Additional comments - Senator Andrew Murray
1 Price and behaviour
The Australian Democrats have long been campaigners for
comprehensive alcohol review and consequent reform. The Hansard record will
show years of campaigning on alcohol issues, including extensive amendments to
improve the system.
The Democrats have no issue with the price of alcohol being
increased via excise if the social intent is to reduce the harmful consumption
of alcohol. We support measures including price measures that will actually
significantly reduce the harm caused by excessive consumption of alcohol. The
Democrats have no set level of excise or alcohol tax in mind that will achieve
this goal. The level at which excise is set is always going to be a matter of
judgement, a behavioural guess, and the Treasury are as good at that sort of
estimate as any.
What we take issue with are excise actions in one alcohol
category in isolation of action in other alcohol categories which are capable
of easy substitution for the targeted category.
The behavioural logic is easy. Price
affects consumption. Raising the price should lower consumption. However
if there are easy substitutes no significant fall in consumption will occur. So
you have to raise the price of all substitutes too.
What was disturbing at both the June Senate Budget Estimates[1]
and at the Committee Inquiry is that the question of substitution has been
largely swept aside or been diminished in importance. Yet it is central to the
question of whether this pre-mixed drink excise increase will work at all in
reducing the harmful consumption of pre-mix drinks, particularly by young
people. Issues relating to the RTD tax increase were discussed at length during
the Economics Committee's session. Extracts from the exchanges on these issues
are at Attachment 1.
At the time of the announcement of
this excise increase for pre-mixed drinks the Democrats said it must be matched
by other action. We said that the government had correctly identified price as
helping curb alcohol abuse. When certain products are flavoured,
sweetened, packaged and marketed to attract the young, then price is an obvious
weapon to use to restrict consumption. Unfortunately young people also can and
do binge drink on beer and wine, as do adults that binge drink.
Despite helpful reform in the
last decade, the federal government's alcohol tax policy lacks integrity and
consistency. In 2002 I had this to say on the matter, and I drew out five
main conclusions in my Supplementary Remarks:
- The Government’s new alcohol tax system is a considerable
improvement on the former regime (an improvement furthered by this Bill);
- Further improvements to the alcohol tax regime could make a
material contribution to improved health outcomes;
- The value-added Wine Equalisation Tax (WET) is a failure in two
respects. It has created a low-price cheap-alcohol cask market that is at the
centre of alcohol abuse, and it is punishing the premium and small business
bottled wine sector;
- The Government’s low-alcohol policy is poor, since it only
focuses on beer, when there are clear opportunities for incentives to encourage
low alcohol RTDs and wines; and
- There are significant continuing inequities and anomalies in
excise taxation, among others in RTDs, Brandy, Cider, and mid strength beer. [2]
The previous Coalition Government did nothing to address
these policy weaknesses, nor did it follow up on the unanimous Senate Economic
Committee's later recommendation in 2006 that a pricing regime be introduced to
encourage the consumption of low-alcohol RTDs.[3]
Alcohol is alcohol, whatever its source. Yet the
alcohol pricing regime is selective between and within alcohol categories on
random grounds. The detrimental effect of alcohol comes from the amount
consumed, not from its type, its packaging or its flavour.
Labor has shown it has the
courage to take on the spirits lobby. It now needs courage to take on the wine
and beer lobbies. Three principles must be followed:
- All products in the same product
category should be taxed the same. For instance, brandy should be taxed
at the same rate as whisky, rum and white spirits, which it is not.
- All products with the same alcohol
level should be taxed the same. Full-strength beer (which is determined
at 4.65+ percent) should be taxed the same as pre-mix drinks at 4.65
percent. If increasing excise curbs binge drinking on RTDs, then beer
excise should also be increased immediately to curb binge drinking on beer;
plus wine should be taxed volumetrically not by value to achieve a similar
outcome.
- The low-alcohol and mid-strength beer
excise should be matched with a low-alcohol and mid-strength RTD excise rate.
Recommendation
1:
That
the Henry Tax Review examining alcohol taxation have regard to these
three general principles:
- all products in
the same product category should be taxed at the same rate;
- all products
with the same alcohol level should be taxed at the same rate; and
- the low-alcohol
and mid-strength beer excise should be matched with a low-alcohol and
mid-strength RTD excise rate.
If this
government is really serious about alcohol policy, when is it going to announce
its response to the Senate's unanimous call, agreed to on 13 March 2008, for a full
review? The Senate motion said:
(1) That the
Senate, noting concern in the community at the abuse of alcohol, asks that the
Government refer the following matter to a parliamentary committee, an
appropriate body or a specially-established task force for inquiry and report: The need to significantly reduce alcohol abuse in
Australia, especially in geographic or demographic hot spots, and what the
Commonwealth, States and Territories should separately and jointly do with
respect to:
(a) the pricing of alcohol,
including taxation; (b) the marketing of alcohol; and (c) regulating the
distribution, availability and consumption of alcohol.
