Chapter 4
Treasury modelling
Introduction
4.1
The Department of the Treasury (the Treasury) undertook modelling on
behalf of the Australian Government entitled Australia’s Low Pollution
Future: The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation (Treasury modelling).
4.2
The modelling examined 'four alternative scenarios in which Australia
and the world follow pathways to a low-pollution future'.[1]
Two of these scenarios assume a global stabilisation goal of 550 parts per
million (ppm) of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2-e) in the atmosphere
while the two remaining scenarios assume global stabilisation goals of 450 and
510 ppm. Each of these scenarios is compared against the 'reference case' which
assumes no mitigation occurs. The reference case does not account for any
impact of climate change on the economy.
4.3
The committee received extensive evidence raising serious concerns about
the modelling undertaken by the Treasury and identifying flaws in the
modelling.
4.4
It appears to the committee that the purpose of the Treasury modelling,
from the government's point of view, was to present the most benign picture possible
of the impact of the Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme (CPRS) on the economy
and jobs.
4.5
Following the evidence presented, it is the view of the committee that
the Treasury modelling was limited and flawed in that it:
-
Assumed other countries would sign up to reducing emissions;
-
Did not assess the impact of the current significant global
economic downturn;
-
Did not assess the impact on regional economies, which, as
outlined later in this chapter, can and has been undertaken by Frontier
Economics;
-
Assumed in its modelling that full employment would be
maintained;
-
Overstated the assistance to some industries;
-
Did not include the effective rates of compensation to industry;
-
Did not take account of the specific circumstances of the Western
Australian electricity market; and
-
Did not model, as far as the committee is aware, the features of
the actual proposed CPRS.
4.6
The Department of the Treasury provided evidence that the 'scenarios
that were modelled by Treasury were done at the direction of the government.'[2]
4.7
This raises the question why the government did not ask the Treasury to
model some more realistic scenarios, in particular a scenario in which the rest
of the world does not take action to the same extent as Australia, as assumed
in the modelling, and in which the global economic downturn will impact the
viability of Australian businesses and their ability to compete
internationally.
4.8
The committee found it very hard to understand why the government would
not have asked Treasury to assess the impact of the proposed scheme on regional
economies to better inform the design of the scheme and to ensure any
transitional assistance could be better targeted.
4.9
The committee considers the modelling undertaken by the Treasury to be
inadequate and that the government should direct the Treasury to undertake and
publish modelling of the impact of the CPRS:
-
assuming
little or no action by Australia's major competitors to reduce greenhouse gas
emissions;
-
taking
account of the economic conditions due to the global economic downturn;
-
on
industry at a sectoral level, including the effective rates of compensation to
industry;
-
on
regional economies; and
-
in
comparison with modelling of a variety of viable alternative policy scenarios
aimed at Australia contributing to the reduction of global greenhouse gas
emissions.
Peer review commissioned by the committee
4.10
In order to properly analyse the modelling undertaken by the Department
of the Treasury, the committee commissioned a peer review of the modelling. The
committee commissioned the review following issues raised during the early part
of the inquiry as to the veracity of the modelling and thus the impacts of the
government's proposed policy.
4.11
The review was undertaken by Dr Brian Fisher, of Concept Economics, formerly
Executive Director of the Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource
Economics (ABARE), and a recognised economist in the area of emissions trading.
