Appendix 3 - Alternative models

Appendix 3 - Alternative models

ASX submission

1.1 The ASX submission to the inquiry identified four alternative models, as follows:[1]

Option 1 - Current Corporations Law Model

1.2 Chapters 2 and 3 deal with the advantages and disadvantages of the current model. The ASX summarised the advantages of the current model as follows:

1.3 Disadvantages associated with this model identified by ASX were as follows:

Option 2 - Dispense with co-regulatory model

1.4 The ASX summarised the advantages of this option as follows:

1.5 The ASX summarised the disadvantages of the this option as follows:

Option 3 - Create one overarching Self Regulating Organisation (SRO) for all markets;

1.6 The ASX summarised the advantages of this option as follows:

1.7 The ASX summarised the disadvantages of this option as follows:

Option 4 - Hybrid Model – that is, leave SRO function for Market Conduct Requirements but responsibility for internal business practices of market participants to reside with third party)

1.8 The ASX summarised the advantages of this option as follows:

1.9 The ASX summarised the disadvantages of this option as follows:

US Securities Industry Association (SIA) white paper[2]

1.10  The US SIA White paper provides an analysis of alternative market supervision frameworks in the United States, although not unexpectedly it shares much in common with considerations of the issue in Australia and elsewhere.

1.11 The SIA prepared the paper in the context of significant change in the US Securities Industry driven largely by technological innovation. The paper notes that technological developments have challenged many of the fundamental assumptions of how markets work and facilitated the creation of new competitive structures. The proliferation of alternative trading systems (ATSs) and electronic communication networks (ECNs) in the US securities market presents substantial competition to the traditional exchanges. In response, the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) announced that it intended to demutualise and the National Association of Securities Dealers decided to spin off and privatise the NASDAQ.

1.12 As in Australia, these developments gave rise to concerns about possible conflicts between supervisory and commercial responsibilities and brought into question the continued viability of this organisation as self-regulatory organisations. (SROs).

1.13 Accordingly, the SIA formed an ad hoc Committee to analyse these issues. The resulting paper examines the advantages and disadvantages of the current self-regulatory structure and evaluates a range of possible alternatives.

1.14 The SIA Subcommittee  identified seven factors for evaluating the appropriateness of regulatory structures:

1.15 It is important to note that in the SIA's evaluation, there was a clear preference for the continuation of self-regulation. The following quotation is indicative of the prevailing view:

The genius of self-regulation is that it puts regulatory decisions in the hands of people intimately familiar with the relevant facts. Any regulatory change should not abandon this valuable asset in favour of a distant, generalist regulator that is ignorant of the markets it regulates.[3]

1.16 The paper evaluated six potential regulatory models, as follows:

1.17 One difficulty that the SIA's analysis presents is its relevance to the Australian market, there being several large competing exchanges in the US compared to the dominant status of the ASX in Australia. Nonetheless there are enough similarities to make cautious comparisons worthwhile.

Option 1 - Retain Status quo

1.18 In the US there are 8 national securities exchanges and one national securities association (NASD) registered with the American regulatory equivalent of ASIC, the Securities Exchange Commission (SEC). The number of exchanges is expected to increase. The basis functions of these SROs are not dissimilar to ASX - they operate and promote a marketplace; and perform a regulatory function of the market and participants. The White paper identifies the following advantages of this structure:

1.19 Disadvantages identified with maintaining the status quo were as follows:

Option 2 - Multiple exchanges with separate boards and information barriers for their regulatory arms (NASDR model)

1.20 In this option, the SIA considers essentially the same structure as option 1, with the important distinction that exchanges undergo an internal corporate restructuring segregating the market and regulatory roles of demutualised SROs. The SIA envisaged at least two subsidiaries within the SRO, one dealing with rules and related matters, and the other containing the market centre. Advantages are:

1.21 Disadvantages identified are:

Option 3 - Multiple SROs with firms designated to a single SRO for examination purposes (DEA model)

1.22 Under this option, inspection responsibilities are allocated amongst the SROs. The option also introduces the concept of a Designated Examining Authority (DEA). Under the model, the SEC allocates responsibility for oversighting broker/dealers who operate in more than one market to one SRO only that becomes the DEA for that group of brokers. The objective is to avoid duplicate examinations of brokers, something that has not been raised as a problem in the Australian context. It is difficult to see how this model could be applied in Australia because of the presence of only one SRO of major significance, the ASX. The advantage of this option is that it eliminates duplicate examinations of brokers - an efficiency measure.

