Chapter 3 - Options for reform
Introduction
3.1
Discussion in the preceding
chapters has adopted the view that a ‘crisis’ is not evident in either public
hospitals or the Australian health system. However, participants who have
presented submissions and evidence to this inquiry have been almost unanimous
in arguing that significant problems do exist and that the public hospital
system is under considerable pressure. Most participants viewed recent
Commonwealth Government initiatives on private health insurance with some
concern. This was particularly the case with regard to the 30 per cent
rebate which most participants believed was unlikely to relieve demand on
public hospital services, despite costing in excess of $2 billion per
annum. Arguably, the 30 per cent rebate can be seen to run counter to the
Medicare principles of universality, equity and access. Little evidence was
presented showing benefits for public hospitals from the rebate. However, the
Commonwealth Department of Health and Aged Care (DHAC) submitted that the full
impact of the 30 per cent rebate on public hospitals ‘will only be able to
be assessed in the long term’.[189]
3.2
More than half of the
submissions to the inquiry proposed minor options for reform to address the
problems facing public hospitals, while around 25 per cent proposed major
changes to the current system. While the available options for reform are
virtually limitless, the one option which no-one appears to favour is standing
still and opting for the status quo. This view was summed up by the Australian
Nurses Federation (ANF) who told the Committee that ‘we are not interested in
maintaining the status quo, rather we are advocating for change’.[190] Accordingly, the status quo is not
considered in this chapter as a serious option for dealing with the challenges
facing Australia’s public hospitals. A rationale for reform of the existing
arrangements can be found also in the following comment from Professor Scotton:
it is now almost a quarter of a century since the introduction
of Medibank marked the start of a new era in the financing of Australian health
services. Since then, or rather since its reintroduction under the name of
Medicare in 1984, a structure designed to meet the needs of the mid-1960s has
remained remarkably stable.[191]
3.3
Prior to proposing and
discussing options for change, the following questions need to be asked:
-
what are the problems which the options are
required to address? and
-
what are the components of the current system
which are not open to change?
3.4
It is clear from evidence presented
to the inquiry that the key problem which needs to be addressed as a priority
is the fragmented nature of the roles and responsibilities of the Commonwealth
and the State and Territory governments and the associated cost shifting, in
the funding and delivery of public hospital services and in the health system
more generally. It is clear also that this is no easy task with several
previous attempts at reform having foundered.
3.5
While there is general
agreement that problems do exist, consensus virtually ends there. As was argued
in chapter 1, different players, particularly the two levels of government,
discern different problems and therefore may be more disposed to certain
options than others. Some participants in the inquiry as well as commentators
maintain that while problems and challenges exist, only minor, marginal or
incremental change is required. Others see that major change may be desirable
but is not likely to be achieved and believe therefore that change at the
margin is preferable to no change at all. Still others argue that in order to
address the current problems in a sustainable manner, major change is required.
A selection of different perspectives on reform is presented below:
-
the Health Department of New South Wales argued
that its position, which it regards as one supported by a wide range of forums
and reports, is ‘for essentially not a fundamental reform’;[192]
-
Professor Hindle, by contrast, believes that a
one-off, total redesign of the health system is required, which could be financed
by the $2 billion cost of the 30 per cent rebate for private health
insurance;[193]
- the starting point for discussion of change
needs to be redefined, according to Professor Stephen Duckett, who argues
that:
responsiveness to consumers, enhancing equity of access, or
equitable financing could all be postulated as ongoing frames for health system
reform. The major problem of Commonwealth/state relations in health might thus
be that the present systems of financing health distorts how health system
issues are considered and inappropriately defines the starting point for health
policy discussions.[194]
-
this point was raised also in the joint
submission by the Australian Healthcare Association (AHA), Women’s Hospitals
Australia (WHA), and the Australian Association of Paediatric Teaching Centres
(AAPTC) who argued that:
there needs to be a move away from discussions between
governments the nature of which is their relative contributions to health care.
These have been no more than blame shifting exercises and have done nothing to
enhance the health of the community.[195]
-
Monash University’s Centre for Health Program
Evaluation (CHPE) believes that the answer to the question of how Australia is
to finance its health care needs is not known. It argues that while choices will
depend on a number of technical/economic relationships (which are not well
understood), we need to acknowledge that choices also involve values and
ideology.[196]
3.6
At the core of all options for
reform are trade-offs between benefits and drawbacks. There are no options
which are easy and straightforward to implement. Thus, the question emerges:
has the problem(s) become of sufficient concern that action is imperative?
Aspects of the health system off
the reform agenda
3.7
Prior to examining different
options for reform, it is arguably necessary first to discuss the elements of
the Australian health system, especially those elements integral to the public
hospital system, which are immutable and not open to change. Few participants
in this inquiry have proposed that the fundamental basis of the Australian
health system, universal public insurance through Medicare, should be targeted
for reform. Indeed, although the inquiry’s terms of reference did not require
it, around 25 per cent of submissions took the opportunity to outline their
support for universal access to health care and/or the Medicare system. This
action was bolstered by over 5000 postcards, letters and e-mails expressing
wholehearted support for Medicare and the public hospital system being received
by the Committee.
3.8
In the Committee’s view, the
following aspects of the Australian health system are off the agenda for
reform: universal public health insurance through Medicare, financed by
taxation; subsidised out-of-hospital medical and diagnostic services; and
public hospital services provided free-of-charge. The Committee is not, in the
main, presenting options which will undermine principles fundamental to the
Australian health system. However, several options for reform, particularly
those relating to funding issues, are quite far-reaching in their impact on
governments. The Committee is concerned that some evidence has indicated that
the key principles which underpin Medicare - universality, equity and access -
are not guaranteed for all Australians with regard to public hospital services
and other health services. The Committee considers that these principles are
central to the Australian health system and the options for reform discussed
below are presented as a means of better achieving universality, equity and
access in the public hospital sector.
Options for reform
3.9
In a research paper prepared
for the Committee, CHERE categorised options for reform into three broad levels
(note that there is some overlap between the different levels) as follows:
- Reform
proposals relating to fundamental overhaul of the current funding and
delivery arrangements:
- reforms relating to how services are funded and
delivered; and
- reforms relating to how health care financing is
raised.
- Incremental
reform proposals, proposing changes at the margin or changes to a specific
sector (partial reform):
- reforms relating to how services are funded and
organised; and
- reforms relating to how health care financing is
raised.
- Specific
reform proposals addressing specific problems identified in the public
hospital system or related health services.
In addition to this categorisation, CHERE evaluated each
proposal in categories one and two against a range of criteria, including how
the proposal could be expected to impact on universality, equity and
efficiency. The description and evaluation of the options for reform in this
chapter are largely drawn from CHERE’s research paper. Where appropriate,
evidence from the inquiry has also been included.
Funding and delivery of services: proposals relating to fundamental
overhaul
3.10
Most of the proposals involving
major reform of funding and delivery of health services related to
rationalisation of Commonwealth and State roles. The motivation for these
proposals was reducing duplication and overlap between the Commonwealth and
States/Territories, reducing the scope for political game playing around
funding issues and removing incentives for cost-shifting. Essentially three
broad options for reform of Commonwealth/State roles were proposed:
-
Commonwealth to take responsibility for funding
and delivery of health services;
-
States/Territories to take responsibility for
funding and delivery of health services; and
-
pooling of Commonwealth and States/Territories
funds at the regional/population group level.
3.11
While these options for reform
are essentially aimed at rationalising Commonwealth/State overlap of
responsibility, and removal of incentives to shift costs between levels of
government, they may also address some of the other issues raised in
submissions, such as continuity of care and equity of access to services.
The single funder model: evidence
3.12
More than 25 per cent of
submissions proposed that a single funder model be adopted. Proposals differed
as to the degree of funding responsibility; for example, 14 per cent
suggested that the Commonwealth should assume responsibility for funding public
hospitals, while others proposed that one level of government should assume
responsibility but were indifferent as to which level of government. Some
submissions proposed that one level of government should assume responsibility
for particular aspects of public hospital services only, such as
pharmaceuticals or nursing home type patients in public hospitals. Others
proposed that the Commonwealth should take responsibility for funding the
entire health system.
