Chapter 3

25th Report of the Senate Select Committee on Superannuation
THE PARLIAMENTARY CONTRIBUTORY SUPERANNUATION SCHEME & THE JUDGES' PENSION SCHEME
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Chapter 3

Reforming the Scheme

The case for reform

3.1 The bulk of the evidence received by the Committee, particularly from members of the public, indicates that the PCSS in its current form is out of step with modern superannuation practice and is excessively generous. The scheme is also considered by some to contain inequitable features, such as marked differences in benefits for short and longer term members. Furthermore, the scheme is criticised as being inflexible, failing to meet the needs of its members.

3.2 In the May 1997 Budget, the Government announced its intention to require preservation of future contributions to superannuation schemes until age 55:

3.3 This decision will impact on Parliamentarians if they leave office prior to age 55 without qualifying for a pension.

3.4 This change alone will require changes to the parliamentary scheme, as currently there is no provision for interest to be paid on these contributions. Younger members who do not qualify for pension benefits will be required to preserve their superannuation savings for many years. Unless the provisions of the scheme are changed, they may find that the value of their contributions is substantially eroded by the time they are paid at retirement.

3.5 Additionally, the defacto redundancy provisions that are part of the current scheme, whereby defeated members are returned a multiple of their own contributions, will be considerably diminished by the changes to the preservation rules.

3.6 Clearly, some form of reform is inevitable. There are a range of possible changes available, including modifying the scheme or terminating it for all new members and introducing an entirely new scheme. While there are a number of possible options available, each has shortcomings as well as advantages and these need to be carefully considered before deciding on the most appropriate action.

 

Remuneration and representative government

3.7 Remuneration for parliamentarians, of which superannuation is a part, must recognise that Commonwealth parliamentarians are the nation's elected representatives: they are its legislators, and they also provide the Cabinet.

3.8 In their submission to the Committee, the Australian Democrats noted that parliamentary office was usually unpaid until the late nineteenth century, and that this was a barrier against potential parliamentarians who did not have substantial independent means. [2] Support for adequate parliamentary remuneration, as part of a program for improving ethical standards in government, was 'a key proposal of liberal political reform activists up to the turn of the century [1900] and after'. [3]

3.9 If the opportunity of citizens to participate in parliament is not to be restricted, then parliamentarians should receive remuneration which is adequate, in the sense that people can serve as parliamentarians without depending on private means. Mr Robert McClelland MP told the Committee that:

3.10 There is adequate evidence that parliamentary remuneration, particularly at Ministerial level, lags well behind what may be expected for similar levels of responsibility in the private sector and in some public sector positions. While there is no apparent difficulty in attracting people to stand for parliament, the Committee has received evidence that many talented people will not contemplate parliamentary service because of the relatively low remuneration when compared to other options available to them.

3.11 In relation to the relative attractiveness of parliamentary remuneration, Mr Ray Stevens, Director, William M. Mercer Pty Ltd, told the Committee that parliamentary salary:

3.12 The Committee notes the statement of Mr McClelland MP that:

3.13 The Committee is aware that delicate balances must be maintained in this area. The Committee shares the view, put to it by Mr McClelland MP, that it would be regrettable if people were attracted to parliamentary office purely for their own financial gain. [7]

3.14 Senator Cheryl Kernot identified the difficulties associated with parliamentary remuneration:

3.15 Representative government is an important feature of Australia's democratic society. All Australians should have equal opportunity to serve as elected representatives. The Committee considers that, in the interests of representative government, it is desirable that a wide range of people undertake parliamentary service. While success in business or the professions, with its attendant high remuneration, is no guarantee of the quality of a parliamentary candidate, it is undesirable that conditions of service in the parliament be so as to deter such persons.

3.16 If the superannuation portion of parliamentary remuneration is substantially reduced without compensation elsewhere in the remuneration package, it is possible that such a deterrent may become substantial.