1.23 Disadvantages identified are:

Option 4 - One SRO for member firms; markets regulate their own trading  (Hybrid model)

1.24 Under Option 4, the SIA contemplates self regulation on the basis of function rather than on the basis of firm membership. The model breaks regulation into two streams – one relating to trading and the other to firm operation and capital requirements. All non-market related self-regulatory functions would be combined into a single organisation which would function irrespective of markets. Hence, each market would undertake its own regulatory and surveillance functions, but matters such as member regulation, sales practices and all other aspects of inter-market trading would be overseen by a single SRO.

1.25 Like Option 3, it is difficult to see how this model could be applied in an Australian market context. However, it is apparently a favoured model in the US context. It is a complex model and received the most attention in the SIA paper.

1.26 The SIA sees the following advantages:

1.27 Identified disadvantages are:

Option 5 - All purpose single SRO (Single SRO model)

1.28 Under Option 5, the SIA would move trading regulation and non-market-related regulation into a single, all purpose SRO. This organisation would then be responsible for all rule making, surveillance and enforcement responsibility for all areas of regulation. The exchanges would be divested of all their self-regulatory authority, leaving each functioning as a simple marketplace, similar to an alternative trading system. This model appears to be based on a concept requiring a private organisation to function as a regulator, with no other purpose.

1.29 The model is possibly feasible in an Australian context but may be impractical. The SIA sees the following advantages:

1.30 Identified disadvantages include the following:

Option 6 - Single regulatory model (SEC only model).

1.31 This option is seen as a drastic solution under which the concept of self-regulation would be abolished entirely. The ASIC equivalent, the SEC, would have its duties expanded to cover all the oversight responsibilities currently undertaken by the SROs. Listed advantages include:

1.32 The option is seen as likely to introduce a host of new problems. Disadvantages include:

1.33 This option does not appear to be seriously contemplated by the SIA.

IOSCO examination of recent international developments

1.34 The mid to late 1990’s has been a period of dramatic change among many of the world’s exchanges. A manifestation of this change has been the increasing number of exchanges opting to demutualise and in some cases, float.

1.35 This rapid change has been addressed by international organisations such as IOSCO. The issues that are canvassed in this chapter are based on the IOSCO paper titled; ‘Issues Paper on Exchange Demutualization’ of June 2001. This final section of the chapter examines a number of the world’s exchanges and briefly summarises, in point form, the more relevant aspects relating to demutualisation. The section highlights the methods that have been implemented to deal with some of the issue that arise when an exchange demutualises and or floats.

1.36 A similar bundle of issues confront all exchanges when they choose to demutualise. The key issues are the problems which arise in relation to conflicts of interest and self regulation. The way in which these issues are managed bear similarities to the systems put in place by the ASX. Solutions generally require the assistance of the relevant countries supervising body in the form of increased monitoring. However, there is no universal plan, each situation requires solutions catering to the specific environments of each exchange. Issues that are common to all exchanges include:

1.37 Some of these issues, even before demutualisation, have confronted all exchanges to some degree. This is evidenced by the fact that many exchanges have been self-regulating since inception. In such an environment exchanges have been required to manage conflict in relation to:

1.38 The response to potential conflicts from stock exchanges around the world has been to point to controls such as:

Hong Kong

Toronto

Singapore

Sweden

United Kingdom

1.39 The Committee notes that since the date of the IOSCO publication, the 4.9 percent ownership limit applying to the LSE has been removed.

Comparison between Australian and overseas developments

1.40 As part of or soon after their demutualisation processes, the Hong Kong, Singapore and Swedish stock exchanges have been merged with their respective futures markets or clearing and settlement houses. It can be assumed that such arrangements offer more depth and security to the market. The ASX has become involved in clearing and settlement activities via the CHESS and SEATS systems. However, the ASX has not been permitted to takeover the SFE due to an ACCC decision based on potential loss of competition.

1.41 All the monitoring responsibilities of Hong Kong’s HKEx falls to the Securities and Futures Commission (SFC). The SFC monitors and manages the HKEx in terms of conflicts of interest. In addition the SFC also has powers associated with trade practices law in matters such as those pertaining to monopolies. The Australian model has split the two roles between the ACCC and ASIC.

1.42 The Toronto Stock Exchange (TSE) has proposed the establishment of the TSE RS. Its role would be the responsible management of market regulation. This model bears some similarity to that of the ASX, which has established the ASXSR. However, the TSE RS charges for its services on a cost recovery basis. The ASXSR is totally funded by the ASX. The TSE RS model offers a perception of independence by charging for its services. However, charging will lead to an increase in costs when conducting business on the TSE.

Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page