3.13
A number of participants in the
inquiry proposed that a single level of government should assume responsibility
for funding public hospital services as a means of overcoming cost shifting and
as a way of overcoming the current split of roles and responsibilities between
the Commonwealth and State and Territory Governments in health financing. It
was argued that adoption of a single funder model would enhance the cost
effectiveness of health care services.[197]
The ACHSE believed that a single funder ‘would remove cost shifting and focus
accountability for the use of funds in terms of their health effect’.[198]
3.14
Noting that the New South Wales
Minister for Health had argued on several occasions for a single level of
funding for the Australian health care system[199],
the Director-General of the New South Wales Department of Health expressed his
personal preference ‘that there be a pool of funding nationally and that the
states be the purchasers’.[200] The
Queensland Government was more specific, arguing for the adoption of ‘a
funder/provider model, with the state being the provider of services and the
Commonwealth being the funder of services’.[201]
3.15
The Australian Health Insurance
Association (AHIA) took this proposal one step further, suggesting that what is
required is ‘one agency that is paying the bill or negotiating the price’ and
that ‘we should be aiming for a situation where the person who purchases all
health services can make some rational decisions about where is the best place
to buy’.[202] In other words, it was
proposed that the most cost effective service to meet the needs of the patient
would be purchased, rather than the patient being directed towards a particular
service on the basis of who pays for the service. The AHIA noted that ‘the
Coordinated Care Trials are already moving in that direction’.[203]
3.16
The HCC supported the use of
the Commonwealth as a single funder and proposed that a pilot project be
conducted in each of two States to evaluate the proposal. This concept had been
supported by Western Australian consumers in an earlier consultation process
conducted by the HCC. In these pilot projects, ‘the Commonwealth would take
responsibility for the funding, management and organisation of outpatient
services, discharge planning and care in the community’.[204]
3.17
Professor Richardson advised
the Committee that while there was not a simple case for proposing one level of
government over the other, the arguments in favour of a single funder were
strong. He argued that under a single funder, ‘the health system for the
population will be improved’[205] and
that a single funder overcomes the artificial financial barriers which operate
under the current arrangements. In addition, a single funder ‘has an incentive
to get a better and cheaper system because they cannot cost shift. So it is
desirable from both the point of view of allocation and cost control’.[206]
3.18
In addressing the question of
which level of government should become the single funder, Professor Richardson
and CHPE made the important point that ‘it is not sensible to discuss the
relative merits of a particular tier of government in abstract from the
organisational detail-the particular model-which is envisaged’.[207]
3.19
CHPE discussed the pros and
cons of the Commonwealth or the States and Territories being the level of
government responsible for public hospital and health funding. The arguments in
favour of the Commonwealth as a single funder include: a greater revenue base;
the likely economies of scale from a single, larger bureaucracy; and less likelihood
of ‘single States implementing foolish reforms’. CHPE argued that with the
States as the funders that diversity and experimentation will be enhanced and
that “dynamic efficiency”-the likelihood of achieving maximum improvement
through time-requires the diversity that would be provided through a
State-based system’.[208]
3.20
There are also drawbacks in the
States and Territories being the responsible level of government. For example,
the joint submission from the AHA, WHA and AAPTC argued that their proposal for
a basic package of care was made in response to:
the wide variations in access to the basic healthcare package
across State and Territory jurisdictions. These variations are due to
differences in policy and funding levels of State/Territory governments.[209]
The AHA, WHA and AAPTC proposed that the Commonwealth should
be the single funder for the basic package of health care.
3.21
The New South Wales Government
pointed out that awareness of the inadequacies of the current arrangements is
not a recent phenomenon and many attempts had been made since the late 1980s
‘to initiate processes that might lead to fundamental changes’.[210] Reasons offered by the NSW
Government as to why these attempts had generally failed included:
-
lack of sponsorship at the Commonwealth level;
-
government’s acknowledgment of public support of
Medicare;
-
reluctance of States to become exposed to risks
of open-ended programs;
-
difficulties in getting genuine reform proposals
considered by Ministers; and
-
lack of clinical leadership and consensus.[211]
3.22
The joint submission from the
Royal Australasian College of Physicians (RACP), the Australian Consumers’
Association (ACA) and the Health Issues Centre offered four possible options
for reorganising the financing and delivery of public hospital services, including
three possible versions of a single level of government assuming full
responsibility for funding and organisation of public hospital services or the
health system as a whole:
-
Commonwealth takes responsibility for funding
and organisation of public hospitals and integration with general practice and
other health services;
-
Commonwealth takes responsibility for all health
care delivery; or
-
States/Territories take responsibility for all
health care delivery.
3.23
However, the groups were not
optimistic that any of these options would be acceptable to either the
Commonwealth or the States and Territories and felt that ‘it is most likely
that the current system will remain’.[212]
This is a discouraging viewpoint given the range of evidence and views of
participants on the importance of addressing the roles and responsibilities of
the two levels of government in the public hospital sector and the Australian
health system. In the view of the RACP, ACA and the Health Issues Centre:
the best that can be hoped for is a structural reorganisation
that articulates and simplifies existing responsibilities; for example, one
level of government funding and organising the provision of pharmaceuticals
and/or the funding of all non-inpatient care.[213]
3.24
The New South Wales Government proposed
a similar model, albeit with a broader focus. It proposed that the Commonwealth
assume responsibility for funding all medical and pharmaceutical services in
public hospitals through the MBS and the PBS as well as responsibility for the
funding arrangements for nursing home type patients in public hospitals.[214] The Commonwealth already funds, via
Medicare, rebates for all out-of-hospital medical and diagnostic services as
well as similar services for private inpatients. The Commonwealth already
subsidises PBS pharmaceuticals outside of public hospitals and also provides
considerable subsidies for aged care accommodation. The mechanisms are clearly
in place to permit the Commonwealth to assume such wider responsibilities. The
States and Territories would obviously need to contribute some funding to these
arrangements.
3.25
It may not be desirable,
however, to extend the MBS to the remuneration of medical practitioners for
their services in public hospitals. Generally speaking, medical practitioners
are currently remunerated by public hospitals on the basis of their time rather
than what particular procedures or tests are undertaken. The Commonwealth, if
it was to fund these services via the MBS, would provide remuneration on the
basis of what the practitioner actually did, using the MBS item numbers for the
particular procedures and/or tests. Under these arrangements, practitioners
would presumably be required to accept the 85 per cent MBS rebate for each
procedure/test.
3.26
It should be noted that if the
Commonwealth was to assume the role of a single funder, it would not
necessarily have to extend the MBS to the payment of doctors in public
hospitals. Existing sessional and salaried arrangements could continue to apply
or alternative methods of remuneration could be investigated.
Commonwealth as the single funder:
assessment
3.27
This model was more commonly
suggested as a solution to cost shifting and overlap or roles and
responsibilities than other models. This may reflect a number of issues or
concerns including:
-
the need to ensure national consistency in
access to services and the level of services provided;
-
the fact that the Commonwealth has greater
revenue raising powers;
-
the fact that the Commonwealth currently has
responsibility for open-ended benefit programs (MBS, PBS) which are the most
variable in terms of utilisation; and
-
the view underlying some submissions that the
Commonwealth has been more pro-active in setting national health policy and
driving micro-economic reform in health.
3.28
In general, submissions which
put forward this proposal as a direction for reform did not suggest mechanisms
by which the Commonwealth would take responsibility for or manage services,
particularly public hospital services. This is an important issue, because the
Commonwealth role in provision of services (across a broad range of services
and portfolios of government) is generally one of funding programs, rather than
hands-on management. However, some submissions suggested that the Commonwealth
could act as a purchaser of public hospital services, using casemix funding
(this does not address the broad range of other services such as community
health services, which States/Territories provide). Other submissions proposed
that the mechanism by which the Commonwealth would assume responsibility for
funding and delivery would be through regional budget holding, with the
Commonwealth acting as a funder of services which would then be purchased by a
regional health authority (which may also be a provider). This is discussed in
more detail later in the chapter.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Commonwealth to
take responsibility for funding and delivering services
|
Universality
|
Maintained by this
proposal
|
Equity
|
Impact on equity
unclear
|
Efficiency
|
May reduce
cost-shifting, but impact on overall costs unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
No direct impact -
depends on how the model is implemented
|
Consumer choice
|
No direct impact
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Indirect improvement
possible because of reduced incentive for cost-shifting
|
Continuity of care
|
Indirect improvement
possible because of reduced incentive for cost-shifting
|
Feasibility
|
Key issue is
establishing mechanisms for C/W to manage services
|
Evidence based
|
Not applicable
|
States/Territories as single funders: assessment
3.29
Fewer participants suggested
this model as a solution to the Commonwealth/State overlap issues. However,
those submissions that did propose it noted the fact that the
States/Territories have established infrastructure for managing hospital and
community health services. They also argued that this model may be more
feasible to implement. The main obstacle to this model is the open-ended nature
of the MBS and PBS. This, combined with the large geographical variation in
utilisation of Medicare funded medical services (raised by the Queensland and
Tasmanian Governments and discussed in the previous chapter) means that the
States/Territories would be reluctant to assume responsibility for funding
these programs without either significant change to taxation powers, or
significant change to the method of funding these programs.