 

Superannuation as part of parliamentary remuneration

3.17 The Terms of Reference for this part of the Committee's inquiry were confined to a consideration of superannuation of parliamentarians. While superannuation is unquestionably one part of remuneration, the Committee has no brief to consider the wider question of the adequacy of parliamentary remuneration and did not take any significant evidence on elements of parliamentary remuneration other than superannuation.

3.18 The Committee places on record its opposition to one particular concept of "total remuneration packaging", that is, where people may trade off superannuation for other forms of remuneration for purposes such as tax minimisation. The Committee believes that Parliamentarians should set an example for the rest of the community in this regard, particularly given the compulsory nature of superannuation.

3.19 However, the Committee received evidence that superannuation is best considered as part of overall remuneration, rather than separately. It was also suggested to the Committee that parliamentarians' remuneration, including superannuation, should be provided as a "total remuneration package".

3.20 In the Remuneration Tribunal's view:

3.21 Similarly, the Australian Government Actuary noted that 'superannuation provision is a major component of the remuneration package of Members of Parliament'. [10]

3.22 Several witnesses, with recognised financial sector credentials, also strongly advised the Committee that any consideration of the type of scheme to be adopted for the Parliament is incomplete and possibly meaningless unless superannuation is considered in a total remuneration context.

3.23 Dr Vincent FitzGerald, an economic consultant who appeared in a personal capacity, suggested that a total remuneration approach should be taken to parliamentary remuneration. [11]

3.24 Mr Ray Stevens told the Committee that if a new parliamentary superannuation scheme were to be developed, then "[i]n conjunction with this, of course, there may be a need for a review of the overall remuneration package of politicians". [12]

3.25 Mr Daryl Dixon, an independent superannuation expert, also suggested that superannuation should be considered in the context of overall remuneration and parliamentarians' remuneration should be provided as a total remuneration package. He told the Committee that:

3.26 Mr Dixon advised the Committee that the New South Wales public service had introduced total remuneration package (TRP) arrangements for its Senior Executive Service (SES) officers. [14] Under these arrangements, SES officers are paid an accepted TRP and from this amount each employee meets the full actuarial cost of remaining in an existing superannuation fund. TRP arrangements allow for individual flexibility as to the level of superannuation, while providing the employer with control over the remuneration expenditure. [15]

3.27 However, the Committee notes that the Remuneration Tribunal has expressed reservations about a total remuneration approach to parliamentary remuneration, notwithstanding its view 'that the maximum level of flexibility consistent with due accountability in the expenditure of public funds should be able to be arrived at'. [16] The Remuneration Tribunal has stated that:

3.28 If TRP arrangements were to be introduced for parliamentarians, this would necessarily involve a review of remuneration as a whole. Such a review would have to address the four main elements of parliamentary remuneration:

3.29 The Committee recognises that any suggestion to alter parliamentary remuneration in order to compensate for changes to superannuation arrangements can of itself be an obstacle to change. This is particularly the case if salaries are increased to compensate for substantially reduced superannuation benefits.

3.30 The Committee accepts that superannuation cannot be regarded in isolation from remuneration generally. This is as true for parliamentarians as it is for the community as a whole.

 

Is an accumulation scheme appropriate?

3.31 The terms of reference for this inquiry require the Committee to consider whether it would be appropriate to replace the parliamentary scheme with a fully funded accumulation scheme. In the following section, the Committee evaluates this proposition, at the same time considering options for modifying the existing scheme. These options include:

3.32 The majority of superannuation schemes in the private sector today are funded accumulation schemes. In these schemes, the employer contributes a set percentage of the employee's salary to a fund. Under the Superannuation Guarantee (SG), the minimum that may be contributed is currently 6 per cent, rising to 9 percent in 2002/03.