4.12
Among the key findings of the review were:
Taking account of assumptions in both the reference scenario
and the policy scenarios in the Treasury modelling, this review concludes that
the most problematic elements surround:
-
sectoral
marginal abatement cost curves that in a number of emissions-intensive
industries appear to admit very significant mitigation at relatively low cost;
-
electricity
sector transformation assumptions that appear to underestimate significantly
the cost and structural adjustment challenge of moving to a decarbonised electricity
generation sector;
-
long-term
commodity price assumptions that in some cases depart significantly from
industry estimates;
-
international
action assumptions that are highly optimistic given the intrinsic nature of the
climate change problem and the institutional framework in which international
negotiations take place; and
-
emission
pricing and permit trading assumptions that bias the results toward
artificially low costs of mitigation.[3]
4.13
Dr Fisher went on to state:
...the interaction of these assumptions is likely to result in
the Treasury modelling seriously underestimating the economy-wide and sectoral
challenges associated with particular emissions reduction targets, particularly
in the short to medium term. The implications are especially important for
Australia’s emission-intensive, trade-exposed (EITE) industries and for the
electricity generation sector.[4]
4.14
The review examined the Treasury modelling with respect to a range of issues
including:
-
sensitivity analysis of the assumptions on which the modelling
was undertaken;
-
the impact on global emissions of the government's proposed
emissions trading scheme (ETS) and the potential leakage of Australian jobs and
industry;
-
the consequences of more realistic assumptions concerning the
likelihood of other countries taking similar action to that proposed by
Australia; and
-
the failure to include the impact of the global financial crisis
(GFC) on Australia's capacity to bear the costs of participation in a global
ETS and the rate at which other countries will commence participation in a
global emissions trading scheme.
The full terms of reference for the review can be found at appendix
6.
Additional information sought from the government by the committee
4.15
The committee is concerned by the government's lack of transparency and
public accountability when it comes to the Treasury modelling of the economic
impact of the proposed CPRS.
4.16
In order to allow a proper assessment and scrutiny of the government's
modelling, the committee, on behalf of the Senate, states and territories,
industry, unions and the Australian public at large needed and deserved access
to all the unpublished modelling information used by the government. This
included unrestricted access to all of the government's assumptions, model
codes and databases among other information.
4.17
In order to allow a comprehensive analysis of the modelling undertaken
by the Treasury the committee sought additional information which had not been
made available in the public domain. The committee considered the gaining of
this information to be in the public interest and necessary for the committee
to properly undertake the task of scrutinising the government's proposed CPRS.
4.18
To date the government has not provided a proper explanation as to why
the information sought by the committee, and ordered to be produced by the
Senate has not been provided.
4.19
The committee is extremely concerned about this lack of public
accountability on behalf of the government in relation to a major policy
proposal with serious potential implications for the Australian economy and
jobs.
4.20
Many witnesses raised concerns about the amount of publicly available
information concerning the modelling undertaken by the Treasury. For example,
Ms Amy Lomas, Assistant Director, Emissions Trading Unit, the Western Australia
Department of Treasury and Finance stated:
We have undertaken a number of different steps to obtain
access to the data that supports the release of the Australia’s low pollution
future report by the Commonwealth Treasury and we have had a response via email
which indicates to us that they are not able to provide us with any data other
than what is already in the public domain. That has meant that we have had to
rethink our approach to how we advise the state government on how the CPRS is likely
to affect Western Australia.[5]
4.21
Ms Lomas detailed for the committee the information the Western
Australia Department of Treasury and Finance had been seeking and had not
gained as follows:
For Western Australia, we are after time series data of
industry growth output in millions of dollars and employment numbers for the
two scenarios that they modelled for the CPRS—that is, the CPRS minus five per
cent and the CPRS minus 15 per cent—and obviously the reference case scenarios
that would apply as well. That would give us data for every year out to 2050
for Western Australia. Sorry, that is for Australia. We are also after the
equivalent for Western Australia so that we can compare it, and any substate
information that is comparable, so industry gross output by, say, regions—the
Pilbara region or the south-west. We do not have any substate regional data.