(2)
In undertaking the inquiry, regard is to be had to: (a) economic as well as
social issues; (b) alcohol
rehabilitation and education; (c) the need for a flexible responsive and
adaptable regulatory regime; and (d) the need for a consistent
harmonised Australian approach.
Recommendation 2:
That the Government comply with the Senate motion of 13 March 2008 calling for a comprehensive holistic review of all aspects of
alcohol.
Political
and industry concern with respect to the RTD increase has been two-fold:
- that this excise
increase is actually a revenue measure disguised as a social policy; and
- that this is a tokenistic response to
a serious issue which will not work because substitution will occur.
The Democrats are prepared to give
the Government the benefit of the doubt that they do desire to significantly
reduce harmful drinking. Even so, there are real weaknesses in their approach.
In an important sense, the
alcopops issue is not a side-issue. It is a worrying signal that the new
Government has already dropped its approach of a principles-based or
alternatively an evidence-based policy response to significant social and
economic problems. If it does that elsewhere or more broadly, then Australia is headed for
troubled policy waters.
Raising price to tackle over-use
is a legitimate behavioural tool, and is commonly used in sin taxes (drinking,
smoking, and gambling) but there is no policy consistency here. If
you raise the price on one alcohol category you have to raise the
price on all categories, otherwise the substitution effect will undo your
policy intention.
Imagine you are a teenage
girl (...well try), and the price of pre-mix vodka and lemon
goes up 70% - do you stop drinking; drink less; switch to much cheaper
wine with a higher alcohol content (cask wine is hardly taxed at
all); switch to cheaper beer with the same alcohol content (beer is
preferentially taxed); switch to cheaper cider (preferentially taxed); or
buy a spirits bottle and a cool drink bottle and mix your own much cheaper
vodka and lemon?
The evidence in the Majority
Report is that the jury is not yet in, the evidence is still being collected,
but there will be behavioural changes, including some present RTD drinkers
drinking less or drinking less harmfully. My own very long experience in this
policy field still leads me to expect that the majority of those who drink for
the alcohol effect will simply switch from RTDs to cheaper products.
This view was supported by
evidence provided to the inquiry including the following real life example from
Dr Raymond Seidler, specialist
in addiction medicine practising in Kings Cross NSW and Secretary of the
Eastern Sydney Division of General Practice:
'Recently, our division of
general practice hosted a youth Forum for all the high schools in our area.
Attendees included 75 students from variety of private and public schools. My
presentation was on intoxication and the subject of premixed alcopops came up
in discussion. The consensus of opinion amongst the young people was that
raising the excise on premixed drinks would do nothing to reduce the level of
binge drinking amongst their cohort. Many of the young women said they would
just resort to cheap drinks or buy their own spirits, and at the same time
purchase a bottle of soft drink to mix with either vodka, bourbon or whisky.
They also explained to me and to their teachers that they would seek out
cheaper alcohol alternatives like wine in casks which they explain could be
procured for around $10 for 4 Litres.'[4]
The majority of evidence to the committee expressed the
opinion that the RTD measure should not stand alone but should be part of a
comprehensive suite of measures to address the harmful consumption of alcohol.
2 A summary of Democrats' views on alcohol
Alcohol is the most commonly used drug in Australia and the
second greatest cause of drug-related deaths and hospitalisations after
tobacco. Almost three and a half thousand deaths are attributed to alcohol
consumption each year. The financial cost of alcohol misuse in Australia has
been estimated at more than $15 billion per year.[5]
A comprehensive national alcohol strategy is needed that focuses on causes and
effects and remedial responses; on regulation, controls, and education; and on
more effective taxation. Our national health depends on it.
In the 2007 federal election the Australian Democrats
outlined their 'Action Plan'. This was framed in the following way:
Implement and properly fund
the National Alcohol Strategy informed by:
-
An inquiry into what Commonwealth, States and Territory governments
should separately, jointly and consistently do with respect to the pricing
marketing and regulation of alcohol;
- A comprehensive study by the
Productivity Commission of the full economic and social costs of
alcohol-associated problems; and
- Ongoing independent research to identify the causes and
effects of alcohol abuse in Australia, and to identify policies to
significantly reduce alcohol abuse and the harm caused by it.
