Chapter 3
Technical issues and committee view
3.1
Several submissions commented on the suitability of the term 'aggregated
assessable income' used in the bill. Various objections to the use of the term
were put forward, including that the term may potentially result in anomalous
outcomes for companies in certain sectors. These issues are examined in this
chapter. The committee's overall conclusions and recommendations regarding the
bill are then detailed at the end of the chapter.
Threshold based on 'aggregated assessable income'
3.2
As noted in chapter 1, the R&D incentive consists of two components:
a 45 per cent refundable tax offset and a non-refundable 40 per cent tax
offset. Whether the refundable or non-refundable tax offset is available to a
particular R&D entity currently depends on that entity's 'aggregated
turnover'[1]—if
it is less than $20 million the R&D entity may use the 45 per cent
refundable tax offset, otherwise the 40 per cent offset is available. The
bill proposes to refine this further by stipulating that the 40 per cent offset
is not available to R&D entities with an 'aggregated assessable income' for
the income year of $20 billion or above.
3.3
'Assessable income' is a core concept in the ITAA 1997. It consists of income
according to ordinary concepts (ordinary income) and income included as a result
of income tax legislation (statutory income), excluding any ordinary or
statutory income made exempt by legislation.[2]
For the purposes of the R&D tax incentive, the bill proposes to define 'aggregated
assessable income' as the sum of:
- an R&D entity's assessable income for the income year; and
- the assessable income for the income year of any entity that, at
any time during the income year, is connected with the R&D entity, is an
affiliate of the R&D entity, and of which the R&D entity is an
affiliate.[3]
3.4
The rationale for basing the threshold on aggregated assessable income
is outlined in the explanatory memorandum as being to ensure that the threshold
'cannot be easily circumvented by diverting income to an associated entity or
directing another entity to conduct certain activities'.[4]
3.5
Submissions advised that the use of this concept to identify large
companies appeared to be a departure from the original policy announcement
which referred to turnover.[5]
A number of specific issues were raised which are discussed below.
Complexity and number of companies
covered
3.6
Stakeholders questioned the use of aggregated assessable income from the
standpoint that the concept is overly complex and technical (that is, the term
does not correspond with the ordinary understanding of what $20 billion of
turnover is). KPMG argued that basing the exclusion on this term 'may
inadvertently capture even more taxpayers than initially announced and produce
some unusual and possibly unintended consequences'. It provided the following overall
explanation:
Assessable income is a complex term which encompasses both
common law and statutory income. This already hints at its complexity and the
difficulties its use will impose on companies trying to determine 'aggregated
assessable income' for themselves and other entities with whom they are
connected.[6]
3.7
KPMG added:
- as the definition does not exclude income derived between related
entities, a $20 billion threshold based on aggregated assessable income will be
reached more quickly than a threshold set an aggregated turnover of $20
billion;
- businesses will be required to understand and apply 'yet
another...subtly different definition'; and
- including both the assessable income of affiliates of the R&D
entity, and of which the R&D entity is an affiliate is, in KPMG's view,
'inconsistent with the aggregated turnover definition and in practice, will
have little further application'.[7]
3.8
Deloitte similarly expounded on the complexity associated with the
definition and questioned the approach of including statutory income:
As soon as you start to introduce multiple tests the
compliance costs increase and confusion reigns. But also this concept of
aggregated assessable income includes both income according to ordinary
concepts but also statutory income. There is a lot in statutory income which is
unusual by its very nature. It is there because of the legislature deeming to
tax certain classes of activities in a particular way. It includes, for
example, capital gains which, depending on the particular transaction, an
organisation may breach the $20 billion threshold notwithstanding its ordinary
turnover would not include that sort of figure.[8]
3.9
In support of Deloitte's argument, Ernst & Young provided an example
of a capital gains event that it considered counts towards the threshold and
would result in an undesirable outcome:
...if I am a business and there are two parts of my business
and I sell that part of the business, the shares in that part of the business,
that potentially triggers capital gains and therefore additional income for me.