3.30
With either proposal for one
level of government to assume responsibility for the funding and provision of
services, it needs to be recognised that incentives for cost-shifting exist
wherever there are different pools of funds for different programs. While this
becomes a major political issue when the different pools of funds are provided
by different levels of government, there will still be cost-shifting incentives
if a single level of government provides different pools of funds for programs
which it manages. Thus, the most effective options for rationalisation of roles
and responsibilities involve major change to the funding of services at the
ground level, which could be achieved through pooling of funds.
3.31
The issue is how flexible are
funding arrangements. These need to be flexible enough to permit providers to
make decisions based on local needs. However, there is currently much variation
between States in the way that services are provided and a lot of variation in
the per capita utilisation of services, for various reasons.
Assessment
against criteria
|
States to take
responsibility for funding and delivering services
|
Universality
|
Risk that states may
provide different level of services - need to maintain national policies and
monitoring
Impact on equity
unclear
|
Equity
|
Efficiency
|
May reduce
cost-shifting, but impact on overall costs unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
No direct impact -
depends on how the model is implemented
|
Consumer choice
|
No direct impact
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Indirect improvement
possible because of reduced incentive for cost-shifting and improved links
between community based and hospital based services
|
Continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Key issue is
maldistribution of medical services and fiscal powers of states/territories
|
Evidence based
|
Not applicable
|
Pooling of Commonwealth and States/Territories funds:
regional budget holding
Regional budget holding: proposal
for Regional Health Agencies
3.32
A developed proposal for
regional budget holding was provided in the joint submission by the AHA, WHA,
and AAPTC. In essence, this proposal is for the establishment of Regional
Health Agencies (RHAs) as statutory authorities at arms length from government.
Each RHA would serve a geographically-defined catchment area and would be
responsible for planning and purchasing the basic healthcare package for its
population. The Commonwealth would allocate funding to the RHAs on the basis of
a population-based, needs-adjusted formula. The AHA, WHA and AAPTC propose that
funding for the RHAs would be capped, but that each agency would have ‘total
flexibility to move funds across existing programs in response to population
requirements and availability of providers’.[215]
3.33
Under this proposal, the
opportunities for cost shifting would be minimised and the duplication of
responsibilities for funding and policy would be overcome. Other key features
of the RHA model include:
-
in addition to its single funder
responsibilities, the Commonwealth Government would also have sole responsibility
for national health policy;
-
regulation of the RHAs would be the
responsibility of one level of government-the AHA, WHA and the AAPTC do not
express a preference for which level of government should have this
responsibility, although if the RHAs are to be regulated in a ‘nationally
consistent manner’,[216] as they
propose, it would seem logical for the Commonwealth to also be the regulator;
-
each RHA would negotiate service contracts with
a range of providers. These contracts would prescribe quality, price and volume
of services. It is envisaged that, where appropriate, provider contracts
‘should be specified at the level of the whole episode of care, not the
setting’ and should ‘also specify whole of life healthcare requirements, not
just episodes’;[217]
-
continuity of care and service coordination
would be achieved by the RHA as the single purchasing agency being responsible
for all funds for its population and the translation of these funds into the
service contracts;
-
following the allocation of funding by the
Commonwealth, all risk associated with the procurement of the basic package of
care rests with the RHAs;
-
methods of remuneration of providers would be
specified by the RHA in the service contracts and could be drawn from block
contracts, capitation, case/episode payments and fee for service. The method of
payment adopted in the contracts would ‘minimise incentives for overservicing
and maximise opportunities for coordination of care across settings’;[218]
-
providers would be able to provide services
outside the basic package, with funding provided through optional private
health insurance, direct payments by the patient or other arrangements, such as
for particular groups such as veterans; and
-
explicit and transparent guidelines for the
rationing of the basic package would be incorporated into the funding agreement
between the Commonwealth and the RHAs which would in turn incorporate this into
service agreements with providers.[219]
3.34
The National Rural Health
Alliance (NRHA) offered its support for regional budget holding and recommended
that the Senate ‘take a long term interest in proposals to establish Regional
Health Authorities as fundholding agencies of the Commonwealth to purchase and
provide health services for their regions’.[220]
3.35
Professor Richardson also supported
the regional model, arguing that:
the regional level is an attractive administrative level because
you can take into account the idiosyncrasies of the area, the relative supply
or deficit of services, and you can plan more easily.[221]
3.36
Adoption of a regional model
would address many of the issues around the roles and responsibilities of the
Commonwealth, and the States and Territories, although it would effectively
restrict the States and Territories to a role as providers of services through
their public hospitals and community health services. However, this would
remove the possibility under the current system of variability in service
provision in geographically adjacent areas, such as Albury and Wodonga, which
are subject to different approaches and priorities by their respective State
governments. While regional agencies such as the RHAs may be more responsive to
the needs of their local communities than the States and Territories, the
proposal for the Commonwealth alone to be responsible for national health
policy may be problematic. Some form of mechanism, perhaps the establishment of
State-wide consumer forums, as proposed in the report of the NSW Health Council
would be necessary to permit local input into national policy formulation.
3.37
Major benefits of this proposal
include a more patient-centred approach where the needs of patients are
preferred over the requirements of providers and funders. Duplication and cost
shifting would be minimised, if not eliminated. The details of exactly which
services are included in the basic package of care would be likely to determine
its acceptance by the community. The disadvantages of regional budget holding
include the difficulty that many special services are only provided at a
national or State-wide level and that these would need to be funded by a
separate mechanism. Provisions would also be needed to ensure there were no
restrictions on access by people temporarily outside of their home region.
Coordinated Care Trials
3.38
An example of budget holding,
albeit on a smaller scale than proposed above can be found in the current
trials of coordinated care. The trials of co-ordinated care are built around
the concept of case management, whereby a care co-ordinator (often a GP) works
with the patient to develop a care plan to meet the health care needs of the
patient. The care co-ordinator then purchases the full range of required health
services using funding which is pooled by the Commonwealth, States and
Territories. The trials of co-ordinated care have been primarily directed at
people with chronic and/or complex, ongoing illnesses who require a wide range
of services and whose needs are not always met in a timely fashion by
Australia’s health system. The types of services which may be purchased by the
care co-ordinator are not restricted to those available under government-funded
schemes. The objective is to ‘provide the right care at the right time’.[222] The nine general trials which
operated in five States and the ACT concluded in December 1999. The four
Aboriginal Coordinated Care trials operating in two States and the Northern
Territory are continuing in 2000 under transitional funding. The final
evaluation of the trials is yet to report.
Regional budget holding: assessment
3.39
This model was proposed in a
number of submissions in different forms, and represents an extension of
existing models such as coordinated care trials or multi-purpose services.
Pooling of funds requires that there is a regional budget holder (for example,
a Regional Health Service) which may be responsible for purchasing services, or
which may be both a provider and purchaser of services. For this model to
operate beyond a trial context would entail significant change to funding,
particularly of medical services in the community. One option would be to cash
out the region’s existing utilisation of Medicare and PBS funds, and combine
these with State/Territory funding which may be population based to a region or
casemix based funding to hospitals and other health services. However, if this
were done on a national basis, it would entrench existing inequities in health
care funding and access to services. Therefore, a more realistic alternative
would be to fund regions on a needs adjusted population basis, which would, in
effect, redistribute medical Medicare and PBS funds.