The Democrats advocated: Stronger
regulation and intervention
- Direct a standard 2% of
alcohol tax revenue (about $160 million per annum) towards promoting the
responsible consumption of alcohol and emphasising the dangers of alcohol
misuse; and, assisting people to limit or abstain from drinking, with
particular emphasis on the young, pregnant women and those indigenous
communities at risk;
- Provide policing assistance to
indigenous and other communities wishing to enforce their ‘dry’ status and
heavy penalties for ‘grog-runners’ and substantially improve access for
indigenous people to prevention and treatment services ;
- Negotiate tighter liquor
licensing laws with the States, with stricter enforcement and higher
penalties for supplying alcohol products to under-18 year-olds and reduce
the number and density of liquor outlets and hours and days of sale;
- Ban products designed to
appeal to young people;
- Restrict alcohol advertising
and promotion, including banning alcohol-industry sponsorship of social,
sports and entertainment events;
- Establish an independent
statutory body to develop and run an independent regulatory system funded
by hypothecated alcohol taxes;
- Apply health warnings on
alcoholic beverages, including the warning that there is no safe level of
consumption for minors or for pregnant women;
- Support high levels of random
breath testing in all jurisdictions, including ensuring that a high
proportion of drink driving offenders are successfully referred to
intervention programs; Increase the availability and use of ignition
interlock devices both on a voluntary basis and as part of sentencing of
convicted drink drivers; Foster mandatory referral of severe or recurrent
drink driving offenders to alcohol treatment services;
- Establish a national network
of sobering up facilities and increase funding for withdrawal and
treatment facilities including greater use of screening for alcohol
related problems, encouraging the use of effective pharmacotherapies and
increasing brief alcohol interventions in primary care settings;
- Support decriminalisation of
public drunkenness and diversion to sobering up facilities;
- Provide targeted funding for
specialised programmes for children raised in substance misusing families;
and
- Make it the law clear that liquor license holders and
alcohol suppliers have a duty of care for the safety of consumers of their
products; or, reverse the changes to the Trade Practices Act that removed
the capacity for litigation to recover health care costs from alcohol
suppliers responsible for or associated with personal injury caused by
conduct related to alcohol consumption.
A much improved taxation
framework
- Revise the alcohol taxation
system so that all alcohol products are taxed according to volume
according to alcohol content, and wine and cider are not taxed by value;
- Introduce the same tax and
excise treatment to low and mid strength RTDs and wine as is applied to
low and mid strength beer;
- Ensure imported products are
not priced differently to domestic products of the same alcohol class, and
brandy is not priced preferentially to other spirits; and
- Establish the ATO as the single government agency
responsible for the collection of revenue and the administration of excise
equivalent alcohol goods.
The Democrats said that issue one was inquiry and
research:
An independent inquiry is
needed, with particular regard to significantly reducing alcohol abuse in Australia,
especially in geographic or demographic 'hot spots'. We need to establish what
the Commonwealth, States and Territories should separately, jointly and
consistently do with respect to
- the pricing of alcohol,
including taxation;
- the marketing of alcohol; and
- regulating the distribution, availability and consumption
of alcohol.
The inquiry must take into account economic and social issues;
alcohol rehabilitation and education; the need for a flexible adaptable
regulatory regime; and, the need for a consistent harmonised approach.
Australia’s per capita alcohol consumption has fallen by
about 25% since it peaked in the mid-1970s, but there is much more to be done.
Concern is justified at the social and economic costs of alcohol abuse, at
binge drinking, and at the costly and socially harmful health problems arising
from excessive alcohol consumption.
Although drinking is often glamorised by popular culture and
viewed as a rite of passage by many, alcohol misuse contributes to high-risk
binge drinking, depression, anxiety, physical and sexual violence, crime rates,
road accidents and injuries, to name a few of many undesirable social effects.
There are high risk groups, including the young and certain indigenous groups.
The only way to deal with risk is to use credible genuinely independent
empirically based research. The challenge is to deepen our understanding of
the underlying motivation of why some people drink at harmful levels.
Evidence provided to the committee agreed that our
understanding of why young people drink to excess is limited as noted by Dr Michael
Tedeschi, Fellow, Royal Australasian College of Physicians, who told the
committee 'Alcohol consumption and the various ways alcohol is consumed by
young people is a highly complex matter in that we have a very poor
understanding of the patterns of why people drink the way they do'.[6]
Good social and health outcomes are a key objective of a
coherent set of alcohol policies. Good alcohol policies can make a positive
contribution to these outcomes. It is possible to moderate behaviour, but it
is hard to change behaviour. To change behaviour you have to know what causes
behaviour. That is why the Democrats place such emphasis on independent
Government-funded research.
The Democrats said that issue two was regulation.