3.33 Employers may contribute in excess of the minimum amount. Superannuation is part of the salary package for many employees and, particularly at executive levels, employers may make substantial contributions as part of a salary sacrifice arrangement. The amount that employers can contribute is effectively restricted by age-based limits for taxation purposes. The employee may or may not contribute. The final benefit comprises accumulated contributions, plus interest earned on the investment of these contributions.

3.34 Accumulation funds operate on a completely different basis to defined benefit funds, like the parliamentary superannuation scheme, which pay a predictable, guaranteed benefit, independent of contributions or earnings.

3.35 The Committee noted that there is a considerable body of opinion in favour of replacing the current parliamentary defined benefits scheme (the PCSS) with an accumulation scheme. For example, Mr Daryl Dixon considered that the current parliamentary scheme should be closed down to all new members:

3.36 Mr Dixon considered that parliamentarians should be offered the option of moving to an accumulation scheme, or if they wished to remain in the old scheme, 'charged the full cost of continuing membership in the schemes'. [20]

3.37 Dr FitzGerald also favoured an accumulation scheme over the PCSS' defined benefit structure. He considered that the defined benefits approach in the PCSS was not in accordance with current thinking and was very inflexible in terms of the choices and options available to members of the scheme:

3.38 Mr Ray Stevens also recommended an accumulation scheme to replace the PCSS. He considered that a 'radical change to the design', including a shift to an accumulation scheme, was the only practical method of addressing the inequities between short and long term members. [22]

3.39 Senator Brian Gibson, one of the few parliamentarians who expressed a view about how the parliamentary scheme should operate, also recommended a fully funded accumulation scheme. He said that the scheme should be operated on a fully funded basis, the Government, as the employer here, making contributions equivalent to other employer contributions. These contributions would be set in line with the rates prevailing in private sector executive superannuation schemes. Senator Gibson submitted that this was necessary to:

3.40 Senator Gibson considered that the failure to fully fund the scheme and disclose its on-going cost contributes to the distorted public debate. He contended that there was a focus on the pension benefits paid to a few former parliamentarians, but not on the fact that most parliamentarians receive a superannuation return that is 'far from excessive'. [24]

3.41 Proponents of accumulation schemes claim such schemes have a number of advantages, including:

Increasing perceived equity between members

3.42 A major disadvantage of defined benefit arrangements was pointed out by the Australian Government Actuary in his submission - the level of employer support received by an individual will vary according to his or her individual circumstances. Some will receive more and some less. [25] While implied employer contribution rates may be quite high, this does not necessarily relate to the level of benefit enjoyed by an individual employee. For example, a person who enters and leaves parliament at a relatively young age and qualifies for a pension may be expected to derive considerably greater benefits from the scheme than someone who enters Parliament late in life or dies shortly after retiring.

3.43 Similarly, a person who does not qualify for a pension at all receives much less than someone who does. As noted previously in this report, the trend towards shorter terms for parliamentarians means that proportionately more people will fall into this latter category.

3.44 Introducing an accumulation scheme would introduce a direct relationship between the level of benefit that a retiring or defeated parliamentarian receives and his or her length of service in the parliament. This arrangement would also avoid the disparity in treatment between members who qualify for a pension and those who do not. Similarly, very long term members should not be disadvantaged.

3.45 Whether this would in fact improve equity depends on the interpretation of equity adopted. As pointed out by the Actuary, equity is a nebulous concept with different meanings to different people. The nature of defined benefits schemes means that people in different circumstances will always derive different quantities of benefit. This can be judged acceptable if the objectives of the scheme, for example, the provision of retirement security for former members, is achieved.

3.46 In the Committee's view, the scheme as currently constituted does not meet this objective, as the scheme only provides income in retirement for those fortunate enough to qualify for a pension. While the scheme makes payments to non qualifying members, this is in the form of a lump sum and is effectively a redundancy payment.

3.47 The Committee acknowledges that under the Government's announced changes to the preservation rules, the proportion of the payment to non-qualifying members which comprises contributions will be preserved for retirement purposes. However, the difference between levels of employer support for qualifying and non-qualifying parliamentarians will remain disproportionate.