3.40
A related but separate model of
pooling funds is based on arrangements currently being piloted, particularly
for Indigenous population groups, involving ‘opting out’ of Medicare.
3.41
A number of issues arise in
considering how either of these models of pooling of funds would be put into
operation. To maintain universality, equity of access and national consistency
in service provision, the Commonwealth and/or States/Territories would need to
establish clear policy guidelines determining the nature of services provided
by a region and how services would be funded. This may limit the scope that the
regional manager has to achieve efficiencies in service provision. For example,
if the model entailed the maintenance of fee-for-service funding of medical
services, this would have significant budgetary implications for the regional
manager. Alternatively, putting this model into operation may entail
fundamental changes to the way medical services in the community are funded,
particularly for general practice (eg capitation funding), to ensure that it is
feasible.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Commonwealth
and States/Territories to pool funds: regional budget holding
|
Universality
|
Maintained by this
proposal if national guidelines on services established
|
Equity
|
Impact on equity
unclear
|
Efficiency
|
May reduce
cost-shifting and increase competition but impact on overall costs unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
Consumer participation
could be enhanced if the model involves regional management with consumer participation
|
Consumer choice
|
May indirectly reduce
consumer choice because of regional budget holding role
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Potential to enhance
appropriateness of care
|
Continuity of care
|
Potential to enhance
continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Key issue is
establishing appropriate population based funding and mechanisms for
purchasing medical/pharmaceutical services
|
Evidence based
|
Coordinated care trials
provide some evidence, but generalisability to broader context unclear
|
Funding and delivery of services:
incremental/partial reform proposals
3.42
Incremental or partial reform
proposals were also largely focussed on rationalisation of Commonwealth/State
roles. Here the principal concern was addressing incentives for cost-shifting,
with less direct emphasis on the issues of removal of duplication, or on the
other potential outcomes such as increasing access to services or ensuring
continuity of care. Many of these proposals represented the extension of
existing reforms such as ‘measure and share’ initiatives, coordinated care
trials, and the arrangements within the current AHCAs for rationalisation of
pharmaceutical funding arrangements.
Commonwealth to fund all
pharmaceutical services
3.43
This proposal involves the
Commonwealth assuming responsibility for funding pharmaceutical services in
public hospitals. A number of alternatives were proposed in submissions,
including:
-
Commonwealth to fund inpatient and non-inpatient
pharmaceuticals for public hospital patients;
-
Commonwealth to fund only non-inpatient pharmaceuticals
in public hospitals;
-
Commonwealth to provide block funding for public
hospital pharmaceutical services;
-
Commonwealth to fund public hospital
pharmaceutical services through the PBS;
-
use of casemix based funding for pharmaceutical
services; and
-
extension of the s100 Scheme[223].
3.44
The primary motivation for the
proposal for the Commonwealth to assume responsibility for funding of all
pharmaceutical services is the removal of incentives for cost-shifting. In
particular, it is seen as a way of addressing the concern that patients
discharged from hospital are issued with small starter packs of medication
which therefore requires them to visit their general practitioner for a PBS
prescription. Evidence from the Commonwealth suggests that this would involve significant
cost-savings. However, a number of issues need to be considered in relation to
this proposal:
-
there is a risk that such a proposal, if
implemented on its own, would simply shift the boundary for cost-shifting
within hospitals. This is particularly the case if there are different
arrangements for inpatient and non-inpatient pharmaceuticals;
-
if hospital pharmaceutical services are funded
from a different pool from the global budget for other hospital services, there
are reduced incentives for hospital managers to monitor efficiency in
pharmaceutical provision. Hospital pharmacists have noted that the incentives
to manage the provision of s100 pharmaceuticals are much lower than for other
components of their service provision;
-
if hospital-based pharmaceutical services are
funded on an open-ended basis (eg through the PBS) there are few incentives for
ensuring efficiency in their provision; and
-
the different purchasing arrangements which
exist for hospital based and community based pharmaceutical services are
relevant to the overall efficiency of service provision.
It should be noted that a
proposal for the Commonwealth to assume responsibility for non-inpatient
pharmaceuticals is already built into the current AHCAs, and negotiations are
underway between the Commonwealth and individual States/Territories for its
implementation. The differences between jurisdictions in their view of the
merits of this proposal are canvassed below.
Commonwealth’s offer to the States
and Territories on hospital pharmaceuticals
3.45
Under the ‘measure and share’
provisions of the AHCAs,[224] the
Commonwealth is negotiating with the States and Territories over a proposal for
the Commonwealth to assume the responsibility for the funding of
pharmaceuticals dispensed in public hospitals. This is an attempt to overcome
cost shifting in this area. Under the current arrangements, the Commonwealth
subsidises pharmaceuticals dispensed in community pharmacies and private
hospitals. Pharmaceuticals dispensed to public patients in hospital are funded
by State and Territory governments. The Commonwealth’s proposal is to ‘allow
the States to dispense against the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme the full
course of treatment. We see that as an all-round win’.[225]
3.46
However, the New South Wales
Health Department expressed reservations about the Commonwealth’s proposal
‘because it simply transferred the risk to the States’ and that it was a ‘take
it or leave it offer’.[226] The
Queensland Government held a similar view, stating that ‘we do not think at
this stage the proposed risk sharing arrangements are acceptable’.[227] The Society of Hospital Pharmacists
of Australia and the Therapeutic Assessment Group were concerned that the
proposal ‘actually makes the system more complex than it needs to be and has
administrative issues involved with it’.[228]
However, the Northern Territory Government was more optimistic, with the
Territory’s Minister for Health arguing that ‘I think it is an appropriate
move. It is early days, so I guess there will be problems along the way, but as
a first move I think it is good’.[229]
3.47
These differences of opinion
about this proposal indicate the problems inherent in any proposals to
reorganise or reform the roles and responsibilities of the different levels of
government in health care.
Assessment against
criteria
|
Commonwealth to
fund all pharmaceutical services
|
Universality
|
Maintained
|
Equity
|
May increase access to
pharmaceuticals for some groups
|
Efficiency
|
Likely to reduce costs;
Reduces incentive for cost-shifting btw levels of government but may create
new boundaries for cost-shifting; May reduce incentive to manage services;
Overall impact unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
No impact
|
Consumer choice
|
No impact
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Reduces need for
additional visits to doctors
|
Continuity of care
|
Could indirectly reduce
continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Feasible, and currently
being implemented
|
Evidence based
|
Not applicable
|
Commonwealth to fund all medical services
3.48
This option for reform was
proposed less often than proposals relating to pharmaceutical services. While
the proposal for the Commonwealth to have responsibility for funding all
medical services largely relates to addressing cost-shifting, it would also
address issues of overlap between public and private services, and the perverse
incentives which can arise when medical practitioners are funded from two
different programs. Essentially two models can be identified:
-
Commonwealth to fund all non-inpatient medical
services through the MBS;
-
Commonwealth to assume all responsibility for
paying for medical services (inpatient and non-inpatient).
3.49
The first model represents a
relatively straightforward extension of MBS and existing arrangements to
hospital outpatient clinics and to emergency departments, and could be seen as
an extension of arrangements which are already occurring on an ad hoc basis.
The primary motivation is removal of incentives for cost shifting, but it may
also improve access to services by removing some financial barriers and by
reducing incentives for outpatient services to be closed. However, it should be
noted that if such an arrangement applied in emergency departments, perverse
incentives for patients not to be admitted would exist. In addition, as with
the proposals for pharmaceutical services, such an arrangement could be seen as
shifting the boundary of cost shifting, rather than removing cost shifting per
se.