The federal Government collects about $8 billion annually in
alcohol revenue, and the alcohol industry is a considerable sector of our
economy. Against that must be set the huge costs of alcohol abuse. The policy
task is to lower these costs substantially. Alcohol requires regulation.
Universal prohibition does not work. Neither does treating alcohol as a run-of-the-mill
consumer good.
Alcohol abuse affects many, but certain indigenous
communities and specific age groups such as underage drinkers are high risk. Australia’s
alcohol regulation is shared between Federal, State and Local authorities.
Coordination and consistency is essential, and is currently missing. Control
policies include taxation, licensing regulation, access, hours of sale, and
disincentives for anti-social behaviour such as drink-driving. Control
policies should regulate the price marketing and availability of alcohol in a
manner that minimises harm and encourages responsible consumption.
Educational programs for parents and the community on the
dangers and inappropriateness of supplying alcohol to underage drinkers are
ineffective. Enforcement is poor. Drink driving laws have been spectacularly
successful in reducing the levels of anti-social drink-driving behaviour on our
roads. We need a similar breakthrough in the area of supply of alcohol to minors
by parents and friends.
Alcohol marketing, promotion, advertising and sponsorship
are permitted almost without restriction in Australia. There is industry
self-regulation of advertising but many problems exist with this system.
Research shows that advertising does have a role in drinking behaviour and
attitudes towards alcohol. Products designed to appeal to young people should
be banned.
Random breath testing has been one of the most effective
programmes for reducing alcohol related morbidity and mortality. It is most
effective when it has a high profile and large numbers of people are routinely
tested. Health warnings on labels have been adopted in some countries and have
contributed to greater awareness of the risks associated with alcohol use.
The Democrats said that issue three was price and
taxation.
The Democrats have always supported the taxation of alcohol
as a standard regulatory mechanism to prevent alcohol being cheaply available,
and as a means of contributing to the public cost of harm arising from alcohol
consumption. The Government’s broad conceptual framework for alcohol taxation
policy in Australia means alcohol taxation and pricing levels are better than
they were but further improvements to the alcohol tax regime could make a
significant contribution to improved health outcomes.
The policy framework still lacks sufficient coherence. The
framework has three key compartments: products with less than 10% alcohol
content; products with more than 10% alcohol content; and wine and cider.
Until this RTD excise increase the Government had recognised
the merit of taxing most products under 10% alcohol content at similar taxation
rates, regardless of the form of the alcohol. This tax is levied
volumetrically as excise or customs duty on the amount of the alcohol in the product.
The Government has also recognised the merits of taxing all products over 10%
alcohol content at a higher rate. This too is sound policy.
However a fatal policy flaw is that the taxation of wine and cider is still
based on the value, not alcohol volume, of the product. Alcohol is alcohol. A
standard drink is a standard drink. Alcohol taxation should reflect this
truth. It is better tax policy to tax each alcohol product on its alcohol
content rather than its value.
This view was expressed by many to the committee such as
Diageo Australia which told the committee they supported a uniform volumetric
approach to taxing alcohol products based on the rationale that 'the effect on
the body is the same whether the alcohol is consumed from a beer, a wine, or a
spirit.[7]
ADCA told the committee 'it is hard to think of any public health-based
justification for differences in taxation between different alcohol beverages
of equal strength.'[8]
The RACP noted that 'Current alcohol taxation does not make any economic sense,
let alone public health sense'.[9]
Many other submissions such as AER, noted the complexity and
anomalies in the current alcohol taxation system.[10]
In pursuing these alcohol taxation issues, Senator Murray
provided questions for a number of organisations (see Attachment 2) and
received responses including the comments referred to above.[11]
The Government’s low-alcohol policy is poor. It only focuses
on beer and fails to provide clear incentives to encourage low-alcohol
ready-to-drink alcohol products (RTDs) and wine. The Democrats have long
campaigned for changes to alcohol excise to encourage the production and
consumption of low-alcohol products, whatever their form. A key feature of any
coherent alcohol policy should be the promotion of low-alcohol products.
The Democrats have consistently recommended that low-alcohol
packaged RTD products be subject to the same tiered excise regime that has
successfully encouraged the production and consumption of low-alcohol packaged
beer.
There was evidence presented to the inquiry that low-alcohol
products should be encouraged. For example, Mr Smeaton, Chief Executive Officer
of the Alcohol Education and Rehabilitation Foundation told the committee:
Beer currently has an incentive to produce a low-alcohol beer
because the first 1.15 per cent of alcohol is not taxed. There is no incentive
in that area for either wine or spirits. That might be something that could be
considered in the context of a public health outcome...[12]
The value-added Wine Equalisation Tax (WET) is a failure in
two respects. It has created a low-price cheap-alcohol cask market that is at
the recorded centre of alcohol abuse. Contrary to the myth, wine is also at the
heart of alcohol abuse, not at its periphery. Secondly, it continues to punish
the premium bottled wine sector. WET provides wine producers with an incentive
to produce low-value wine. Research in the Northern Territory demonstrates that
increasing the price of cask wine substantially reduced alcohol abuse.
