Chapter 5
The transition to a permanent scheme
5.1
The global financial crisis constituted extraordinary circumstances
calling for unusual responses. As Professor Harper put it:
... the whole point of financial regulation is to achieve an
appropriate balance between competitive efficiency and system stability.
Something like the GFC obviously upsets that balance and raises the premium
which a government should place on system stability at the expense of
competitive efficiency, at least until things return to normal.[1]
5.2
While the Government has paid lip service to the need, once the global
financial crisis eases (and evidence exists that it already is), for a
transition to a more limited, permanent, scheme of depositor protection and no
support for wholesale fundraising, it has done little to indicate how or when
this might occur. This is despite calls by the Reserve Bank for the transition
to start soon:
For their part, banks will need to reduce their reliance on
the extended guarantees and stand on their own feet before too much longer. The
banks of the United States and Europe are starting down this path on their
wholesale issuance, having recognised that it is in their own interests to do so.
It would make sense for Australian banks, which have accounted for 10 per cent
of global issuance of government‑guaranteed bank debt over the
past nine months, to step up their efforts to do likewise.[2]
Removing the guarantees
5.3
Treasury is monitoring the situation:
...I think it is a little premature to be thinking about
exiting at this time...It may be that the second-tier banks will need the
guarantee longer than, say, the majors.[3]
5.4
There are risks involved in leaving the guarantee in place too long:
If you leave these things in place, you unduly strengthen the
institutions that are inside the cordon, relative to their competitors on the
outside of the cordon. The longer you leave it there, the more competitive
strength they gather, which is really drawn on the strength of the guarantee
rather than on competitive performance. In the worst case, you debilitate the
system by making life so difficult for those outside the cordon that they
eventually begin to fail or are absorbed by those inside the cordon and you
create for yourself an inner core in the system which becomes certainly very
stable but really too profitable for the long-term good of the efficiency of
the system.[4]
5.5
An opinion poll conducted in June 2009 suggested the public still wanted
the deposit guarantee in place then:
Only 30 per cent of those surveyed said they would be
comfortable keeping money in the bank with no guarantee. A guarantee of
deposits up to $50,000 would satisfy 50 per cent of the population. A $100,000
guarantee finds two-thirds public support, while a $500,000 guarantee brings in
80 per cent.[5]
5.6
Of course, most Australians prior to the crisis thought their funds were
already guaranteed!
5.7
The wholesale funding guarantee should be subject to a gradual
phase-out, or what the RBA and APRA have called a 'natural exit mechanism':
As market conditions normalise and funding markets ‘thaw’, it
is expected that it will no longer be commercially viable for entities to rely
on the guarantee.[6]
...at some point investors will no longer be willing to accept
the lower yields on guaranteed paper and banks will therefore no longer seek to
insure their debt.[7]
As the price and availability of credit normalises,
non-guaranteed debt issues will become relatively more attractive, and at some
point, paying the guarantee fee will become an uneconomic proposition.[8]
5.8
The Reserve Bank Governor was asked about this recently and commented:
On the wholesale front, when the pricing of the fee for the
guarantee was set it was set in a way that we hoped would be such that when
market conditions normalised it would be too expensive to issue with the
guarantee and would naturally therefore fall into disuse. We are probably not
that far actually from that stage. I think that it would be good for our
institutions to just start to issue in their own name anyway as much as they
can. That is happening in other countries. I think that conditions have pretty
much now sufficiently stabilised that it would be sensible for them to start doing
that even if it did cost slightly more in the short term, and I have said that
publicly.[9]
5.9
Professor Swan said that this might apply to some banks but perhaps not
the weaker banks:
I think that particularly the weaker banks who have trouble
borrowing will want to go on relying on the guarantees as much as possible...[10]
5.10
One foreign bank emphasised the risks from uncertainty about the removal
of the guarantees:
Certainty as to the mechanisms and timing of any changes or
removal of the Government Guarantee arrangements is critical to maintaining
confidence and stability in both retail and wholesale funding markets.[11]
5.11
There have been calls for considerable notice of any phase-out:
For the Wholesale Bank Funding Guarantee Scheme, the
Government will provide a minimum notice period of 12 months prior to the
closure of the Scheme to new issuance, and the Government will not provide such
notice prior to the point in time that funding markets have normalised for all
ADIs currently qualifying to utilise the Guarantee. (Investec believes that
such “normalisation” is unlikely to be achieved prior to 1 January 2010).[12]
...information about the removal of the bank funding guarantee
should be clearly communicated to the market well in advance of its scheduled
implementation.[13]
5.12
Even some critics of the guarantees believe it needs to be phased out
gradually rather than abruptly:
If the guarantee is now removed abruptly a flight of funds
from small financial institutions to banks is likely which may endanger the
very survival of these institutions. Consequently, the deposit guarantee roll
back needs to be done with caution.[14]
5.13
Specific timetables for removal have been suggested:
...a gradual reduction of the $1 million threshold to $50 000
over the next 12 to 18 months (and in line with market conditions) with that
level being retained for a further 12 months before being closed.[15]
I suggest that the government roll back the deposit guarantee
scheme in stages: to $100,000 by December 2009, to $60,000 by June 2010 and to
$20,000 by December 2010.[16]
5.14
The Tasmanian Government suggested that markets should have been
regarded as 'normalised', and so the guarantees withdrawn, once most of the
following conditions (Table 5.1) have been met for one to three months.[17]
Table 5.1:
Tasmanian Government criteria for normality
Source: Tasmanian Department
of Treasury and Finance, Submission 16, p 2.