Improved choice and flexibility

3.48 In the 1997 budget, the Government announced that, as at 1 July 1998, employees would be given a choice concerning the superannuation fund or retirement savings account into which their contributions would be paid. [26] The Committee understands that defined benefits funds may be exempt from these provisions. Nonetheless, it would be in keeping with government policy and wider community standards in this area if parliamentarians were given some choice in this regard.

3.49 The Committee has received only limited evidence to indicate whether parliamentarians regard choice of fund and flexibility as desirable. Evidence given to the Committee by Mr Wilson Tuckey indicates that this may be an issue to some parliamentarians. Mr Tuckey advised the Committee that some older parliamentarians will not recover their contributions back as benefits before they die, particularly if they retire at or after 60 and choose a pension over a lump sum. [27] Nonetheless, these members are compelled to continue contributing to the scheme.

3.50 Similarly, the submission of the Parliamentary Retiring Allowances Trust observed that some members may wish to provide better cover for spouses and children or other dependants, or to enhance their benefits by contributing at a higher rate. [28] They are unable to do so within the scheme under current rules.

3.51 Dr Vincent FitzGerald also drew the Committee's attention to anomalous situations that may arise as a consequence of the current lack of flexibility in the scheme. He noted that a person who enters the Parliament later in life and who has already accrued a substantial superannuation benefit from previous employment is none the less required to contribute to the fund. [29]

3.52 As pointed out by Mr Daryl Dixon, such persons may even fall afoul of reasonable benefit limits and be subjected to penalty rates of taxation, through no fault of their own. [30]

3.53 Mr Graham Millar, Assistant Secretary, Commonwealth Superannuation Group, Department of Finance confirmed that member choice of fund and investment' are not really practical' under a defined benefit arrangement as currently exists. Mr Millar told the Committee that, in his opinion, if greater choice of scheme or investment policy is required, then 'it would seem appropriate to move to a fully funded accumulation scheme'. [31]

3.54 An accumulation scheme could offer members improved flexibility, within the context of a total remuneration package arrangement. Under such an arrangement, a parliamentarian could, as in the private sector, negotiate a total package, including an appropriate level of superannuation, according to individual requirements. However, such an arrangement is not currently available to parliamentarians.

Cost control

3.55 In a defined benefit fund, the benefits paid to members and hence the costs of the benefit, are determined by qualifying conditions rather than accumulated contributions. The Committee received the following evidence that the cost controls on the PCSS are inadequate and that the scheme is vulnerable to exploitation.

3.56 Mr Daryl Dixon was highly critical of the lack of controls on the cost of the scheme, and argued that the failure to examine parliamentary superannuation in the context of the total remuneration package, but rather as an 'add-on', can lead to 'vast blow outs in cost'.

3.57 Mr Dixon indicated that he thought that the 'single worst feature' of the scheme was that there is no adjustment of the level of pension according to the age at which it commences.

3.58 He also criticised the lack of provisions in the scheme to take account of the age of the spouse of a parliamentarian, noting that as a result, a parliamentarian who is survived by a much younger spouse creates a much greater cost to the taxpayer than where the spouse is of equivalent age. Mr Dixon said that this was not in accordance with industry practice. He advised the Committee that if a person buys a pension in the private sector, the age of the spouse is 'the first thing the insurance company will ask you. [33]

3.59 Improving cost controls should theoretically be easier to achieve in an accumulation fund arrangement, if benefits are effectively limited by contributions. However, the Committee understands that benefits are commonly paid to members of accumulation schemes in the event of invalidity, or to their spouses or estate in the event of death. These arrangements are usually provided through insurance cover taken out by the superannuation fund with an insurance company.