The Royal Australasian
College of Physicians told the committee that 'The
College is of the view that in Australia, the introduction of the Wine
Equalisation Tax (WET) primarily benefited cask wine producers (mostly large
multi-national companies) at the expense of Australia’s premium wine producers.
An unintended negative consequence of the WET has been the effect on the health
and well-being of many disadvantaged communities where the low price of cask
wine is a primary factor influencing the quantity of alcohol consumed.'[13]
Beyond increasing the price of cask wine, a volumetric wine
tax would also lower the price of higher value wines, which are over-priced by
virtue of the WET. This, in turn, would stimulate that sector of the industry,
and create jobs. There is consistent support for the view that all alcohol
should be taxed volumetrically as alcohol regardless of its type. The
Australian Medical Association supports moving to a volumetric wine tax. ADCA
and other health lobby groups advocate a volumetric wine tax.
Inequities and anomalies continue in alcohol taxation. For
instance, imported goods such as bourbon and brandy have tax advantages over
domestic products. Brandy is concessionally taxed to other sprits. These
policy differences are unnecessary and should be ended.
At present Customs is responsible for administration (i.e.
licensing and audit) and policy of imported spirits and RTDs. However,
the ATO is responsible for administration (i.e. licensing and audit) and
Treasury is responsible for policy on locally produced spirits and RTDs.
This creates unnecessary duplication, and a single administration, under the ATO,
would significantly reduce red tape and costs.
Evidence to the committee called for a comprehensive review
of alcohol taxation and the government has committed to a review of alcohol
taxation issues as part of the Ken Henry review of taxation.[14]
Senator Andrew Murray
Australian Democrats, Western Australia
ATTACHMENT 1
DISCUSSION OF RTD TAX INCREASE DURING
SENATE BUDGET ESTIMATES HEARINGS
Senate Economics Committee, Proof Committee Hansard, 3 June 2008, pp. 53-55
Senator MURRAY—Thank you.
I have read, over several decades, papers concerning price effects with alcohol,
including the effects of substitution as well as the effects of an aggregate
increase on price. Nearly all the elasticity models I have seen are complicated
by the substitution issue. In certain categories, substitution is automatic.
For instance, if you raise the price of one beer, people switch to another
beer. That is almost an equal effect whereas it is different if you get
radically different types of alcohol?
Mr Ray—That
is correct.
Senator MURRAY—Were you
able to use the overseas studies on price effects in alcohol to moderate your expectation
of the effect of increasing price so radically in just one area where it is
plain that direct substitution is possible—by which I mean you can take a
bottle of rum and a bottle of coke and mix them yourselves—and indirect
substitution is possible whereby you can move from an RTD to, say, a cheap cask
wine?
Mr Ray—Yes.
Mr Brown—In
looking at the overseas studies, that was one of the areas where there was
fairly mixed evidence. The studies tended to show that, if you look at spirits,
that spirit based drinks tended to be complements to things like beer, that
beer tended to complement wine, and that spirits and wine tended to be substitutes.
Mr Ray—That
is complement with an ‘e’, isn’t it?
Mr Brown—Yes. But the
actual significance of some of those results is rather dubious. While you can
get reasonable estimates of price elasticities from studies, usually the
cross-elasticities are far less significant in terms of statistical
significance, so they are less reliable results. The other issue for RTD
beverages is that there are very few studies, if any, that directly look at RTD
beverages that are out there in terms of price elasticities and that may
reflect that the amount of data or the length of time data is available may be insufficient
to do a valid econometric analysis of them. The issue in respect of
substitutions, say, from RTDs to spirits in terms of the costing is less
significant as well because now with the excise rate per LAL of alcohol set at
the same level, if you substitute the same amount of alcohol for the same amount
of alcohol in a different beverage it does not actually affect the revenue
estimates that we would derive.
Senator MURRAY—The
evidence, as I understand it, with respect to cross-elasticities of demand, is
that where there is insufficient data you therefore have to look at the motive
or the prime determinant of consumption, and if the prime determinant is effect
then, as I understand the documentation I have read, substitution is more
likely to occur than if the prime purpose of consumption is alternative, such
as quality, packaging or something of that sort. The inference around binge
drinking, of course, is its effect—basically an ingestion of large amounts of
alcohol to get drunk—which would imply that substitution would be relatively easy
for that class of drinker. It may be different, for instance, for a plumber
aged 30 who likes to drink his Bundy and Coke. But did you use a kind of
commonsense appraisal, if you like, to supplement your advice which would cover
off that area of motive and likely effect?