3.50
The second model is more
complex to implement, because the extension of the MBS to all inpatient care
would, in effect, involve a change in the definition of a private patient, and
have significant implications for funding of public hospital services. This
model was proposed as one option by the former National Health Strategy. An
alternative arrangement would be for the Commonwealth to fund the medical
component of casemix based funding. However, either of these arrangements
introduce a new complexity in funding of public hospital services which is
likely to create perverse incentives.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Commonwealth to
fund all medical services
|
Universality
|
Maintained
|
Equity
|
No direct impact
|
Efficiency
|
Reduces cost-shifting
and incentives for gaming; Overall impact depends on the funding model
implemented
|
Consumer participation
|
No impact
|
Consumer choice
|
Depends on the model
implemented
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Impact unclear
|
Continuity of care
|
Impact unclear
|
Feasibility
|
Depends on the model
implemented.
|
Evidence based
|
Not applicable
|
Extension of Coordinated Care Trials/trial of regional
budget holding
3.51
A number of submissions
proposed that the coordinated care model be further trialed, with extension to
broader population groups. In particular, several submissions proposed that the
next step in trialing budget holding
and coordinated care would be to pool
funds for a region. This requires consideration of who would hold the budget.
One option would be to establish regional health authorities with
responsibility for purchasing services for their population. Alternatively,
general practitioners could act as budget holders for their patients. This would,
in effect, involve capitation funding to the general practitioner, with the
general practitioner taking on a purchasing role.
3.52
Related to this, the issue of
how services would be paid for needs to be considered. If general practitioners
or some other case manager at the local level are to take on the purchasing
role, there would be a clear role for government in establishing and
prescribing funding arrangements for hospital and other services (for example,
defining DRG prices for hospital services and fee schedules for specialist
medical services). Further, the effectiveness of such a model is highly
dependent on how any cost-savings are distributed. It is important to establish
appropriate incentives for the budget holder to manage resources appropriately,
but also to ensure that access to appropriate services is guaranteed.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Extension of
coordinated care trials/trial of regional budget holding
|
Universality
|
Maintained, given
clearly established national policies and monitoring
|
Equity
|
Efficiency
|
Likely to reduce
cost-shifting and increase potential for cost savings, however, evidence from
CCTs suggests impact on efficiency unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
May increase consumer
participation at the local level
|
Consumer choice
|
Impact unclear
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Potential to enhance
appropriateness of care and continuity of care
|
Continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Key issue is
establishing population funding and addressing variation in medical services
utilisation
|
Evidence based
|
CCTs provide some
evidence but generalisability unclear.
|
Health care financing: proposals relating to
fundamental overhaul
3.53
Although a number of
submissions did propose significant overhaul of health care financing in
Australia, a consistent theme through most submissions was that there was
little reason to change the fundamentals of Medicare or private health
insurance. For example, many submissions argued that the level of health care
expenditure in Australia is appropriate, and most submissions supported the
universal nature of a tax funded health financing scheme, and private health
insurance as complementing this (although there was considerable debate about
the role private health insurance should play).
3.54
Further, there is strong
support for Medicare from consumers. In general most submissions favoured
incremental reform rather than fundamental reform, and focussed on funding and
delivery arrangements rather than the issue of health care funding as such. To
the extent that funding of public hospitals was seen as a problem it was
related much more to Commonwealth/State issues and political debate about the
relative shares of funding rather than an issue of the nature of the health
insurance scheme.
3.55
It should be noted that reforms
proposed to how health care funding is raised also involve significant changes
to how services are organised and paid for.
Single national insurer
3.56
Some submissions argued for a
single national taxation funded insurance scheme for all health care services -
that is, extension of Medicare to cover all health care services, with no role
for private health insurance. The main argument for this was the relative
efficiency of taxation as a means of raising funds and a single insurer as a
means of paying for services. However, such an arrangement would significantly
reduce choice to consumers.
3.57
An alternative model would be
to limit the role of private health insurance to funding of treatment in the
private hospital sector, with private health insurance to cover all the costs
of this treatment including medical services. This model would provide a much
more limited role for private health insurance than currently exists and would
considerably reduce access to private health care for consumers. It raises the
issue whether private health insurance would continue to be community rated or
not.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Single national
insurer
|
Universality
|
Maintained
|
Equity
|
May be enhanced
|
Efficiency
|
May reduce
administrative costs of insurance
|
Consumer participation
|
Reduces choice available
to consumers
|
Consumer choice
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Impact unclear
|
Continuity of care
|
Impact unclear
|
Feasibility
|
May not be feasible
because of impact on consumer choice and implications for funding of medical
practitioners
|
Evidence based
|
Some indirect evidence
from other countries to support impact on costs - may not be generalisable
|
Transferable Medicare entitlements
3.58
Several submissions discussed
the model which has been proposed by the Australian Private Hospitals
Association (APHA), which involves transferable Medicare entitlements. This
model proposes that individuals would be able to opt whether to be insured by
the single national insurer (Medicare) or by a private insurer. An individual
who does not opt out of Medicare would be entitled to free treatment in a
public hospital and to subsidised access to medical services and pharmaceutical
services.
3.59
However, individuals who wanted
to access private health care could opt to be insured by a private insurer. In
this case, the private insurer would receive a risk rated premium from the
(Commonwealth) government equivalent to the consumer’s ‘Medicare entitlement’,
which would then be supplemented by premium payments by the consumer, depending
on the level of coverage. In this model, opting out of Medicare would mean that
the individual was no longer entitled to free treatment in public
hospitals-they would only be entitled to care in facilities and from providers
who had contracts with their private insurer (as in managed competition).
3.60
As well as being risk rated
(age and sex adjusted, with some possibility of other adjustments based on
factors such as chronic health conditions), premiums could be adjusted for
income, with higher income individuals receiving a lower subsidy from
government.
3.61
The main rationale for
transferable Medicare entitlements is its potential to increase efficiency
(through competition), reduce scope for and incentives for cost-shifting, while
maintaining universality and consumer choice. However, while some analysis of the
financial viability of this proposal has been undertaken by the APHA, it is not
clear what the final impact on health care costs would be.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Transferable
Medicare entitlements
|
Universality
|
Key issue is ensuring
that all insurers are required to provide a reasonable minimum level of
services - may be difficult to monitor
|
Equity
|
Depends on the model
implemented, but may reduce access to private care and lead to a “two tiered”
system
|
Efficiency
|
Potential to increase
cost control through competition. However, administrative costs likely to be
higher. Overall impact unclear
|
Consumer participation
|
Potential to enhance
choice available to consumers and consumer participation (eg specific
population groups could establish their own fund)
|
Consumer choice
|
Appropriateness of care
|
May enhance
appropriateness of care and continuity of care because a single purchaser is
responsible for all care
|
Continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Data requirements for
establishing appropriate arrangements are substantial
|
Evidence based
|
Indirect evidence
available from other countries
|
Health Savings Accounts
3.62
One submission proposed a
variant of the Singapore health system model, whereby each individual would
have a ‘health account’ held (and underwritten) by the Commonwealth government.
The government would pay an annual amount into each individual’s health
account, which would accrue over time. Individuals would be entitled to
withdraw from their account to purchase services (in the model proposed, the government
would define a list of approved health services and establish a fee schedule
for these) regardless of whether their account had a positive or negative
balance. Individuals who had a positive balance at the end of the year would be
entitled to a health dividend. Medical services would be funded on a
fee-for-service basis, and pharmaceuticals would be funded on the basis of
negotiated prices (as with the current PBS). Hospital services would be funded
on a case payment basis, with the government determining the DRG price. Private
health insurance could be allowed in the model, to cover services not included
in the approved health services, or to cover charges above the schedule fee.
3.63
There are a number of issues
with this model. It is likely to increase health care costs, because it places
more services on an open-ended fee-for-service basis, and reduces incentives
for health services managers to manage the provision of services. Private
health insurers would have little scope to manage funds, because their role
would essentially be that of a third party payer. Further, while it would be
possible to risk-adjust the amount paid into an individual’s health account, it
is likely that the model would reinforce inequities in health status, because
individuals are, in effect, rewarded for not using health services.