We are also after gross state product time series data, again
for those two scenarios, so that we can actually see what the nominal values
would be for gross state product out to 2050. We are after time series data of
emissions. If you look at the Commonwealth Treasury modelling, there is no
information in there for states and territories on their actual emissions
levels, so I could not tell you if Western Australia’s emissions are forecast
to decline relative to 2000 in the Commonwealth Treasury modelling report, and
we are also after price changes for household consumables. We do not have any
indication of which products households would be purchasing and what the
relative changes in prices would be for those.[6]
4.22
The committee also noted the view expressed by Professor Warwick
McKibbin, who stated that 'I am a big fan of open access and open source, and
anything that I do which is funded by public money is publicly available.'[7]
4.23
When asked why modelling information was being kept secret, Ms Meghan Quinn
from the Department of the Treasury stated:
I draw your attention to the information that is available
from the modelling exercise undertaken by Treasury and other external
consultants. My understanding is that it is the most comprehensive
documentation available in Australia and comparable exercises. We have
published comprehensive background consulting reports on the internet. All the
underlying data that is contained in the report is available on the webpage,
including all the data underlying all the charts. So there is a comprehensive
set of information. It is more comprehensive than other publicly available
information on comparable modelling in Australia or overseas. So it is not fair
to say that there is not comprehensive information available in the public
domain for you to look at.[8]
4.24
The committee was not at all satisfied with the explanation provided.
The committee was not seeking access to publicly available 'background
consulting reports' but to unpublished underlying data, assumptions, model
codes and databases among other things that were vitally important to assess
the credibility of the government's conclusions about the economic impact of
the proposed CPRS. If all the information was indeed publicly available why has
the government not complied with the Senate's order of 11 March 2009 (as
discussed below), pointing out that all the information requested was already
publicly available. It is clear that this information is not publicly available.
4.25
In attempting to gain the additional information, in the first instance
the committee questioned the Department of the Treasury about the release of
information to organisations seeking additional information about the
modelling. Ms Quinn stated 'Any additional information requested from an
industry, a stakeholder, a non-government organisation or state government is a
matter for the government to decide whether it is released or not.'[9]
4.26
The committee wrote to the Treasurer, the Hon. Wayne Swan MP, on
9 December 2008 requesting that:
Dr Fisher be afforded full access to the government's
complete documentation of the government's models together with the model codes
and databases and any other model simulations undertaken relevant to the policy
scenarios, but not publicly released.[10]
4.27
The Treasurer's response, which was only received on 3 February 2009,
after the committee had given notice of a motion to order the production of
information in the Senate, refused the committee's request and stated that:
The Treasury's climate change mitigation modelling was
undertaken in conjunction with external consultants. The Treasury is
obligated, under contractual agreements with these consultants, to not disclose
or make public any Confidential Information of the other party. The
information includes model codes and databases.[11]
4.28
On 4 February 2009 the Senate made an order requiring the
production of information by 5 February 2009:
CARBON POLLUTION REDUCTION SCHEME—TREASURY MODELLING—ORDER
FOR PRODUCTION OF DOCUMENTS
The Chair of the Select Committee on Fuel and Energy (Senator
Cormann) amended general business notice of motion no. 334 by leave and,
pursuant to notice of motion not objected to as a formal motion, moved—That the
Senate—
-
notes that:
-
the Select Committee on Fuel and Energy contracted Dr Brian Fisher from
Concept Economics to conduct an independent peer review of the Department of
the Treasury modelling of the impact of the Government’s proposed Carbon
Pollution Reduction Scheme,
-
the committee wrote to the Treasurer (Mr Swan) on 9 December 2008 requesting
that Dr Fisher, be given ‘full access to the government’s complete
documentation of the government’s models together with the model codes and
databases and any other model simulations undertaken relevant to the policy
scenarios, but not publicly released’ by 17 December 2008,
-
the Treasurer has refused the committee’s request, and
-
Dr Fisher has reported that he was impeded in carrying out the work requested
by the committee because the information requested from the Treasurer was not
made available to him; and
-
orders that there be laid on the
table by the Minister representing the Treasurer, no later than noon on 5