That can in a sense artificially inflate that. That is not the ordinary income.[9]
3.10
Deloitte also advised that gaining access to information about related
party transactions with affiliates and entities controlled through affiliates
can often be 'problematic'.[10]
Implications for companies
approaching the $20 billion threshold
3.11
KPMG and Michael Johnson Associates suggested that the proposed
amendments could create uncertainty for companies that could not confidently
determine in advance whether their aggregated assessable income would be above
or below the $20 billion threshold. As aggregated assessable income can only be
determined after the end of an income year and, according to KPMG, is a figure
that would be difficult to determine, these companies could not know if they
were eligible for the incentive until after the decision to undertake (or not
undertake) R&D activities had been made.[11]
On this issue, Michael Johnson Associates provided the following reasoning and
outline of the possible consequences:
The use of the concepts of assessable income and grouping
will make the potential application of the threshold highly unpredictable for
company groups in the vicinity of the $20 billion figure.
The Incentive is designed to impact the type and level of
investment decisions at the time they are made. The fact that the Incentive may
subsequently not be available because a combination of circumstances sees a
company group exceeding the $20 billion threshold where it is not certain that
this will be the case will deter these groups from making R&D decisions on
anything other than the conservative assumption that the Incentive will not
apply.
This introduces more uncertainty into the system and will be
an additional dampener on levels of R&D investment.[12]
3.12
BDO Australia noted that other provisions in the ITAA 1997 use a prior
year test, such as the taxation of financial arrangements provisions in
Division 230.[13]
Do the proposed amendments
disadvantage Australian companies?
3.13
Several submissions argued that the use of aggregated assessable income discriminates
against Australian companies because all income derived by Australian companies,
whether in Australia or overseas, will be captured by the definition. For
foreign companies, however, assessable income is only income derived in
Australia.[14]
The Australian Academy of Technological Sciences and Engineering believes that
it 'is difficult to understand how the Parliament could agree to such a
discriminatory approach'.[15]
Michael Johnson Associates also questioned this aspect of the bill, suggesting
that 'modest transnational performers in terms of Australian revenue remain in
the program whilst stellar local performers are closed out'.[16]
3.14
This issue was discussed at the committee's public hearing. Deloitte
explained how it expects multinational companies to respond:
From a multinational perspective, depending on where they derive
their assessable income, they may have income well in excess of $20 billion but
they do not derive it here, and they would have an advantage compared with an
Australian company that derives most of its assessable income in country, and
they may be accessing and being supported whilst an Australian company is not.
That might, however, have the positive impact of actually making Australia a
little bit more attractive than a multinational to conduct R&D in country,
but I still think it is discriminatory.[17]
3.15
Officials from the Department of Industry and Treasury confirmed that
the policy intent behind the definition was a desire to continue to provide an
incentive for foreign companies to undertake R&D in Australia. It is
assumed that Australian companies affected by the proposed amendments will
continue to undertake their R&D in Australia regardless.[18]
A Department of Industry official added that the aggregated assessable income
test would result in 'ease of administration', as foreign companies are already
required to determine their assessable income in Australia for their tax
returns.[19]
Potential anomalous impacts on
particular sectors
3.16
Submissions advised that the proposed definition of aggregated assessable
income could have particular consequences for life insurance companies and
petroleum retailers.
Life insurance companies
3.17
Life insurance companies are subject to special rules for determining
their taxable income due to the nature of their business. These rules are
contained in division 320 of the ITAA 1997, which aims to ensure that the
taxation of life insurance companies occurs 'in a broadly comparable way to
other entities that derive similar kinds of income'.[20]
Under these rules, the total amount of the life insurance premiums paid to the
company in the income year is included in the company's assessable income.[21]
When determining taxable income, however, the inclusion of these premiums is
offset by deductions for investment capital.[22]
KPMG argued that the actual turnover of life insurance companies 'is in reality
limited to the fees received by the company'.[23]
The mechanism in division 320 reflects this understanding by providing that
life insurance companies are not taxed on premiums that do not constitute their
economic income.
