Chapter 2

Chapter 2

Dumping, subsidisation and the international environment

2.1        Anti-dumping and countervailing issues are complex. There is considerable debate over whether governments should take action to address the effects of dumping and subsidisation. Many submissions raised concerns over the compatibility of the bill’s amendments with Australia’s international legal obligations, and argued that all interests, from consumer to exporter, should be considered.

2.2        This chapter provides an introduction to dumping and subsidisation, including statistical information on recent trends in global and Australian anti-dumping and countervailing activities. It then explores the role of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in enforcing international anti-dumping and countervailing agreements, and considers their interaction with Australia's domestic legal framework.

Dumping and subsidisation  

2.3        Trade distortions can occur through a number of different mechanisms, both through the behaviour of individual companies (dumping) and through government intervention (subsidisation).

2.4        Dumping is defined as a 'situation of international price discrimination, where the price of a product when sold in the importing country is less than the price of that product in the market of the exporting country'.[1] In other words, a product is considered dumped 'if the export price of the product exported from one country to another is less than the comparable price, in the ordinary course of trade, for the like product when destined for consumption in the exporting country'.[2] Theoretically, this will result in increased substitution by users of the good from domestic production to imports, and translate to "unfairly" lower prices for end-consumers.

2.5        A government may also subsidise industries by providing grants, tax concessions, loan guarantees, equity infusions, or price support. Often, the manifestation of subsidisation is the ability of domestic firms to export at lower prices than otherwise would have been possible based on their costs of production.

2.6         Whether government action should be taken against dumping is an area of considerable debate. Some argue that where dumping has a 'disproportionate' effect on certain industries, 'the damage borne by the affected sector can often be very substantial and difficult to recover from, even when dumping ceases to occur'. This effect is exacerbated when dumping occurs in regional areas, where affected firms are often the largest employer, placing a 'heavy burden on communities and families'.[3]

2.7        On the other hand, the merits of an anti-dumping system have been questioned by others. While acknowledging that in instances of 'predatory' dumping,[4] action should be taken, it has been argued that more often than not, anti-dumping measures imposed by countries are 'naked protectionism', harming domestic consumers to the 'partial benefit' of domestic firms.[5] Ultimately, dumping promotes lower prices for consumers and increases competition in the importing market.[6]

2.8        The negative effects of anti-dumping actions on other sectors of the economy are also contentious. For example, the Australian Steel Association (ASA) highlighted the case of the steel sector, in which many steel imports are produced to order and are not supplied ex stock of the overseas mill. The ASA notes that 'the Australian users and stockists in competition to Australia's sole upstream, vertically integrated steel producers, factually cause the goods to be imported, and as such they have to pay for those goods'.[7] In other words, importers may not always be able to substitute towards domestic production. Take the example of JELD-WEN Australia. Dr Silberberg told the committee that:

There are a number of areas of building activity where there is a sole manufacturer of a product in Australia. That relates to steel and glass. Imports play an important part in meeting shortfalls in domestic supply. That is particularly the case with clear float glass. There are many small and medium sized businesses that rely on the availability of competitively priced imports of glass for their business.

If we look at the glass manufacturing sector, there would be fewer than 300 people involved in the direct manufacture of glass in Australia. JELD-WEN alone employs 4½ thousand people in the manufacture of windows and doors and their installation, but they are not the only player. There are thousands and thousands of people in downstream processing and fabrication. Their voice is rarely heard in this area of anti-dumping. Typically, the most vocal players are the local manufacturers. That is not a criticism; it is just an observation.

...

One of the issues that we are confronted with is that, if we were to have duties increased on some intermediate goods, where duties do not apply to the final product there is an additional possibility of import leakage of fully fabricated products. That is pertinent to windows. There are price points on clear flow glass where it will be more economic to bring in fully fabricated windows, so we have to be careful. We could bring in fully fabricated double-glaze windows below the cost of what is being produced in Australia today. It is a real risk.[8]

2.9        The empirical literature further suggests that anti-dumping application behaviour in developed economies is influenced by changing macroeconomic conditions:

First, countries that experience a significant currency appreciation have industries that confront new competition from cheap imports after the shock, increasingly the likelihood of injury...industries that pursued antidumping investigations had an exchange rate whose value had depreciated less rapidly on average (9.60% versus 23.37%) in the prior year than non-initiating industries. Furthermore, AD-initiating industries were at points in the business cycle in which real GDP growth had recently been slower (3.29% versus 4.10%) than for non-initiators as well.[9]

