Chapter 2

25th Report of the Senate Select Committee on Superannuation
THE PARLIAMENTARY CONTRIBUTORY SUPERANNUATION SCHEME & THE JUDGES' PENSION SCHEME
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Chapter 2

Appropriateness

Public perceptions of parliamentary superannuation

2.1 From time to time there has been expressed criticism of parliamentary superannuation as being too generous and unrelated to the superannuation entitlements of ordinary people. Some of the more recent and graphic criticisms were contained in an article in the January 1997 edition of the Reader's Digest, [2] and in the resulting letters to the editors of daily newspapers and several submissions to the Committee.

2.2 The Committee was mindful of the existence of these perceptions and for the need to test some of them in evidence at the public hearing on parliamentary superannuation held in Canberra on 4 June 1997. Accordingly, the author of the Reader's Digest article, Mr Paul Raffaele, was invited to give evidence to the Committee. Mr Peter Szalay, a member of the public, also gave evidence following a submission made by him to the Committee.

2.3 In submissions received from the public, the following comments are representative of the points most often made:

2.4 Evidence presented to the Committee did highlight some anomalies in the Parliamentary Contributory Superannuation Scheme (PCSS). However, the Committee considers there may have been undue attention paid to individual cases in the press which has exaggerated general perceptions of unreasonableness.

2.5 In the following paragraphs of this chapter, the Committee examines:

 

Is the scheme trying to do too much?

2.6 The Committee considers that as a community, we may generally have required too much of superannuation. At the micro level, this kind of expectation may have manifested itself in the Parliamentary Scheme. The evidence in support of this view included that from Dr Vince FitzGerald, who said of the PCSS:

2.7 Dr FitzGerald suggested that aspects of the scheme could be better handled by providing assistance in some other way to those members who leave involuntarily, to help members re-establish themselves 'in some other pursuit and get back to earning an income in some other way'. [10] The issue of a dislocation benefit is considered in Chapter 4.

 

The tenure of Australian Parliamentarians

2.8 The Committee's secretariat undertook research on the tenure of federal parliamentarians since the 1940s. This table is a breakdown of the average term in years of completed service of those parliamentarians elected in the particular decade.

Average Tenure

  1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s
H of R 12.9 14.7 11.0 8.7 8.9
Senate 11.6 14.6 11.2 10.8 7.0

2.9 While the figures for the 1980s appointees may be statistically skewed downward due to the omission of those still serving, the Committee is satisfied that the figures do indicate a trend toward shorter parliamentary careers. The Committee regards this trend as important in assessing the appropriateness of the current PCSS.

2.10 One implication of this trend is that fewer parliamentarians will reach the criteria to qualify for a pension. For them, the PCSS becomes purely a compensation or redundancy scheme. However, the Government-financed element of this benefit is 26.8 per cent of salary paid during their service, which is considerable. The amount received in this way, or part thereof, could be applied to superannuation for the former member.

 

The age of parliamentarians

2.11 The Committee noted the view of the Australian Government Actuary that there has been a trend toward younger members of Parliament. [11] However, the following table is not necessarily supportive of this view. [12]

Average Age of Senators and Members

2.12 Perhaps a more relevant table is that following, which details the ages at which and the periods in which parliamentarians were first elected. [13]

 

Age at which first elected

Period or Parliament Senate House of Reps Both Houses
       
1901-48 48.8 45.0 46.3
1949-79 47.8 42.1 43.9
1995 - all sitting Members & Senators 41.7 40.1 40.5
1996 - all sitting Members & Senators 41.4 40.6 40.9

2.13 These tables are somewhat difficult to reconcile and, given the limited statistical analysis available, the Committee is reluctant to draw firm conclusions. However, the evidence does indicate that there is probably a lowering in the age of initial election to the Parliament. The consequences are that parliamentarians are becoming eligible for pensions at a younger age. This factor, plus increases in life expectancy since the turn of the century, means that the costs, or potential costs, of these pensions is rising because recipients receive payments for a longer period.

 

The relative benefits to long and short term members

2.14 In Part B of this Report (the Judges section), the Committee examined the difficult issue of equity between members. The principles outlined there can be equally considered in relation to the parliamentary scheme. In that light, the PCSS can be seen as particularly generous to younger members who leave parliament soon after qualifying for a pension, and relatively less beneficial to long term members. Also, Mr Daryl Dixon, a superannuation consultant, found a 'discrimination':

2.15 These perceived inequities are well illustrated in the following graphs submitted the Government Actuary. The graphs show the actuarial value of benefits, as a multiple of the Parliamentary Allowance, that are provided to a 32 year-old new entrant to the PCSS. In the first graph there is no commutation of pension, while the lower graph assumes a 50 per cent commutation of any pension to a lump sum. [15]

2.16 The spectacular increase in the actuarial value of benefits around the pension qualifying period is obvious, while actuarial evidence is less necessary to understand that the longer time a pension is paid, the more overall benefit is received.