3.18
This net outcome does not appear to be reflected in the bill as
deductions are not considered. Accordingly, KPMG argued that life insurance
companies could reach the $20 billion aggregated assessable income
threshold and be excluded from claiming the R&D tax incentive while having an
actual turnover that was much lower.[24]
Downstream petroleum industry
3.19
It was argued that petroleum retailers could be disadvantaged by the
proposed definition because of the high turnover, low margin nature of that
industry and the items that petroleum retailers include in their assessable
income.
3.20
Caltex advised that it is likely to surpass the $20 billion aggregated
assessable income threshold, and thus would no longer be eligible to claim the
R&D tax incentive in future if the bill were passed.[25]
However, Caltex argued that the ability to afford R&D is measured by
profitability, and that profitability and assessable income 'are not always
well correlated'.[26]
To demonstrate this, Caltex advised that in 2012 it had an after tax profit of $57
million on a historic cost basis, or $458 million on a replacement cost of
sales basis. Caltex argued that its profitability, and the profitability of the
oil industry generally, is relatively low compared to turnover and the turnover
of other very large companies that would be affected by the proposed changes.[27]
Caltex provided a table of the top companies by revenue and net profit after
tax to support this reasoning. An abridged version of this table is at Table
3.1.
Table 3.1: Top 20 companies by revenue and net profit
after tax
Rank
|
Company
|
Total revenue ($billion)
|
Net profit after tax ($billion)
|
1
|
BHP Billiton
|
72
|
15.2
|
2
|
Rio Tinto
|
60
|
5.7
|
3
|
Wesfarmers
|
58
|
2.1
|
4
|
Woolworths
|
56
|
1.8
|
5
|
National Australia Bank
|
49
|
4.1
|
6
|
Commonwealth Bank of
Australia
|
47
|
7.1
|
7
|
Westpac Banking Corporation
|
42
|
6
|
8
|
ANZ Banking Corporation
|
40
|
5.7
|
9
|
Telstra
|
26
|
3.4
|
10
|
Xstrata Holdings
|
23
|
3.2
|
11
|
Caltex Australia
|
23
|
-0.7*
|
12
|
Shell Australia
|
22
|
-0.8
|
13
|
BP Australia
|
21
|
0.8
|
14
|
QBE Insurance Group
|
21
|
0.7
|
15
|
Suncorp Group
|
16
|
0.7
|
16
|
Qantas
|
16
|
-0.2
|
17
|
NSW Health
|
16
|
0.09
|
18
|
Fonterra Co-op Group
|
15
|
0.5
|
19
|
Origin Energy
|
13
|
1
|
20
|
Metcash
|
12
|
0.09
|
Source: Caltex
Australia, Submission 15, p. 8; originally sourced from BRW Top 1000
Companies in 2013.
* Caltex notes that the
replacement cost of sales operating profit (RCOP) net profit after tax
(pre-significant items) is $0.3 billion. Caltex advised that RCOP 'results
remove the impact of fluctuations in the US$ price of crude and foreign
exchange an cost of sales, which is separately identified as inventory
gains/(losses) in the statutory accounts'.
3.21
Caltex provided a two-part explanation for petroleum companies having a
high assessable income relative to profit. The first reason given is petroleum
companies face a high cost of sales that fluctuates due to the exchange rate:
The cost of goods, as we have shown on the schedule, has gone
from about $12 billion in 2009 to almost $17 billion as at the end of December
2012. That is a significant sum that we have to expend. When we exclude all
that, our profits are really down to about $1.7 billion as at the end of 2012.