2.10      Similarly, the role and reasoning behind the provision of subsidies by governments is also contentious. Some agree that for developing countries, subsidies may play an important role in the transformation of their economics from centrally-planned to market-oriented. They allow these countries to develop their markets to compete for a share in global trade.[10]

2.11      However, subsidisation is generally argued to have detrimental impacts on trade, manifested in artificially lower prices. It hurts the domestic industry in an importing country, exporters trying to compete in the subsidising country’s domestic market and rival exporters from another country when competing in third markets.

The Australian anti-dumping and countervailing experience in an international context

2.12      Some governments have established administrative systems designed to protect domestic industries from injury caused by dumping and subsidisation. Anti-dumping measures imposed under these systems generally take the form of import duties that are imposed by anti-dumping authorities on foreign exporters of the dumped goods. A related concept is countervailing measures, which are duties imposed on imports that benefit from any of a specified group of government subsidies and which cause or threaten material injury to a local industry producing like goods.[11] This inflates the price to a level comparable to the price in the importing country so that the export of the goods is no longer injurious to the domestic industry.

2.13      While Australia is historically one of the most systemic and prolific users of the anti-dumping and countervailing system, its share of anti-dumping measures in recent years has decreased, with the number of new anti-dumping measures falling from an average of 14 per year in the 1990s to around five a year over the past decade (Figure 2.1).

Figure 2.1: Australia's anti-dumping and countervailing activity

Figure 2.1: Australia's anti-dumping and countervailing activity

Source: Productivity Commission, Australia's Anti-Dumping and Countervailing System, Report no.48, 2009, p. 27.

2.14      There are a number of factors, both local and global, that have contributed to the declining use of the anti-dumping and countervailing system. A critical factor has been shifting trade patterns and the changing composition of industries traditionally at the centre of anti-dumping initiations and measures.

2.15      The changing composition of Australian manufacturing, for example, has resulted in many of the industries that used the system previously ceasing local production.[12] Compounding this trend is the more liberalised trade environment, and increased globalisation, which have encouraged greater importation of goods to complement local manufacturing, discouraging the resort to anti-dumping measures.[13]

2.16      In particular, the increased shift towards manufacturing products in Asia has led to increased anti-dumping initiations against countries in that region. The majority of Australia's anti-dumping and countervailing measures are aimed at Asian exporters, particularly China, which alone has attracted 12 anti-dumping measures over the past 15 years (Figure 2.2). China's emergence as a major export-oriented economy is reflected in its prevalence in anti-dumping measures imposed and the upward trend in anti-dumping initiations against China amid falling global initiations (Figure 2.3).

Figure 2.2: Australia's anti-dumping initiations and measures (January 1995–June 2010)

Figure 2.2: Australia's anti-dumping initiations and measures (January 1995–June 2010)

Source: WTO, 'Statistics on Anti-Dumping', 2011  http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/adp_e/adp_e.htm (accessed: 18 April 2011) .

Figure 2.3: Number of anti-dumping measures and initiations: China versus rest of world

Figure 2.3: Number of anti-dumping measures and initiations: China versus rest of world Figure 2.3: Number of anti-dumping measures and initiations: China versus rest of world

Source: WTO, 'Statistics on Anti-Dumping', 2011 http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/adp_e/adp_e.htm(accessed: 18 April 2011).

2.17      The 2009 Productivity Commission report, however, revealed that this absolute decline in anti-dumping measures and new investigations over the period masks:

(a) a higher success rate for anti-dumping duty applications, with nearly 50 per cent of cases initiated over the last decade leading to measures being taken, compared to one third of cases in the preceding decade; and

(b) an increasing proportion of measures being extended, with the average duration of measures increasing from 4 years and 7 months to 5 years and 2 months between 2002 and 2009.[14]

2.18      Countervailing measures tend to be imposed at a lower frequency than anti-dumping measures. Australia has only imposed 11 countervailing measures over the period January 1995–June 2010, with the majority directed at China (three measures), European countries (six measures), South Africa (one measure) and the US (one measure).