2.17 Further evidence on relative benefits was provided by the Parliamentary Retiring Allowances Trust, the body responsible for the PCSS. The Trust said:

 

Superannuation, parliamentarians and the wider community

2.18 In the previous chapter, major changes to the PCSS since the establishment of the scheme were outlined, with the last major changes to the structure being in 1973 (see paragraphs 1.3 to 1.9). The commutation option was established in 1978-79 (paragraph 1.8), and the changes since have been less major, and largely restricted to necessity. Examples include the introduction of the Superannuation Guarantee (SG), and correcting anomalies such as the 1983 revisions to the commutation percentage and to pensions under the office of profit provision.

2.19 In Australia over the past 18 years or so, there have been significant changes to the superannuation environment and in the community's involvement with superannuation. In the 1970's, superannuation was provided to relatively few in the workforce. Where it was provided, 'it was to look after those who retired after long service with the employer'. [17]

2.20 This situation fairly reflected, and indeed encouraged (to the limited extent that superannuation was provided), more stable employment patterns than is the case today. Generally, those who left employment prior to retirement received little in the way of employer support. In the case of parliamentarians, this generally meant that their only superannuation would be a pension under the PCSS.

2.21 Changes in the late 1980's and 1990's especially, have brought about near universal superannuation coverage for all in the workforce. Through the SG provisions particularly, much greater levels of employer support are provided for shorter term employees. As indicated by the Government Actuary, this means current parliamentarians are likely to receive superannuation benefits from employment before and after parliamentary life. Therefore, most future members of the PCSS will end up with significantly more superannuation than in the 1970's, when a parliamentarian was most likely to receive only a PCSS benefit. [18]

 

The nature of parliamentary life

2.22 In considering whether there are special aspects of the life of a federal politician that particularly affect the matter of superannuation that justify special superannuation provisions different from those applying in the general community, the Committee regarded the following factors as relevant:

Uncertainty

2.23 Election to Parliament by its very nature implies an uncertain future. Apart from the particular issues relating to marginal seats and election volatility, there is preselection and all the other stresses relating to political life. While the Committee fully recognises that many other occupations involve a greater or lesser degree of volatility, there are characteristics of parliamentary life that perhaps lead to a shorter and more intense career than many (if not most) others. This should be fairly reflected in the associated remuneration package.

 

Disruption

2.24 For many, the decision to seek and achieve parliamentary office involves considerable disruption to an established lifestyle and career. This point was well made by Mr Robert McClelland MP:

Post-parliamentary employment

2.25 Employment at the end of a parliamentary career is an issue closely related to that of career disruption on entering parliament. It is true that some former parliamentarians, particularly those who have held ministerial positions, find that their parliamentary experience opens up excellent opportunities for employment. For others, however, the situation is the reverse, and employment opportunities may be limited, especially with regard to the resumption of a former career.

2.26 Where a person leaves employment to become a member of parliament and subsequently has to re-establish a career after parliamentary life, Mr Wilson Tuckey MP said:

2.27 Mr McClelland MP also averted to the problem of re-establishment, in his case back into legal practice:

 

Early pensions

2.28 The availability of an indexed pension at an early age is probably the most criticised aspect of the PCSS. This is not a benefit provision unique to the PCSS, as other superannuation schemes also provide for a pension entitlement prior to retirement age. However, in the private sector, 'pensions tend to be either non-indexed or indexed subject to a certain cap or qualifier'. The Government Actuary added:

2.29 Dr FitzGerald also regarded the giving the same pension to members retiring regardless of age as 'quite unusual'. [23]

2.30 Regarding other public sector schemes which provide for early pensions, Mr Daryl Dixon cited the Commonwealth Superannuation Scheme which provides for Commonwealth public servants. In that scheme, the pension payable is discounted by three per cent a year 'for every year below the age of 60':

2.31 Mr Dixon considers the parliamentary pension should be defined as an age 60 pension, and discounted by an actuarial factor to mean there would be no pension payable at age 30. [25]

2.32 The Government Actuary provided an estimate of a 20 per cent saving in the cost of the PCSS for new members if pension benefits were not paid prior to age 55. [26]

 

Flexibility, portability and choice

2.33 As with all defined benefit schemes, there is an inherent inflexibility in the PCSS. Whether this is desirable can be seen in the light of the proposed reforms discussed in the next chapter. At this stage it is worth noting the inflexibility in contributions. With membership compulsory, members must contribute at the rate of eleven and one-half per cent for the first 18 years of membership and at five and three-quarters per cent for subsequent membership. By comparison, those schemes operating for Commonwealth public servants have allowed for a flexibility in contribution rates, with benefits varying accordingly.