Mr Ray—In terms of the
specifics about motives of binge drinking, you are probably better asking the department
of health, but this is about the aggregate consumption of RTDs. The costing is
not about binge drinking, per se.
Senator MURRAY—Yes, but
if I may interpolate on this basis: if I understand Senator Coonan’s question correctly
and my own, we are concerned about the aggregate consumption of alcohol, within
which RTD is one component, for which if you adjust the price effect, if the
primary motive is simply to get drunk which is binge drinking, then you are
likely to see a substitution effect, which is contrary to the elasticity
measures you have been relying on to give the government advice.
Mr Ray—As
Mr Brown has said, it depends on what they substitute into.
Senator MURRAY—There
are only two choices, as I understand it: alcohol or drugs.
Mr Ray—I was actually
referring to which different type of alcohol you might substitute into.
Senator MURRAY—If
you say that the anecdotal evidence so far is that substitution is occurring,
the
question we would all be looking
at is how large that substitution effect is.
Mr Ray—I think we would
be cautious about short-term responses—studies which purport to show a
shortterm response. I think we would want to wait to see how the long-term
response settles down.
Senator MURRAY—I can
assure you when a retailer places an ad they know the next day whether or not the
ad was effective. When there is a price movement, they know the next day
whether price is effective. I understand you being cautious because that is
your job, but the market effects will, in fact, be immediate. That is the
nature of substitution: the market effects are immediate. I will leave it
there.
Senator COONAN—Following
on from Senator Murray, you would obviously be aware that on 28 May there was
released findings from an AC Nielsen survey from the latest data collected from
liquor retailers across Australia. Were you aware of that?
Mr Brown—Yes.
Senator MURRAY—Just
to clarify my own view: I do accept that increasing price will affect consumption.
My point is you that you have got to increase the price of substitutes, as
well. Do you think a measure to decrease consumption of alcohol, in addition to
this one, could be to raise the price of all substitutable products? That is
essentially what Senator Eggleston was saying. You have to bring up the price of
cask wine, beer and all substitutable products if you want to reduce
consumption for the effect that we are discussing. Do you agree with that?
Mr Ray—This
is getting quite close to policy advice, but I do not disagree with the idea
that the demand curve is downwards sloping.
Senator MURRAY—Thank you.
Senate Economics Committee, Proof Committee Hansard, 3 June 2008, pp. 68-70
Senator MURRAY—I have
some questions quickly on the same topic. I just want to discuss this question of
closing an anomaly which has been widely used as a justification for this price
increase in RTDs. For the purposes of your answer, let us talk about a beer at
five per cent alcohol by volume, an RTD which is spirits based at five per cent
alcohol per volume and an RTD which is wine based at five per cent alcohol per
volume. Each of those has got one constant and that is five per cent, but the
beer taxation is less because there is a 1.15 per cent tax free threshold. The
spirits is more because its rate is higher. This is before the change. Wine is
less because wine is a value-added tax, not a volumetric tax, so wine is the
cheapest of all.
Mr Ray—That
is correct.
Mr Brown—If
the wine based was an RTD it would be taxed as another excisable beverage if it
was five per cent.
Senator MURRAY—And
it is only when it reaches a certain percentage of alcohol that it has to be—
Mr Brown—It has to meet
the definition of wine.
Mr Ray—Which I think is
about eight per cent.
Senator MURRAY—I will
just focus on the beer and the spirits RTD. Apart from the fact that beer is cheaper,
why is it considered to be an anomaly when an RTD spirits based at five per
cent alcohol by volume is taxed at nearly the rate of beer at five per cent
alcohol by volume? I have not understood this idea of raising the price of a
spirits based RTD closer to the full bottle spirits rate, because, as you know,
it is normally but not always 40 per cent alcohol by volume. What does it mean
in policy terms—and I am not asking you a policy question—from Treasury’s
perspective?
Mr Ray—I think this is a
benchmark question. What the government has said is that what this measure does
is tax alcohol in spirits at the same rate, whether those spirits are sold in a
bottle just in the spirits and then mixed with some other thing like cola or
lemonade, or whatever these things are mixed with, or it is sold in a
pre-packaged product where it is pre-mixed. That is what the government has
said.
Senator MURRAY—Assuming
you are dealing with rational people, that would be because a spirits based drink
at five per cent alcohol by volume has eight per cent of the impact of a beer
based drink at five per cent alcohol by volume? Is that what lies behind it?