International co-ordination of the transition
5.15
The Committee was presented with a broad consensus that the removal of
the guarantee should be related to similar action in other countries:
...we need to have a globally coordinated approach to
evaluating the application and then ultimate removal of guarantees.[18]
...any exit from the Guarantee Scheme for Large Deposits and
Wholesale Funding should be gradual and implemented in a coordinated way, with
other countries, in an atmosphere of international cooperation.[19]
We think that our banking system is strong enough to be a
magnet for funds so long as they do not have to compete against other banks
which have government guarantees. That is why the international agreement to
remove them all is important for us.[20]
...the issue of when the funding guarantee should be lifted is
one that is going to take an awful lot of international coordination.[21]
...the Government should also consider what international
practice is... so as to protect against any potential for a significant outflow
of funds from Australia that may seek to “chase the Guarantee” of other
jurisdictions.[22]
...given the interconnectivity of global financial markets, the
wholesale funding guarantee can only be removed when other members of the G20
do so.[23]
Australia could lead the way in discussions, but if Australia
just made an announcement then there would be a rash of money running out of
the country.[24]
...the guarantees should be removed in an orderly way,
coordinated with similar actions in the major European and North American
economies.[25]
...the removal of bank guarantee arrangements should be
coordinated with similar actions in key overseas jurisdictions to ensure this is
achieved in a smooth and non-disruptive manner.[26]
...it is also important to ensure that some kind of
coordination exists amongst countries for terminating the government backed
debt program.[27]
5.16
Treasury and the Reserve Bank have referred to global co-ordination:
Exit strategies from various actions that governments have
taken are matters that are being discussed in the G20, the Financial Stability
Board and other international meetings on these issues.[28]
...it is important to have some degree of coordination. I would
not say that everybody has to do everything all at once or that you need to
have some formal agreement because I think countries do have scope to go their
separate ways. What we do will partly depend on market conditions and what
happens in other countries. All of these things are part of ongoing discussions
through various international forums, particularly the FSB and the G20.[29]
5.17
Some other economies are planning to coordinate their measures. For
example, the Hong Kong Monetary Authority, Bank Negara Malaysia and the
Monetary Authority of Singapore announced recently the establishment of a 'tripartite
working group to map out a coordinated strategy for the scheduled exit from the
full deposit guarantee by the end of 2010 in their respective jurisdictions'.[30]
5.18
A recent press report warned that achieving global agreement will take
time:
...few expect a swift multi-lateral agreement given that some
national banking systems are still on life support.[31]
5.19
Some countries have indicated termination dates for their schemes,
although in a number of cases the original closing dates have already been
extended (Table 5.2).
Table 5.2: Expiry
dates for guarantee schemes
Source: RBA & APRA, Submission
7, p 5.
An ongoing deposit insurance scheme
5.20
There have been discussions about a possible deposit insurance scheme in
Australia for a long time. In mid-2008 Australia and New Zealand were the only
OECD countries not to have such a scheme.[32]
There are around 100 deposit insurance schemes operating around the world,
according to the International Association of Deposit Insurers.