2.34 The result of the inflexible nature of the PCSS is a lack of choice for individual parliamentarians. In view of the increasing prospect of new members bringing to their parliamentary life substantial superannuation as a result of other employment, it seems inefficient as well as unnecessary to be requiring them to contribute to a scheme which may result in them exceeding Reasonable Benefit Limits or exceeding their own superannuation requirements.

2.35 As part of its research on the issue of choice, the Committee examined the report of the Wallis Report on the Australian financial system. Recommendation 88 of that report said in part:

2.36 The Committee also recognises the lack of portability involved in the parliamentary scheme. While it is possible for a member of the PCSS to purchase notional past service which will be taken into account in determining future entitlements under the PCSS, this option is generally not taken up. Then, on leaving parliamentary service, there is no transferability of a PCSS pension entitlement to another scheme.

2.37 One possible solution to these dilemmas is for membership of the PCSS to be optional, to the extent that every parliamentarian is a member until he or she opts out.

 

To be or not be funded

2.38 The Government Actuary was equivocal on the issue of whether the PCSS should be funded. He indicated that to fund the scheme by paying the employer contributions would increase budget outlays in the first year by 'approximately $12 million':

2.39 In about 60 years time the cost to the budget of the PCSS would reduce to approximately $12 million in present day values. [28] To put this into context, net Commonwealth PCSS benefit expenditure in 1995-96 was $17 million. This was a heavy expenditure year because of the large turnover of members following the March 1996 election. For comparison the:

2.40 The Government Actuary considered if there were no change to the scheme, that 'PCSS expenditure will not have a material impact on future budgets'. [30]

2.41 Alternatively, the Commonwealth could take the decision to fund the whole unfunded liability now. That unfunded liability, calculated as part of the 1996 Long Term Cost Report on the PCSS, was $371 million. [31] Since the Government has indicated that it wishes employers to provide choice, a limited choice should also be provided for parliamentarians. This will inevitably lead to full funding for parliamentary superannuation.

 

Conclusion

2.42 The evidence outlined in this chapter indicates that the PCSS:

2.43 There is clearly a negative perception in the mind of the public about the scheme, and an uneasy relationship between the PCSS and superannuation in the broader community. In the light of these findings, the next chapter examines suggested reform.

 

[Return to Table of Contents]

Footnotes

[1] Submission No. 42, Department of Finance, p. 9.

[2] Paul Raffaele, Australia's Outrageous Parliamentary Pensions, Reader's Digest, January 1997.

[3] Submission No. 5, J.H. Jury.

[4] Submission No. 7, Mr J. Collins.

[5] Submission No. 16, Mr J. Bear.

[6] Submission No. 27, Mr & Ms A. & M. Thomson.

[7] Submission No. 37, Mr M. Quirk.

[8] Submission No. 38, Mr B. Fernandez.

[9] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 153.

[10] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 153.

[11] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 7.

[12] Statistics provided by Parliamentary Library Information Service to the Committee, 28 November 1997.

[13] Statistics provided by Parliamentary Library Information Service to the Committee, 19 June 1997, incorporating extracts from A Federal Legislature The Australian Commonwealth Parliament 1901-1980, by Joan Ryden, published 1980.

[14] Submission No. 48, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 2.

[15] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 7-8.

[16] Submission No. 43, Parliamentary Retiring Allowances Trust, pp. 2-3.

[17] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 9.

[18] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 9.

[19] Submission No. 24, Mr Robert McClelland MP.

[20] Evidence, Mr Wilson Tuckey MP, p. 149.

[21] Evidence, Mr Robert McClelland MP, p. 128.

[22] Evidence, Mr Craig Thorburn, p. 126.

[23] Evidence, Dr Vincent FitzGerald, p. 153.

[24] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 130.

[25] Evidence, Mr Daryl Dixon, p. 132.

[26] Supplementary Submission to No. 42, Australian Government Actuary.

[27] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 21.

[28] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 21.

[29] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 19.

[30] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 19.

[31] Submission No. 42, Australian Government Actuary, p. 20.