2.19      This mirrors the international experience. Over the January 1995–June 2010 period, countervailing measures imposed by members of the WTO totalled 143 measures compared to 3752 anti-dumping measures over the same period. Measures were primarily directed at minerals and base metal products, and agricultural products, with approximately 70 per cent of these countervailing duties directed at products from developing countries (with China and India accounting for 36 per cent of these duties).

2.20      One of the potential reasons for the significantly lower incidence of countervailing measures being imposed is the inherent difficulty in proving that subsidising is occurring, let alone causing material injury to the domestic industry:

Senator XENOPHON: ...in terms of the ACTU, you make reference to the... [the fact that] the granting of subsidies by foreign governments does not receive proper examination, as the focus is on dumping.

Mr Fetter:  Yes...our system does have a primary focus on dumping, whereas, if you look at the distortionary and unfair trade practices of some of our trade competitors, it would seem that as much if not more of the damage is done through the provision of subsidies... Complaints are not often brought in Australia on that basis, ...[one] response... is that it is much more difficult to establish that the subsidies are improper. Indeed, for instance, Australia subsidises primary, secondary and tertiary education, and we would not want foreign governments saying that is an unfair subsidy improving the quality of our workforce. So, for whatever reason, the law or maybe even the parties in Australia have not been as vigorous in tackling unfair subsidies as have other parties overseas, and we think that those subtle forms of trade distortion are probably as important as dumping is in terms of adverse effects in Australia...

What I am saying is that the existence of subsidies, particularly in countries like China, is often hidden and it would be an almost impossible exercise for a complainant company or even a complainant trade union in Australia to prove they did exist, particularly if there is a high evidentiary bar with an onus on the complainant to prove on the balance of probabilities that the subsidies were there and were unfair and illegal and were the cause of the low cost of the product. Again, there is an informational asymmetry here and my suspicion...it is the difficulty in gathering evidence of subsidies that means that you do not often see challenges to foreign subsidies under Australia's countervailing duties regime.[15]

International Rules—the role of the WTO

Options for recourse under WTO agreements

2.21      The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), negotiated by member countries sets out arrangements directed to the substantial reduction of tariffs and other barriers to trade, and to the elimination of discriminatory treatment in international commerce. As a signatory to the GATT, Australia is bound to ensure that its own laws do not breach its obligations under the agreement.

2.22      To ensure fair trade, the GATT makes provisions to allow member countries to take action against products that are demonstrated in terms of both the WTO agreements and domestic legislation to be dumped or subsidised. There are two WTO agreements that have been negotiated specifically for the purposes of providing members with options for recourse against dumping and subsidisation. These are:

2.23      The AD and SCM Agreements establish the rules and procedures that signatory members, such as Australia, must follow to both investigate allegations of dumping and/or subsidisation and the measures that can be imposed against them.

2.24      Under these agreements, investigating authorities have a 'fact finding' role, and must base their decisions on 'facts available'. They can only make a finding of injury caused by dumping or subsidisation based on 'positive evidence'. For example, in the case of dumping, investigative authorities must positively establish that (a) dumping is occurring and (b) dumping is causing 'sufficient' injury to the domestic industry. Investigative authorities can only determine causation after examining all relevant evidence before them, including other known factors that are causing injury to the industry.[16] 

2.25      The agreements prescribe the methodology and calculations required to determine variable factors (such as normal value, export price and dumping margins).  They also include detailed provisions on what factors should be considered during this determination, constraints on overall timeframes of investigation, and requirements related to the implementation and revocation of measures, consultation and public notification, and judicial review.

2.26      Despite these constraints, there is considerable flexibility afforded under the agreements. This accounts for the difficulties in collecting information to ascertain the variable factors, as well as the different economic frameworks of WTO members, particularly between developing and developed economies. This flexibility has resulted in important differences in the administrative approach adopted by international jurisdictions, which are discussed in more detail in chapter 3.

2.27      In addition, there are important distinctions between the two agreements due to the nature of the issues they are addressing. Dumping is an action taken by a company, which the WTO does not have jurisdiction over. As such, the AD Agreement is concerned with government actions against dumping.