5.21
Deposit insurance is regarded as a standard feature of the financial
system in much of the world:
Deposit insurance is a natural, optimal and permanent part of
the financial system architecture in every country in the OECD for very good
theoretical and practical reasons. It builds a firewall into the financial
system that prevents large shocks to the banking system propagating to the
household and business sectors.[33]
5.22
One reason deposit insurance had not been introduced in Australia is
that the 1996 Wallis Inquiry recommended against it.[34]
However the IMF supported such a scheme in its 2006 assessment of the
Australian financial system.[35]
Committee view
5.23
The Committee considers such an alternative should be considered as part
of the examination of options for an ongoing deposit guarantee.
The optimal cap for a permanent
scheme
5.24
The Council of Financial Regulators advocated an Early Access Facility,
which would provide early repayments of up to $20,000 per depositor in a failed
institution.[36]
In June 2008, the Government announced its intention to introduce a Financial
Claims Scheme along these lines.[37]
5.25
However, with the introduction of the guarantee schemes, deposits are
currently guaranteed up to $1 million under the Financial Claims Scheme. This
is believed to cover 99 per cent of depositors.[38]
5.26
There are a range of views about the appropriate cap for a permanent
deposit insurance scheme:
The monetary cap on deposit protection under the permanent
financial claims scheme should be set at a level well below $1 million. The
$20,000 threshold that was originally proposed is low relative to the
international standard.[39]
5.27
Some lessons for design of deposit insurance have been drawn by the run
on Northern Rock in the UK, the first on a UK bank for 130 years. The Reserve
Bank commented:
One aspect of the UK arrangements that has featured
prominently in the post-crisis evaluations is the design of the deposit
insurance scheme. Prior to the run, depositors were guaranteed to receive
repayment of the first £2 000 of any deposit in a failed bank, and 90 per
cent of the next £33 000. There were, however, no arrangements in place to make
these repayments to depositors in a timely fashion. The combination of the 10
per cent ‘haircut’ on repayments above £2 000 and likely delays in repayment
are widely thought to have contributed to the scale of the run.[40]
5.28
A key lesson in this is the timing issue. Whatever is put in place must
deliver quick access to a substantial portion of depositors' funds.
5.29
An IMF survey has referred to average coverage levels in (pre-crisis)
deposit insurance schemes being around one to two times per capita GDP,
although they note:
That ratio, however, is only a statistical description of
deposit insurance systems and is not meant to be considered as a desired design
feature.[41]
5.30
Given Australia's GDP of over $1 trillion and population of over 20
million, in round terms, one to two times per capita GDP would translate into a
range of $50 000 to $100 000 as a coverage limit.
5.31
Some features of pre-crisis deposit insurance schemes are given in Table
5.3. Many of the schemes are long-established and are generally compulsory. One
way in which they attempt to reduce moral hazard is by having risk-related
premia.
Table 5.3: Pre-crisis
deposit insurance schemes
|
Enacted |
Compulsory? |
Risk-adjusted
premium? |
Coverage US$'000
(ratio to per capita GDP) |
Austria |
1979 |
√ |
x |
22.6 (0.7) |
Belgium |
1974 |
√ |
√ |
22.6 (0.8) |
Canada |
1976 |
√ |
√ |
42.8 (1.2) |
Finland |
1969 |
√ |
√ |
28.3 (0.9) |
France |
1980 |
√ |
√ |
79.1 (2.8) |
Germany |
1966 |
√ |
√ |
22.6 (0.8) |
Hong Kong |
2006 |
√ |
√ |
12.8 (0.6) |
Japan |
1971 |
√ |
x |
82.3 (2.6) |
Netherlands |
1979 |
√ |
x |
22.6 (0.7) |
Norway |
1961 |
√ |
√ |
282.5 (5.8) |
South Korea |
1996 |
√ |
x |
42.0 (3.4) |
Sweden |
1996 |
√ |
√ |
30.9 (0.9) |
Switzerland |
1984 |
x |
√ |
22.3 (0.5) |
UK |
1982 |
√ |
x |
57.2 (1.9) |
USA |
1934 |
√ |
√ |
100.0 (2.8) |
Source: Secretariat, calculated from data in Hoelscher,
Taylor and Klueh, The Design and implementation of deposit insurance Systems,
IMF Occasional Paper 251, 2006.
Senator Alan Eggleston
Chair
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page