Mr Ray—That
is asking me to impute a motive. I think that the simple way to explain what
the government has been saying is that spirits will be taxed the same no matter
how they are packaged and sold.
Senator MURRAY—I accept
that there are anomalies in customs and excise taxation of alcohol; in fact I know
and you know that to be the case and I am not unhappy for them to be resolved.
What I cannot work out is where the policy rationale lies, because I am told by
the drug and alcohol people—not by the industry, but by the people who are
trying to stop the abuse of alcohol—that alcohol is alcohol. Quite simply,
alcohol by volume is the same: wine, spirits, beer or cider, it does not matter
what you drink, it has the same effect.
Mr Ray—Unlike
Senator Conroy I am not a teetotaller and I probably—
Senator MURRAY—My
question is: if the desire is to change the anomaly, has Treasury given advice
to the government to equalise the tax, and equalise the price effects,
therefore, and the demand effects, on all products relative to the alcohol by
volume?
Senator Conroy—I
would only disagree with you on the basis that I think you are suggesting the
rational basis for the comparison. I am not sure that when you sit down—
Senator MURRAY—Senator
Conroy, you know nothing about grog.
Senator Conroy—I actually
worked in a liquor store for five years. I was a very safe employee and I did observe
a lot of behaviour.
Senator MURRAY—Deviant
behaviour.
Senator Conroy—I am not
sure about your alcohol stores. The ones I worked in were not deviant behaviour.
I am not sure that the underlying assumption that you make is an accurate one.
When I worked in stores I have literally watched people walk in and they were
not sitting there comparing the alcohol content, they were comparing the price.
Senator MURRAY—Since I
have been listening to these answers, essentially I have heard the correct answers
from Treasury—namely that they have looked at this as an economic matter and
that the health effects, the alcohol effects, considerations are those that
concern the health department. But from a rational Treasury point of view, I
cannot see the tax rationale of this. I just cannot see it. I need a better
explanation from either you, who I do not trust on these matters—
Senator Conroy—As a
teetotaller, I do not take that personally.
Senator MURRAY—But
I have not heard a decent response on that aspect from Treasury. I have heard
the economic response.
Mr Ray—As I
said, this measure equalises the excise equivalent customs duty on spirits, no
matter how it is sold. I think that is actually explained in the budget papers
as being one of the policy rationales that the government has. I do not want to
mislead you. I think we in the Treasury would agree that if you increased the price
of something the demand for it would fall—other things being equal.
Senator MURRAY—What
I get from that is, ‘Spirits bad; wine and beer good,’ and the amount of
alcohol in it is irrelevant. And yet the government is selling this as an
assault on the consumption of alcohol.
Senator Conroy—We have
also indicated we will have a look at excise taxes in the Henry review. We are moving
to look at this in a much broader range, which I think you have suggested—
Senator MURRAY—Which I
appreciate, Minister.
Senator Conroy—and
we have taken up as a worthwhile policy discussion. Some of the questions that
you have put in here will naturally fall to be dealt with within that review
process.
Senator MURRAY—You see,
Minister, through the chair, I am caught in a bind, in that the Treasury have defended
the previous policy and now defend this policy, and the two are markedly
different. Of course the officers have to do that; I accept that. But I think
what you have done is created a greater anomaly, which you now need to fix
through the Henry review. What I want to do, Minister, is ask for your
commitment on behalf of the government that you will look at this whole area
objectively and with a view to maximising the social benefit and minimising the
social harm from the consumption of alcohol of all types. That is what I want.
Senator Conroy—I think we
have given that public commitment to examine these issues thoroughly as part of
that review. I am happy to reiterate that. The former government introduced the
new category of excisable alcohol that had the effect of reducing the effective
rate of excise on spirit based ready to drink beverages by 40 per cent, so I
would challenge you on your suggestion that we have created a bigger anomaly. I
think that was an anomaly that was created then and we have addressed that by
reversing the decision. Spirits are taxed at the same rate, no matter how they
are consumed. But the overall point that you make is a worthy one and I am sure
it will be considered in detail.
Senator MURRAY—I hope so.
ATTACHMENT 2
QUESTIONS FROM SENATOR MURRAY TO CERTAIN GROUPS MAKING SUBMISSIONS TO
THE SENATE COMMUNITY AFFAIRS COMMITTEE INQUIRY INTO READY TO DRINK ALCOHOL
BEVERAGES
1 The Government has
increased the excise on ready-to-drink (RTD) alcohol beverages. Do you agree
with these broad propositions made in the general debate with respect to this
alcohol policy?