Assessment
against criteria
|
Health Savings
Accounts
|
Universality
|
Risk that universality
of access and equity of access to services could be compromised
|
Equity
|
Efficiency
|
Increases open-ended
funding arrangements therefore likely to increase costs
|
Consumer participation
|
Potential to enhance
choice available to consumers and consumer participation, but this depends on
consumers having equitable access
|
Consumer choice
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Impact unclear - may
increase fragmentation in the system
|
Continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Data requirements for
establishing appropriate arrangements are substantial
|
Evidence based
|
No evidence available
|
Health care financing: incremental/partial reform
proposals
3.64
Although a number of
submissions proposed incremental or partial changes to how health care finances
are raised, it is difficult to separate these reforms from the broader debate
about current health insurance arrangements and the effectiveness of the new
measures to increase private health insurance uptake. Thus, proposals often
related to either removing or extending some of the existing or proposed
measures. In relation to any proposed changes to health insurance arrangements,
several points should be noted:
-
submissions which addressed these issues tended
to be divided between those which argued for less support for private health
insurance (for example, submissions which argued that the rebate should be
abolished and funds diverted to public hospital funding) and those which argued
for greater support for private health insurance (for example, those which
suggested measures to eliminate co-payments);
-
it is difficult to separate out the rationale
for any changes to health insurance arrangements from the underlying position
of the stakeholders proposing it. Thus reform proposals in this area often
appeared to be driven by ideology or politics rather than evidence;
-
as noted in a number of submissions, it is too
early to assess accurately the impact of existing and proposed measures
including the 30 per cent rebate and the introduction of lifetime health cover;
and
-
the effectiveness of health insurance
arrangements needs to be assessed against their proposed objective. The
objective of increasing private health insurance uptake, or making private
health insurance more affordable and available to consumers per se needs to be
separated from the objective of financing health care, particularly public
hospital care. A number of submissions have provided reasonable assessments
which suggest that mechanisms to increase private health insurance uptake are a
relatively inefficient way of reducing pressure on public hospital services.
Reform proposals addressing specifically identified issues
3.65
Many submissions identified
specific reforms to components of the health system. These proposals tended to
relate to the funding and delivery of specific services and are briefly
outlined below. The issues involved with a number of these proposals will be
discussed in more detail in the Committee’s final report, which will address
the remaining terms of reference.
Quality management
-
introduction of report cards/performance
monitoring for public and private hospitals and other providers;
-
trialing of quality improvement programs;
-
relating funding to quality improvement and to
outcomes, for example, by funding hospitals only if they have established
clinical care pathways;
-
establish financial incentives for hospital
managers to implement quality improvement programs;
-
further development of clinical care pathways;
-
increased development of evidence based
guidelines; and
-
support for teaching and research in public
hospitals.
Continuity of care
-
more comprehensive discharge planning;
-
increased role for general practitioners; and
-
financial incentives/funding arrangements to
encourage general practitioners to link with other providers.
Data collection
-
establish unique patient identifiers applicable
to all health services; and
-
improve data collection in specific areas (eg
rehabilitation services).
Access to services
-
provision of funding for Aboriginal language
interpreters;
-
appropriate funding for primary health care for
Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander populations;
-
increase the role of nurse practitioners in
rural areas; and
-
extend the provision of multi-purpose services
in rural areas.
Consumer choice
-
establishment of a prospective payment for
maternity services.
Further options for reform
3.66
In addition to the funding
options considered and evaluated by CHERE, several further options for reform
were raised by participants during the course of the inquiry. Although these
options do not relate primarily to funding issues (other than the discussion of
managed competition), a number of them could be considered to underpin or
facilitate the adoption of some of the funding proposals. These further options
are discussed below although, other than the managed competition proposal, they
are not readily assessable against the criteria applied to the funding options
earlier in the chapter.
A National Health Policy
3.67
Australia does not currently
have a national health policy,[230]
although the formulation of such a policy has been on and off the health policy
agenda for some time. It could be argued that Medicare is a defacto national
health policy but while it articulates several core principles it does not
encompass all aspects of health care. In order for all components of the health
system to have a similar set of priorities, it may be worth considering the
extension of the Medicare principles beyond their present focus.
3.68
A national health policy could
be expected to offer an overarching articulation of what the community expects
of Australia’s health system and its key components, including the public
hospital sector. It could be expected to focus on the system as a whole and the
linkages between its different elements, constructing pathways which are built
around the needs of patients, rather than the priorities of funders and
providers.
3.69
Submissions and evidence to the
inquiry have indicated that a national health policy underpins many of the
other options for reform. For example, the New South Wales Health Department
argued that the investigation of options which would overcome problems around
the split of roles and responsibilities of governments, such as a single pool
of funding, could not be done ‘without a national health policy in place’.[231] ACHSE believes that a national
health policy is a prerequisite for any reforms aimed at improving information
systems and data collection in public hospitals. ACHSE argues that:
...we strongly believe that there is a need for a national health
plan-a national health policy framework-so that if you cascade that down the
states have a framework in which they are working and the health care providers
also have a local and a broader framework within which they are working. If we
had that framework and we had the sorts of outcomes we want clearly identified,
then I think we could start designing our systems and data collection to focus
on where we are trying to get to.[232]
Other participants, including representatives of nurses,
such as the Queensland Nurses Union[233] and consumers, such as Western Australia’s Health Consumers’ Council (HCC),[234] also offered their support for the
formulation of a national health policy.
3.70
The development of a national
health policy would necessarily involve players other than governments and
would include providers and other interest groups as well as the broader
community. The following section discusses the arguments around community
consultation and involvement and also canvasses various methods of achieving
these ends.
Community debate and transparent
priorities
3.71
A number of submissions raised
the need for the consultation, involvement and/or education of the community in
setting priorities for the health system, including the level of funding and
methods of paying for services. For example, Monash University’s CHPE stated
that ‘it is impossible to determine the ideal allocation of resources without
knowing what it is that the community wishes’.[235] The HCC informed the Committee of
feedback from consumers who argued that ‘we had a tax summit in the 1980s, why
can’t we have a health financing summit at Parliament House?’[236]
3.72
The HCC proposed that the key
to an informed community response is education: ‘the education of the community
about a range of factors that impact on the health system is the best way to
get an informed community response-a citizen response, not just a consumer
response’.[237] The joint submission
from the AHA, WHA and AAPTC argued that community debate is not a static,
one-off process but rather ‘there should be an ongoing and open public debate
as to the nature and level of funding for the health system’.[238] The ACHSE acknowledged the
difficulties involved but believe that ‘communities and key stakeholders need
to have some discussion about the resources that are available and what our
expectations, needs and key priorities should be’.[239]
3.73
Professor Hindle argued that
cost effectiveness could be improved if the community had a greater degree of
involvement in, and understanding of, the health system:
we would have, overnight, a radical improvement in the cost
effectiveness of health services if the community had a real voice, a real
understanding and a set of rights about knowing what was going on and had the
opportunity to say how it should be changed.[240]
3.74
Several participants expressed
the view that the community needed to be engaged in a dialogue or debate about
the health system and the public hospital sector to help determine the
community’s preferences and priorities. For example, the Australian Medical
Association (AMA) ‘believes that it is time for the Australian community to
have a more mature dialogue about the provision of a wider range of choices
when it comes to publicly funded services’.[241]
Professor Phelan of the Committee of Presidents of Medical Colleges, offering a
personal view, felt that the medical profession was concerned about moving
ahead of community expectations with regard to what care could and should be
provided, particularly for older patients. He argued that ‘what we have failed
to do is to stimulate an informed community debate on this issue’ and that ‘the
community needs to set its priorities’.[242]
3.75
Part of this lack of community
engagement has been a failure to acknowledge that there are constraints upon
the services that can be delivered by the public hospital sector and the
Australian health system. It is simply impossible to provide all possible
services to all patients all of the time. No health system is capable of doing
this because there are limits on health budgets. Certainly, choices can be made
and ‘the size of the health sector is extraordinarily flexible’[243] as argued by Professor Richardson,
but it is a fallacy to pretend that limits do not exist. The Western Australian
Health Department acknowledged that:
we need a much larger community debate on what people actually
want from their health system, because it is impossible, certainly under the
current funding arrangements, to provide everything that everybody wants.[244]
3.76
In accepting that budgetary
limits exist, there is an implication that priorities need to be established.
While the issue of limits and priorities is difficult to grapple with, it is
one that needs to be addressed. Several levels of the health system and the public
hospital sector currently set priorities, but few are transparent. Governments
set priorities in a number of ways, but most visibly through the funding
provided for services. For example, as was discussed in the previous chapter,
all State and Territory governments fund their public hospitals via a global
capped budget. The response from public hospitals is to establish priorities to
enable them to work within their budgets. This response takes the form, for
example, of bed/ward closures and waiting lists for elective surgery.