* * *
A lot of our costs, a lot of our turnover, is influenced by
the foreign exchange rates which have significantly varied over the last few
years. We have gone from 80c for a US dollar to 96c. The average price of crude
oil, which is also denominated in US dollars, which we buy in order to
manufacture, has gone from US$64 to US$114 on average. When one considers that,
it automatically has external factors which adversely impact an organisation
such as Caltex which has to compete with all the other multinationals.[28]
3.22
The second explanation provided for petroleum companies having a high
assessable income relative to profit is excise. Caltex stated that its ordinary
income includes cost recovery from customers of excise of over $5 billion,
representing $0.38 for every litre of fuel sold in Australia.[29]
3.23
Overall, Caltex considered that both turnover and aggregated assessable
income are a 'very poor metric for the size of a firm'.[30]
It recommended that a second test be introduced based on taxable income:
By all means leave the turnover or assessable income test in
place, if that is the government's intention, but ensure that more profitable
firms are captured by introducing a second test or threshold which relates to
taxable income.[31]
3.24
Alternatively, Caltex suggested the definition be amended to exclude ordinary
income derived from sales of retail fuel—an exclusion already contained in the
ITAA 1997 to ensure that small petroleum retailers were not excluded from the
definition of a small business used for Pay As You Go withholding tax.[32]
However, Caltex advised that it preferred the addition of a threshold based on
taxable income to an exclusion, given that future increases in oil prices may
still push Caltex above the $20 billion threshold even if excise were excluded.[33]
Committee view
3.25
The committee acknowledges that most submissions do not agree with the intent
behind the bill. A proposed change to taxation arrangements inevitably triggers
a vocal response from those that do not agree with the proposal, particularly
the entities directly affected by it. The committee welcomes a robust debate
about tax policy and seriously considered the views put forward. However,
during this inquiry the committee has been mindful of the statutory object of
the R&D tax incentive, which is to:
encourage industry to conduct research and development
activities that might otherwise not be conducted because of an uncertain
return from the activities, in cases where the knowledge gained is likely to
benefit the wider Australian economy.[34]
(emphasis added)
3.26
The committee has been provided with evidence that supports the
contention that the R&D tax incentive could be better targeted. It is
acknowledged that there is some research which reaches a different conclusion,
although some of the counterarguments made and studies cited in submissions focused
on the benefits R&D undertaken by large companies provide for the economy.
This is not in question—how responsive these companies are to the R&D tax
incentive and whether this represents the best use of taxpayer money are the
key issues.
3.27
The committee is also mindful of the government's intention to implement
a sustainable fiscal strategy and how the bill fits in with efforts to
strengthen the budget position. Given the evidence received, it is prudent for
changes to be considered that will better target the R&D tax incentive to companies
that are more likely to increase their R&D spending in response to the incentive.
This will ensure that the government revenue foregone as a result of the tax
offsets that make up the incentive delivers the greatest possible return for
taxpayers. Accordingly, the committee supports the bill.
3.28
There are elements of the bill that the committee considers require
specific comment. The retrospective application of the proposed amendments is
already discussed in chapter 2. The second matter is the concept of aggregated
assessable income used in the bill. Although it is a technical taxation law term
that is a more complex concept than turnover, the committee does not consider
that its use will, generally, pose issues for the large, well‑informed
taxpayers affected by the proposed amendments. The committee also notes the
evidence that asserts Australian companies will be disadvantaged by the proposed
amendments compared to foreign companies. This is a difficult policy question
although, on balance, the committee agrees with the approach taken on the basis
it will maintain an incentive for foreign companies to undertake R&D in
Australia and therefore maximise the amount of R&D undertaken in this
country.
3.29
The evidence received regarding the practical application of the bill to
companies in particular sectors, such as life insurance companies and petrol
retailers, warrants further consideration. It may be appropriate to include certain
exclusions to the definition of aggregated assessable, such as excluding the
assessable income of an R&D entity to the extent it is attributable to life
insurance company policyholders' interests, or to introduce a secondary test
based on taxable income. These are matters the government should consider
further before the bill proceeds, although this recommendation does not impact
the committee's endorsement of the bill.
Recommendation 1
3.30
The committee recommends that the government further consider the definition
of 'aggregated assessable income' of an R&D entity in the proposed new
section 355‑103 of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1997 with a view
to addressing, to the extent possible and with minimum fiscal impact, any potential
anomalies that the use of the term may create for life insurance companies and
petroleum retailers.
Recommendation 2
3.31
Subject to recommendation 1, the committee recommends that the bill be passed.
Senator David Bushby
Chair
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page