3.60 Similarly, there are no reasons to prevent the imposition of limits on benefits within defined benefit funds. For example, the Public Service Superannuation scheme includes a qualifying test based on age of a surviving spouse. Further, that scheme contains a provision discounting early retirement pensions by 3 per cent for each year before the age of 60.

3.61 Bringing parliamentary superannuation more into line with common private sector practice by introducing an accumulation scheme may help alleviate adverse public perceptions of parliamentary superannuation benefits.

 

Disadvantages associated with accumulation schemes

3.62 Accumulation schemes do however have some disadvantages, including the following:

Unpredictable benefit levels

3.63 In particular, the return paid to accumulation scheme members depends on the success or otherwise of the investment of the fund. Consequently, it is not possible to predict in advance the value of employee's benefit, which makes retirement planning more difficult.

Variable benefit levels in like circumstances

3.64 Variations in investment performance can also give rise to differences in benefit levels for persons in like circumstances. This may be perceived as inequitable. A person who retires after a period of buoyant investment returns may derive higher benefits than someone who retires after a time of lower investment success.

Administration costs

3.65 If the Parliament were to establish its own accumulation scheme, this may entail a higher level of administration costs than is currently the case, because of the need to manage investments. The consequences may be higher costs to the Commonwealth or lower benefits for members, depending on the mechanism for allocating the costs associated with administering the new scheme and managing the investments.

3.66 Alternatively, the Parliament could devolve the scheme to the private sector, either by allowing existing public offer funds to compete for the Parliament's business or requiring parliamentarians to nominate the superannuation fund or retirement savings account into which they required contributions to be paid. This would not necessarily be a lower cost option to members, as any private fund would impose management fees.

Independence

3.67 In the section of the inquiry that examined the judges' pension scheme, the Committee received evidence on the need to maintain judicial independence through a range of measures, including judges being insulated from superannuation fund investments. This was seen as important in the event that judges might be required to rule on matters in which they had an interest.

3.68 Somewhat surprisingly, the Committee received very little evidence in this regard concerning parliamentarians. This must, however, be acknowledged as a factor that should be considered in any evaluation of whether an accumulation scheme would be appropriate for the Parliament. The Parliament is regularly required to consider legislation that affects the superannuation system and potentially, all members of parliament in a funded parliamentary accumulation superannuation scheme would have a direct interest.

3.69 The Committee does not wish to overemphasise the importance of this potential disadvantage. There is currently no prohibition on parliamentarians holding investments or indeed operating businesses, as long as such interests are declared.

3.70 The Committee considers that the eventual transition of the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme to an accumulation scheme offers an alternative for addressing the problems identified with the current scheme.

3.71 An alternative to introducing an entirely new scheme is to modify the existing PCSS to address some of the more significant shortcomings identified in this inquiry. The Committee has canvassed two options:

 

Preservation to age 55

3.72 The first option for reforming the scheme is to increase the age at which pension benefits can be taken. [34] The Committee was advised that Parliamentarians in the USA, Canada and the UK are not paid benefits until 50, 55 and 65 respectively.

3.73 Preserving benefits to a later age could reduce the cost of the scheme to the taxpayer by a substantial margin. The Australian Government Actuary, Mr Craig Thorburn, estimated that the saving could be 20 per cent if the age of access to pensions was increased to 55 years. [35]

3.74 This option would also be publicly acceptable, as it is more in accordance with private sector practice where contributions to accumulation funds are generally preserved until a recognised retirement age.

3.75 Mr Thorburn advised the Committee that making changes to pension preservation rules may produce unexpected results, including behavioural change. He predicted that 'people would be less likely to retire before 55'. [36]

3.76 It is also possible that such a change may change the patterns of people entering Parliament at a relatively young age. Such people may choose to delay their entry into Parliament until a later age.