2.28      In contrast, subsidies are based on government policies which are subject to the WTO’s agreements. The SCM Agreement disciplines both the use of subsidies by governments and the recourse that other governments can take.[17] Under the agreement, a member country could either initiate its own investigation and charge a ‘countervailing duty’ on subsidised imports found to be injurious to domestic producers; or they could use the WTO's dispute settlement procedure to seek the withdrawal of the subsidy or the removal of its adverse effects.

Settling disputes—the Dispute Settlement Body

2.29      Under the Dispute Settlement Understanding Agreement, WTO members can settle trade disputes through the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB). The dispute settlement process begins with consultations between the governments concerned. If consultation fails, a panel is established that assists the DSB make rulings or recommendations. The panel’s findings have to be based on the relevant agreements. Both the complainant country/countries and the respondent have an opportunity to appeal the panel’s decision. The DSB can either accept or reject the appeals report within 30 days, but rejection is only possible by consensus.

2.30      There are a number of disputes involving Australia as both a complainant and a respondent that are currently being settled under the Dispute Settlement Body. There are currently seven cases where Australia is the complainant, opposed to ten cases where Australia is the respondent to dumping complaints.

2.31      The DSB also monitors how adopted rulings are implemented. Any outstanding case remains on its agenda until the issue is resolved. The dispute settlement agreement stresses that 'prompt compliance with recommendations or rulings of the DSB is essential in order to ensure effective resolution of disputes to the benefit of all Members'.[18]

2.32      Failure to comply within specified timeframes with WTO rulings and recommendations could result in the complaining country or countries requesting permission from the DSB to impose limited trade sanctions in the same sector as the dispute to minimise the chances of actions spilling over to unrelated sectors. Otherwise, it could also result in the defending country entering into negotiation with the complainant to determine a 'mutually acceptable' form of compensation.

The WTO agreements: mere guidelines or legally binding agreements?

2.33             There are strong incentives for Australia to comply with its WTO obligations. Fundamentally, the AD and SCM Agreements are a product of intense negotiations and agreement between WTO members, many of whom are Australia's main trading partners. Discounting the importance of the WTO agreements would, in effect, divert Australia from international best practice. It would also serve to limit Australia's influence in changes to WTO jurisdiction and trade agreements as part of the Doha Round of negotiations or any subsequent negotiations. Indeed, the literature points to the problem of 'dirty hands', where:

...one country is afoul of the same legal provision that it accuses another of violating—which complicates the state's ability to get others to settle trade disputes on favourable terms.[19]

2.34      This reaffirms the multilateral nature of WTO dispute settlements, and the costliness of trade disputes, which often involve third parties and require countries to exhaust all avenues for consultation before proceeding to sanctions. As Busch et al. (2008) explain:

Yet another deterrent to an unmerited AD award is the prospect of having to mount a legal defence in the WTO judicial process, which involves nontrivial costs and staff time, especially because litigation commonly draws the participation of other interested parties (i.e., "third party" governments) in the dispute (Busch and Reinhardt 2006), and often entails successive rounds of appeal, compliance assessments, and arbitration.[20]

2.35      Assuming that non-conforming amendments are passed, and anti-dumping measures were imposed on the grounds established by the amendments, then WTO members representing the exported goods under question could raise a dispute with Australia over the imposition of these measures through the DSB. Supposing that the DSB finds in favour of the complainants, Australia would be obligated to amend its practices to conform to its WTO obligations. Failure to comply could result in the DSB paving the way for complainant parties[21] to impose sanctions on not only the direct industry involved, but potentially other industries, as well as the removal of any negotiated trade concessions. An empirical study that collated data on the level of compliance by WTO members with adverse DSB rulings found that:

The generally positive record of Members in complying with adverse rulings ... has been an important factor in the success of the WTO dispute settlement system to date. In approximately 90 percent of the adopted reports, one or more violations of WTO obligations have been found by panels and/or the Appellate Body. In virtually all of these cases the WTO Member found to be in violation has indicated its intention to bring itself into compliance and the record indicates that in most cases has already done so. It is noticeable, if not unsurprising, that compliance has been more rapid where the WTO violations can be corrected through administrative action as opposed to legislative action...As a final note, the overall positive record of Members in complying with adverse WTO rulings is reflected in, and confirmed by, the low number of cases where Members have sought and received authorization to impose retaliatory measures.[22]

2.36      Indeed, while many submissions praised what they perceived as a more lenient interpretation of the WTO laws adopted by the EU and the US, these jurisdictions account for approximately half of all adverse WTO rulings.[23] Importantly, following adverse WTO rulings, the US and the EU have largely brought their practices in conformity with the rulings, even when the decisions would have been unpopular domestically.