-
Price is an important tool in reducing
alcohol abuse;
- Higher prices for alcohol reduce
consumption;
- There are anomalies in the taxation of
alcohol that need fixing; and
-
Binge drinking needs to be addressed by
increasing the price of ready-to-drink pre-mixed spirit-based beverages.
2. Do
you agree that the price of alcohol affects consumption? Do you support the
specific taxation of alcohol products (through customs and excise duties and
through the Wine Equalisation Tax (WET)), all of which have the effect of
raising the price of alcohol products? If you do agree with these statements
do you support:
- Some alcohol types being tax-free?
Why/why not?
- Some higher alcohol products being
taxed less than some lower alcohol products? Why/why not?
- Different tax rates for the same
product? Why/why not?
3. With respect to your
answers to Q2, are you aware that - and what is your opinion of these policies:
- A rebate of $500 000 is payable in WET paid annually by any
producer or producer group, the effect of which is to make tax-free wine bought
at the cellar door of small producers?
- All wines, meads, perries, ciders and sakes are subject to the
WET, and this means that these products are often taxed less than lower alcohol
products subject to customs and excise duties?
- Where beer is consumed on the premise, such as a bar, a draught
beer is taxed less than the same beer in a bottle?
4. Do you think there is a
case for beer products with the same alcoholic content being taxed at different
rates? How do beer products that have the same alcoholic content being taxed
at different rates contribute to less alcohol abuse? In answering these questions
please give your views on low-strength packaged beer paying 5 times the tax of
low-strength draught beer; mid-strength packaged beer paying 1.9 times the tax
of mid-strength draught beer; full-strength packaged beer paying 1.4 times the
tax of full-strength draught beer?
5. Do you think there is a case for spirit products that have the same
alcohol content being taxed at different rates? How does a concessional tax
rate for brandy reduce alcohol abuse when it has the same alcoholic content as
rum or any other spirit? What is the justification for brandy not paying tax
equal to the spirits rate?
6. What is the
justification for having a 5% ad valorem (value-added) customs duty payable on
imported RTDs and imported spirits but not on imported beer? Why should only
some imported alcohol products pay customs duty but not others? Should all
imported alcohol products pay customs duty, or none? Why?
7. Do you agree that
alcohol is alcohol, whatever its source, and that ingestion of (say) alcohol at
5% by volume, will have the same or very similar effects on the consumer
regardless of the product that the 5% is found in?
- If you disagree with that statement please indicate why?
- If you agree with that statement do you agree with the
proposition that all alcohol should therefore be taxed by volume, so that
whatever the type of product, the taxation is the same for a given % of alcohol
in the product?
8. If there is to be a
customs duty on imported alcohol, should it be based on alcohol by volume or
should it be based on value? Why?
9. Are you aware
that wines, meads, perries, ciders and sakes are taxed by value but spirits,
spirit-based drinks and beers are taxed on their alcohol by volume? Which
policy is fairer and why? Which policy contributes more to addressing the
abuse of alcohol, or delivers better health outcomes, and why?
10 Is cheap alcohol a risk with regard to binge-drinking
and alcohol abuse? As an example, does cask wine feature in binge-drinking or
alcohol abuse? Is it the case that a standard drink
of cask wine and many RTDs average a similar alcohol content? Is it the case
that RTDs pay 14 times the tax paid by cask wine? Do you believe cask wine
should be taxed on its volume of alcohol content, so raising its price?
11. It is the case that many
beer products have a similar alcohol content to packaged RTDs, so why is the
excise duty payable on a mid-strength can of RTD greater than the amount
payable on a full-strength can of beer? How does that contribute to
addressing the abuse of alcohol, or delivering better health outcomes? Given the similarity of alcohol content for both
products, why should RTDs and beer be taxed differently?
12. Do you support
differential tax rates so that full-strength beer is taxed more than lower strength
beers to encourage the consumption of lower strength beer? Do you believe a
similar policy should be introduced for all other alcohol products, in
particular RTDs?
13. Is it the case that a
cider product pays tax of 26c whereas a spirits-based RTD pays tax of 84c (per
standard drink)? Why is this difference good policy?
14 Is it the case that
under WET, a wine-based RTD would need to have an alcohol content of at least 8
% before being taxed? Is it the case that some wine-based RTDs may bear no WET
at all if the producer is in receipt of the WET producer rebate? If wine-based
RTDs are taxed according to their value under the WET and have to be at least
8% alcohol by volume to be taxed under the WET, isn’t this an encouragement to
produce wine-based RTDs with a lower price and higher alcohol content than
spirit-based RTDs? How does that contribute to addressing the abuse of
alcohol, or delivering better health outcomes?
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page