3.77 The desirability of this eventuality must be considered, as it has implications for the concept of representative government. Its importance should not however be overstated, as there is little current evidence of parliamentarians basing their behaviour around the possibility of an early lifetime pension. As Mr Thorburn noted:

3.78 The major disadvantages of preserving benefits until age 55 are:

 

Actuarially reduced pensions

3.79 A second option is to maintain the scheme essentially in its current form, but pay pension benefits at a lesser rate if taken before a recognised retirement age. The rate at which pension is paid would be discounted using actuarial tables taking into account life expectancy and years of service.

3.80 A similar arrangement is in force in the Commonwealth Superannuation Scheme for retiring or redundant Commonwealth public servants. Mr Daryl Dixon pointed out that in this scheme, it is possible to take a pension prior to recognised retiring age. However the pension is discounted by 3 per cent for each year below the age of 60. [38]

3.81 The Committee found some general support for this proposal throughout the evidence.

3.82 The disadvantages of the proposal are similar to those associated with the previous proposal. It is possible that as foreshadowed by the Australian Government Actuary, such a proposal may also produce behavioural changes in parliamentarians and prospective parliamentarians.

3.83 The proposal has a number of distinct advantages, however. These include:

 

Conclusions and recommendations

3.84 The Committee considers that change to the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme is desirable. The scheme is now out of step with superannuation practice in the wider community. There is convincing evidence that it is excessively generous to a small group of retiring parliamentarians.

3.85 The Committee is also conscious of the difficulties associated with a parliamentary Committee reviewing their own entitlements. Inevitably, charges of conflict of interest will arise.

3.86 The Committee believes there is a lack of transparency in parliamentary superannuation, and that this lack of transparency gives rise to much of the criticism of the PCSS.

3.87 The divergent views of Coalition and Australian Labor Party Senators are expressed in the following section. The Australian Democrat member, Senator Lyn Allison, has appended a separate dissent to this report.

Coalition Senators' view - Superannuation and Parliamentary remuneration

3.88 Coalition members of the Committee conclude that the issue of superannuation must be considered as part of parliamentary remuneration determined by the Remuneration Tribunal.

3.89 The Coalition Senators consider that the framework and the terms of remuneration should be determined by the Government of the day, who should give guidance to the Remuneration Tribunal taking account of the following principles:

3.90 At present the parliamentary scheme provides for the taking of pensions prior to retirement age. Under the changes to the preservation rules announced in the 1997-98 Budget, early access to benefits will still be possible 'where the benefits are taken as a non-commutable life pension or lifetime annuity'. [39] While a case may be made for allowing early access to pensions, this is not consistent with current community standards. Coalition Senators recommend that future members of parliament should not receive any pension benefit until age 55.

3.91 For current members, Coalition Senators consider that there is a case for introducing actuarially discounted benefits if they are taken before age 55. The Australian Government Actuary should determine the appropriate discount to be applied. However, introduction of this provision should coincide with the new preservation rules announced in the 1997-98 Budget, that is, to commence from 1 July, 1999.

Australian Labor Party Senators' view - Superannuation and parliamentary remuneration

3.92 The report refers to the independent Remuneration Tribunal setting the employment conditions of members of parliament.

3.93 Labor Senators have chosen not to recommend specific changes to the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme but see the Remuneration Tribunal as the appropriate body to make necessary recommendations for reform in light of its independence, experience with remuneration matters and its ability to evaluate the totality of the scheme and its objectives.

3.94 Labor Senators believe there is a case for reviewing the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme and recognise the potential conflict of interest in current parliamentarians determining changes to the superannuation scheme which affect the entitlements of current and future parliamentarians.

3.95 Labor Senators recommend that any review of the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme be conducted independently by the Remuneration Tribunal.

Funding

3.96 The Committee has considered whether there is any advantage to be gained through fully funding the PCSS. The Committee notes the evidence of the Australian Government Actuary that such a proposal would not produce any savings for many years.

3.97 In the long term the Committee believes that the PCSS should move toward becoming a fully funded scheme. This would provide for greater transparency of superannuation with other parliamentary entitlements.