2.37      An illustrative example of the enforceability of WTO rulings is the recent dispute surrounding the "Byrd Amendment". In 2000, the United States enacted the Continued Dumping and Subsidy Offset Act of 2000, commonly referred to as the 'Byrd Amendment', which allowed for the redistribution of anti-dumping and countervailing duties to the petitioning industry. This amendment was challenged by eleven WTO members, including Australia, and was found by the DSB in 2003 to have violated WTO rules. The US did not repeal the amendment by the WTO deadline. Subsequently, Brazil, Canada, Chile, the EU, India, Japan, Mexico and South Korea requested and were granted authorisation from the WTO to suspend tariff concessions and other obligations against the US. Some of these retaliations were quite significant, with US exports subject to additional 15 per cent duties in the EU and Canada on 18 and 8 products respectively. Mexico and Japan soon followed, with duties imposed ranging from 5 to 30 per cent. In February 2006, the US repealed the Byrd Amendment, leading to countries such as Canada and Mexico ceasing retaliatory tariffs. Other retaliatory tariffs remain, however.[24]

2.38      This case demonstrates that amendments to domestic legislation which breach international agreements can have serious consequences and involve retributions that may remain in force for a prolonged duration, even well after rectifying actions are taken. What begins as a measure to enhance the system could result in damage to other non-petitioning industries and in effect, costly to the wider economy. For Australia, this issue is magnified given its economy is more heavily reliant on trade than the United States (see Table 2.1).[25]

Table 2.1: Trade indicators and trade policy (2007–2009)

I.        International Trade Comparisons

 

Trade per capita (US$)
2007-2009

Trade to GDP ratio (%)
2007-2009

Import duties collected to total imports (%)
2005-2007

Australia

19,463

44.4

2.3

Canada

27,888

65.5

0.7

United States

12,849

27.6

1.2

United Kingdom

23,573

56.9

n/a

II.      Australian Trade Statistics

Exports

 %

Imports

 %

Share of world exports

1.23

Share of world imports

1.3

Breakdown of Australia's total exports

Breakdown of Australia's total imports

(i) By main commodity group

 

(i) By main commodity group

 

Agricultural products

15.2

Agricultural products

6.2

Fuels and mining products

56.8

Fuels and mining products

13.9

Manufactures

14.9

Manufactures

72.2

(ii) By main destination

(ii) By main origin

China

21.7

European Union

19.7

Japan

19.5

China

17.8

European Union

8.7

United States

11.3

Republic of Korea

8.0

Japan

8.3

India

7.4

Thailand

5.8

Source: WTO, 'WTO Statistics', 2011, http://stat.wto.org (accessed: 14 May 2011)

2.39      The effects on trade that anti-dumping and countervailing applications can have are also well-documented. As the ASA told the committee:

...the very chilling effect of an initiated antidumping action, let alone the imposition of interim and periodic measures, is the lessening of competition in the Australia market for the goods concerned... We will just give a fairly recent example of one of our members down in Canberra a few weeks ago. Just with some of the [anti-dumping] rhetoric that has been understandably in play in recent times, their overseas supplier chose not to offer to supply them for that quarter. They said, 'We're not exactly sure what's happening and we don't want to pick a fight, so we'll just withdraw until we get a better understanding.' What does that mean for that business? He needs to deal with that. He either does not have material to value-add to—he has paint lines; it is a 50-year-old Australian business—or otherwise he counters that by holding increased working capital. That is a cost to his business which ultimately lessens his competitiveness.[26]

2.40      In particular, the threat of retaliatory action could have a substantial impact on investor confidence, as highlighted by a recent study which looked at the impact of EU retaliatory threats on the share market following the 2002 imposition of US steel safeguards. The study found that after announcements had been made that signalled to investors an increased likelihood of retaliation by the EU:

...firms within targeted industries experienced negative abnormal returns ranging from approximately -2% to -4%, with the largest wealth losses being suffered by firms threatened with the maximum 100% retaliatory tariff. Shareholders also generally responded positively to the early cancellation of the safeguards, which removed the risk of retaliation.[27]

Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page