Priorities are also set by medical providers whereby a privately insured
patient is likely to be treated before a public patient with a similar elective
condition.[245]
3.77
The New South Wales Health
Department developed the issue of transparency, arguing that governments
generally had not been very good about engaging the community in a dialogue of
what realistically could be expected of the health system:
I think we have a way to go in the Australian health care system
in terms of having a true dialogue with our community about what our system is
good at-and it is a very good system, particularly by comparison with the rest
of the world-and also what the limitations are of the $43 billion we expend
upon the Australian health care system.[246]
3.78
Finally, the Northern Territory
Government warned the Committee that community consultation might require a
long time frame, perhaps 10 years, but that ‘the debate must be had and must be
heard’.[247]
Mechanisms for engendering
community debate
3.79
Although several submissions
discussed the necessity for community involvement and education, none proposed
any means of achieving an engagement with the community. The following section
provides an overview of various methods of ascertaining the community’s ideas
and wishes and/or involving the community in consultations and decision-making
on health policy matters. This section includes models which are currently
occurring in Australia as well as selected examples of overseas experience.
3.80
In attempting to gauge the
preferences and expectations of the community with regard to the public
hospital sector, one obvious mechanism is to utilise the existing consumer and
health consumer groups, such as the Consumers’ Health Forum, the Health
Consumers Council (WA) and the Australian Consumers’ Association. While these
groups would be able to provide useful community feedback, it is difficult to
judge whether the feedback would necessarily reflect the preferences of the
community as a whole. However, the feedback available through these groups
would be important because it is likely to reflect the preferences of users of
the health system and the public hospital sector.
3.81
Barwon Health informed the
Committee of a survey of its local community that is currently underway which
could provide a possible model or be used more widely. Barwon Health is
conducting:
a community survey of the community’s priorities and
expectations about their public health system. I do not believe such a survey
has been done before in Australia. We have just completed the focus groups
attached to that and we will have a major survey in July. Out of that we are
getting a lot of data about what the community feels are the advantages,
disadvantages of our organisation and, indeed, the broader health care system.[248]
3.82
The recent report of the NSW
Health Council, chaired by Mr John Menadue, made several recommendations on
involving communities in health service planning at both the local and State
levels. The Council’s recommendations included:
That local community participation structures be enhanced. This
includes the appointment of dedicated staff in each Area Health Service, to
assist community organisations to participate in planning the role and
distribution of health services;
That a new, State-wide consumer forum be established to provide
input into State-wide policy development and resource allocation.[249]
In his response to the report of the NSW Health Council, the
NSW Minister for Health announced that the Government would establish the
recommended State-wide consumer forum.[250]
3.83
The approach adopted by the
Commonwealth Department of Health and Aged Care (DHAC) and Queensland Health to
involve local communities in the planning and establishment of Regional Health
Services (RHS) utilises a technique called rapid needs appraisal. This is
described by DHAC as a process:
where we go and engage members of the community direct and work
with local health professionals as well as to provide them with a very broad
context of health to give them the capacity to understand their health context
in a broader sense.[251]
Research in the United Kingdom indicates that rapid
appraisal methods work best in a ‘population that can be considered as a
community in some sense of the word’ and can be used to ‘gain community
perspectives of local health and social needs and to translate these findings
into action’.[252]
3.84
A report was issued by DHAC in
1997 of a research project which investigated the involvement of consumers in
improving hospital care. An underlying premise of the report was that ‘hearing
the voice of consumers is an effective way for hospitals to get good
information about what needs to be done about the quality of their services’.[253] One of the lessons derived by the
report was that:
consumer councils/advisory committees have an important role to
play, but they are unlikely to be effective, unless participation processes are
in place at service planning and delivery level, and processes are in place to
consult with consumers. These high level committees need to have a process of
consumer consultation.[254]
3.85
Other countries have adopted a
variety of mechanisms to generate community debate and/or attempted to get a
sense of the priorities and expectations of the community. For example, Oregon,
in the United States, undertook a series of consultations with its community in
the 1980s over changes to its Medicaid[255]
program, the most controversial of which was to put in place an explicit,
transparent system of rationing publicly funded health services. The mechanisms
used in Oregon to involve the community in the decision-making process included
the formation of a citizen-based project (Oregon Health Decisions) which was
intended to increase public awareness of the issues involved in health care
provision; a telephone survey of a sample of residents; and community meetings.
3.86
Several studies and polls have
been conducted in Canada in an attempt to gauge whether the community wishes to
participate in decisions on health-related matters. Writing in the Canadian Medical Journal about the
findings of a deliberative polling survey of three urban and three rural
communities in Ontario, Abelson et al
concluded that ‘there are significant differences among groups in the community
in their willingness to be involved, desired roles and representation in
devolved decision making on health care and social services in Ontario’.[256] The authors found that as
participants understood the complexity of devolved decision making they ‘tended
to assign authority to traditional decision makers such as elected officials,
experts and the provincial government’. The preferred role for the community
was in a consulting role, such as interested citizens attending meetings at
town halls.[257]
3.87
In the United Kingdom, trials
have been conducted to evaluate a community health advisory forum called citizens’
juries. These juries, selected by random sample in local communities, sit for
several days during which time they are presented with information by experts
and patients to assist them in arriving at health-related decisions. Some
juries have considered broad issues such as how priorities should be set for
purchasing health care and what (if any) role the community should play, while
others have deliberated on more specific issues such as the provision of
primary care services in an area with a shortage of GPs. Although citizens’
juries appear to be an expensive form of community consultation, costing
13 000-20 000 pounds for each meeting,[258] an initial evaluation indicated that
‘given enough time and information, the public is willing and able to contribute
to the debate about priority setting in health care’.[259]
Managed Competition
3.88
Budget holding is a central
feature also of the managed competition model proposed by Professor Richard
Scotton.[260] Managed competition has
been proposed in several forms both in Europe (and implemented in the
Netherlands) and the United States as a means of overcoming perceived
shortcomings in different health systems. Scotton’s proposal addresses the
Australian situation and aims to eliminate cost shifting through the use of a single
funding pool, creates distinct roles for each level of government in the health
system and utilises budget holding to promote efficiency. The AHA, WHA and
AAPTC argued in their submission that Scotton’s model ‘offers much promise for
the improved organisation of jurisdictional responsibilities of government’.[261] Scotton’s model of managed
competition utilises elements of the market but does so without compromising
the universality and equity of Medicare.[262]
The main features of Scotton’s proposals are as follows:
-
defined and distinct roles for Commonwealth and
State authorities;
-
a private sector basically operating within the
national system-subject to incentives designed to achieve national program
objectives-and not (as now) outside it; and
-
efficiency-promoting incentive systems,
including:
-
all government subsidies taking the form of
risk-related capitation payments to purchasers or budget holders (to inhibit
risk selection, or ‘cream skimming’);
-
all costs incurred in the treatment of any
individual being financed out of a single budget (to prevent cost shifting);
and
-
the income of all service providers consisting
of payments by budget holders for services provided to their enrollees at
prices reflecting the full costs of efficient production (to promote internal
efficiency).[263]
3.89
Professor Scotton argues that a
strong case can be mounted for managed competition, particularly in its ability
to deal with some structural features, and therefore the underlying problems,
of the Australian health system. Most participants in this inquiry have raised
these features, notably the Commonwealth/State jurisdictional issues and their
attendant problems. Scotton acknowledges that his model will not solve all
problems but argues that ‘it provides a framework within which many problems
that now seem intractable could be more successfully tackled’.[264]
3.90
Professor Duckett has argued
that Scotton’s model would require significant issues to be addressed before it
could be implemented in Australia. These include the ability of funders to set
a fair capitation rate (and the consequent risk of ‘cream skimming’ in the
absence of a fair rate) for coverage and that independent utilisation review is
very much in its infancy in Australia.[265]
He points also to the likely opposition of the Australian Medical Association
(AMA) due to the managed care elements of the model.[266]
Assessment
against criteria
|
Managed
Competition
|
Universality
|
Maintained
|
Equity
|
