall in personal income tax raised.
1.29
If
this thesis is accurate, then the ‘Simple Super’ Bill has struck an adequate balance between
encouraging more work, and encouraging those that can save for their retirement
to do so, whilst at the same time preserving the means to raise taxation
revenue to meet forecast welfare and social costs.
1.30
Neither
Government nor the Explanatory Memorandum has attempted to discuss this
possibility. Understandably, the Government is focusing on what taxpayers stand
to gain rather than what they may lose in the form of future increased taxation
revenue. Broadcasting the value and importance of the national superannuation
pool as a potentially progressively more important source of taxation is not
likely to be part of the Governments 'spin', particularly if such potential
gains are uncertain at this stage.
1.31
I
am of the view that the superannuation system, by its very design, is
structured to serve Australians with incomes substantial enough to set aside
funds for retirement. This is the essence of self-funded retirement. For low
and low-to-middle income Australians, their reliance on the superannuation
system will be of a very different nature. Their pension will, indirectly, be
reliant upon the same system for the taxation returns that the reformed system
offers, as opposed to the generation of an income stream substantial enough to
self-fund their retirement.
Senator
Andrew Murray
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page