Controls on costs to the Commonwealth

3.98 The Committee notes the evidence that it received that the provision of survivor and invalidity benefits represent a significant and uncontrolled extra cost. While accepting that there may be a need to review these provisions, the Committee notes that survivor benefits are provided in many superannuation arrangements. The Committee considers that such arrangements are entirely reasonable.

3.99 The Committee recommends that survivor and invalidity benefits continue to be paid. However, the rules under which these benefits are paid should be reviewed by the Remuneration Tribunal, in accordance with standards adopted in other private and public sector superannuation schemes.

Interest on contributions

3.100 The new preservation rules announced by the Government apply to contributions by Parliamentarians to the PCSS. Unless a mechanism is developed for paying interest on these contributions, the real value of these contributions may be eroded over time.

3.101 The Committee therefore recommends that contributions made by parliamentarians attract interest in accordance with normal superannuation practice.

 

[Return to Table of Contents]

Footnotes

[1] House of Representatives, Hansard, 13 May 1997, p. 3379.

[2] Submission No. 40, Australian Democrats, p. 2.

[3] Submission No. 40, Australian Democrats, p. 2.

[4] Evidence, Mr Robert McClelland MP, p. 142.

[5] Evidence, Mr Ray Stevens, p. 160.

[6] Evidence, Mr Robert McClelland MP, p. 141.

[7] Evidence, Mr Robert McClelland MP, p. 139.

[8] Evidence, Senator Cheryl Kernot, p. 174. Senator Kernot went on to suggest that this might indicate over-generous remuneration of some private sector executives (Evidence, p. 174).

[9] Submission No. 45, Remuneration Tribunal, p. 2.

[10] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 27.

[11] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 155.

[12] Evidence, Mr Ray Stevens, p. 162.

[13] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 128.

[14] On these arrangements see Evidence, pp. 128, 131, 135.

[15] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, pp. 128, 131.

[16] Remuneration Tribunal, Statement: Members of Parliament Allowances and Entitlements (1996), p. 2.

[17] Remuneration Tribunal, Statement: Members of Parliament Allowances and Entitlements (1996), p. 2.

[18] The four elements are identified in Submission 45, Remuneration Tribunal, p. 4. Parliamentarians' salary is presently adjusted under statute by reference to a public service pay level (the current link is with the bottom point of the Australian Public Service SES Band 2 level). The Remuneration Tribunal deals with the electorate allowance and other benefits (including, for example, the charter transport reimbursement allowance and the travelling allowance). See Submission 45, Remuneration Tribunal, p. 1.

[19] Submission No. 48, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 1.

[20] Submission No. 48, Mr Daryl Dixon, p.1.

[21] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 155.

[22] Evidence, Mr Ray Stevens, p. 163.

[23] Submission, Senator Brian Gibson, p. 1.

[24] Submission, Senator Brian Gibson, p. 1.

[25] Submission, Australian Government Actuary, p. 3.

[26] House of Representatives, Hansard, 13 May 1997, p. 3379.

[27] Submission No. 30, Mr Wilson Tuckey MP, p. 3.

[28] Submission No. 43, Parliamentary Retiring Allowances Trust, p. 3.

[29] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 156.

[30] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 128.

[31] Evidence, Mr Grahame Millar, p. 112.

[32] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 132.

[33] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 135.

[34] As previously explained, lump sums will be preserved until 55 under the new preservation rules.

[35] Evidence, Mr Craig Thorburn, p. 122.

[36] Evidence, Mr Craig Thorburn, p. 122.

[37] Evidence, Mr Craig Thorburn, p. 123.

[38] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 130.

[39] Savings: Choice and Incentive, Statement by the Hon. Peter Costello, M.P., Treasurer of the Commonwealth of Australia and Senator The Hon. Jocelyn Newman, Minister for Social Security, 13 May, 1997, p. 27.