Maintained-dependent on
fair capitation rate
|
Efficiency
|
Reduces cost-shifting;
potential for greater efficiency
|
Consumer participation
|
Potential for greater
involvement
|
Consumer choice
|
Choice of provider
likely to be more limited than current system; choice of services may
increase
|
Appropriateness of care
|
Possibility of enhanced
appropriateness of care
|
Continuity of care
|
Possibility of
increased focus on continuity of care
|
Feasibility
|
Key concern on fair
capitation rate; likely opposition of AMA although may be more acceptable to
GPs; will require education of community to gain acceptance
|
Redefining the role and services of hospitals
3.91
A number of submissions
proposed that a means of ameliorating the pressures on public hospital finances
was to reduce the demand for hospital services. Several methods were suggested,
including a greater emphasis on preventive services. For example, the Northern
Territory Government told the Committee about its Preventable Chronic Diseases
Strategy which has as a fundamental objective an increase in the birth weight
of Aboriginal babies.[267] Professor
Richardson argued that efficiency gains had been made in public hospitals
through the use of techniques such as casemix-funding in an attempt to do more
with the available resources, an approach which he labelled as technical
efficiency. Acknowledging that the data is limited, Richardson believed that
the greatest efficiency gains could be made from allocative efficiency, or
‘working out where we should be putting our services’, offering the example:
‘should you be putting so many people in hospital rather than having preventive
care?’.[268]
3.92
The Health Department of New
South Wales argued that efficiency gains for public hospitals were possible by
keeping people out of hospital and that this was particularly evident in the
better management of chronic care.[269]
The Northern Territory Government warned, however, that the benefits of a
greater emphasis on prevention would only be visible in the long term: ‘we
believe that the benefit will accrue possibly in decades, in generations’.[270] The Committee of Presidents of
Medical Colleges supported the argument of the New South Wales Government
regarding the likely efficiencies available from a reduction in demand for
public hospital services and commented that at least part of the solution lay
beyond the public hospital sector:
many patients are admitted to hospital in Australia because
there are no alternative facilities in the community and patients are retained
in hospital because they are not able to be discharged, again because of a lack
of community facilities and also because of work practices within the hospital
environment.[271]
3.93
Other proposals were for a more
fundamental reform for public hospitals. Professor Roberton, for example,
suggested that it would be preferable to ‘remove the word “hospital” totally
from our lexicon and say that hospitals are health services and parts of health
services’.[272] The NRHA held a similar
view, arguing that in non-metropolitan areas ‘a hospital does not have to be
there to provide a really good health service, because you can have health
centres instead’. It acknowledged, however, that the community valued its
public hospitals and that hospitals held a special significance in rural and
remote areas:
...we need to get away from that fixed hospital structure which
the community look upon. The minute the word “hospital” is mentioned, people
say, “They are going to close it. We are going to be left. Nobody is going to
come here”.[273]
The Australian Health Insurance Association (AHIA) expressed
its concern about the community’s perception of the public hospital and also
indicated that some community education may be required: ‘for many people, the
big cathedral hospital has a psychological effect way beyond its actual
benefit, and it is a psyche that we really have to shake in this community’.[274]
3.94
The NRHA argued in its
submission that rural and remote areas were leading the rest of the country in
‘the redevelopment of hospitals’ contribution to health care’ and it believes
that ‘it is clear that hospitals of the future will have quite a different
place in the health care system’.[275]
The joint submission of the AHA, WHA and AAPTC offered the Committee a vision
of the hospital of the future. This statement was also quoted in the NRHA’s
submission:
a number of commentators have suggested that the core of the
hospital of the future will consist of emergency and intensive care units and a
small number of high level acute care beds. Operating theatres, diagnostic
services and other therapeutic services, such as cardiac angiography units will
support them. The trend towards day of surgery admissions, shorter length of
stay, day only, ambulatory and home care will continue to reduce the
traditional emphasis on beds. Subject to commercial viability assessments,
which will vary between locations, “medi-hotels” will be able to meet many of
the accommodation needs of people requiring treatment but not needing an acute
care bed. They will be cheaper to run than an acute ward and not being “core
business” could be run by the private sector. Service delivery systems will
focus increasingly on the continuum of care with networks of service providers
involved in meeting the pre-admission, acute episode and post acute care needs
of patients.[276]
3.95
Perhaps the most radical option
for reform in this area was proposed by ACHSE (NSW Branch), which believed that
‘the term “hospital” should no longer be used and that we should move away from
the current concept of a hospital’.[277]
The key components of ACHSE’s alternative model include:
-
hospitals should be redefined as ‘Acute
Treatment Centres’ (ATC), which patients would attend in an emergency or for
‘complex, short-term, serious treatments’;
-
ATCs would consist of accident and emergency,
theatre, intensive care units and other intensive treatment services;
-
all other care and treatment, where possible,
would occur in a person’s home, although institutional care will be required
for some rehabilitation, convalescence and long term care;
-
consumers should be offered a ‘one-stop shop’
which incorporates all services offered through the many Commonwealth, State
and Commonwealth/State funded health programs such as HACC, primary care,
allied health and community health. ACHSE proposes the concept of ‘Multi
Service Provider’ (MSP) to fill this role. This would require pooling of funds
and ‘ideally could be best achieved by having one level of government
responsible for all of health care funding’; and
-
any such reforms ‘must be focused on meeting the
needs of the whole Australian community’.[278]
3.96
During the course of the
inquiry, the Committee has been informed of several developments currently
underway which seek to redefine the role and services of the traditional
stand-alone public hospital. Two of these, Barwon Health and Health Direct, are
briefly discussed.
Barwon Health: An example of an
integrated organisation
3.97
Barwon Health was established
in 1998 as a result of a voluntary amalgamation of five formerly separate
organisations: Geelong Hospital, the Grace McKellar Centre (a rehabilitation
and aged care facility), and Corio, Geelong and Surfcoast Community Health Services.
Barwon Health regards itself as:
a good example of an integrated model of care and one that
represents, I think, what the future of health care is going to be-and that is
not standalone silos that deliver services independently of each other but
rather more integrated services that do not have artificial barriers that
individual organisations create.[279]
3.98
Although Barwon Health is
attempting to create a patient-focused health service which will enable
patients to move through the system without encountering organisational
barriers, it still must deal with the funding rigidities and obstacles inherent
in the health system. For example, it is required to deal with some 64
different lines of funding just in its community health program.[280]
3.99
Another innovative aspect of
Barwon Health’s patient focus is a survey it is conducting of the local
community to obtain a sense of its priorities and expectations about the public
health care system. Barwon Health is also surveying its staff.[281]
Health Direct in Western Australia
3.100
Health Direct is an initiative
of the Western Australian Government. It has operated for approximately 12
months and works in the following way:
that is a telephone service where nurses answer the telephone
and take you through the level of your emergency, triage you and let you know
about locums, after-hours general practitioners or seeing a GP the next day-so
that people have some more choices and there is more consumer information given
to the public.[282]
3.101
Thus, Health Direct may save a
patient who does not require hospital treatment the time involved in attending
an accident and emergency unit by being referred to a more appropriate service.
The scheme is strongly supported by Western Australia’s main health consumer
association, the HCC, which reports a high level of consumer satisfaction with
the service. Similar operations are to be introduced in New South Wales[283] and the Australian Capital
Territory.
Concluding comments[284]
3.102
Few of the proposals for reform
suggested in submissions are new. However, a persistent problem with assessing
proposals for reform is the lack of appropriate data to determine whether
reforms are likely to achieve their objectives. In some cases this could be
addressed through pilot projects or trials, but it is important to note that trials
of some reforms will not necessarily provide appropriate data for full
assessment of the reform. In making an assessment of the reform proposals
against criteria, in most cases it was only possible to make a broad
qualitative judgement of whether reforms would enhance equity and efficiency.
3.103
While there were proposals for
reform to the way health care funding is raised, a strong theme that ran
through many submissions was that the Australian health system generally
performs well by international standards, and that features such as the
universality of Medicare and the availability of choice to consumers should be
maintained. There is a tension between those commentators who believe that
funding arrangements are inherently unstable and the system is heading for a
crisis, and those who believe that the fundamentals of a taxpayer funded
national health insurance scheme supplemented by private health insurance are
sound, and that reform is only needed at the margin to improve the efficiency
of how services are funded and organised.
Senator the Hon Rosemary Crowley
Chair