February 2009, the following information relating to the Department of the
Treasury modelling, Australia’s low pollution future: The economics of
climate change mitigation:
-
the model documentation and codes together with all databases for both the
global trade and environment model and the Monash multi-regional forecasting
model that were employed in the department’s modelling of the Carbon Pollution
Reduction Scheme scenarios in a form that would allow the reproduction of the
department’s results, and
-
any other model simulations undertaken relevant to the abovementioned policy
scenarios but not publicly released.[12]
4.29
Senator Ursula Stephens, Parliamentary Secretary for Social Inclusion
and the Voluntary Sector, made the following statement in the Senate on behalf
of the government on 5 February 2009:
The Treasury's climate change mitigation modelling is one of
the largest and most complex economic modelling projects ever undertaken in
Australia, and extensive documentation of the project has already been made
publicly available. The Treasury's climate change mitigation modelling was
undertaken in conjunction with external consultants. The Treasury is obligated,
under contractual agreements with the consultants, to not disclose or make
public any confidential information of the other party. This information
includes model codes and databases, and it is likely that external consultants
would be subject to commercial harm if the Treasury were to release to the
committee any model codes or databases covered by such contractual agreements.[13]
4.30
On 6 February 2009 the committee wrote to the Treasurer
referring to the statement made by Senator Stephens on 5 February 2009
and pointing out that the Senate, in passing the order of 4 February 2009,
had effectively accepted the judgement of the committee that contractual
obligations to consultants did not constitute a valid reason for declining to
produce the documents. The letter quoted the relevant resolution of the Senate
of 30 October 2003 which provides:
The Senate and Senate committees shall not entertain any
claim to withhold information from the Senate or a committee on the grounds
that it is commercial-in-confidence, unless the claim is made by a minister and
is accompanied by a statement setting out the basis for the claim, including a
statement of any commercial harm that may result from the disclosure of the
information.[14]
The letter to the Treasurer requested a statement of the
nature of the commercial harm claimed.
4.31
Senator Stephens made the following further statement in the Senate on
behalf of the government on 11 February 2009, attempting to make the
case of commercial harm:
The government believes that the provision of documents
related to the modelling conducted for Australia’s low pollution future: the economics
of climate change mitigation would cause substantial commercial harm to
organisations that were contracted to assist Treasury. In the case of the
Monash Multi-Regional Forecasting model, the MMRF model, provision of the model
codes and database would cause substantial commercial harm to Monash
University—in particular, to the Centre of Policy Studies at that university.
The model codes and databases for this model are the private, confidential information
of that organisation. They are sold as a commercial product by Monash
University. Disclosure of these model codes and databases would have the result
that other organisations would have had access to this information without
entering into a commercial arrangement with Monash University. In effect,
Monash University would be deprived of the value of the model codes and
databases, resulting in commercial harm through the loss of the market to which
they had previously sold their products.
In the case of the Global Trade and Environment Model, the
GTEM, provision of the database would cause substantial commercial harm to the
Centre for Global Trade Analysis at Purdue University. The Centre for Global
Trade Analysis provides the global trade analysis project database from which
the database for the GTEM has been derived. Disclosure of this GTEM database
would have the effect of disclosing a substantial portion of the private,
confidential information of the Centre for Global Trade Analysis. Disclosure of
this database would have the result that other organisations would have access
to this information, again without entering into a commercial arrangement with
the Centre for Global Trade Analysis. This would prejudice the ability of the
Centre for Global Trade Analysis to sell access to the database in Australian
and world markets, resulting in commercial harm through the loss of the market
to which they have previously sold their products.[15]
4.32
Following the response from the government the committee wrote to Monash
University and Purdue University on 11 February 2009 seeking to work
with the universities to protect the intellectual property of the universities
while allowing the committee to properly scrutinise the material.[16]
4.33
On 12 February 2009 the committee received correspondence from
Purdue University stating that commercial harm to its Global Trade and Analysis
Project, would be avoided by the simple purchase of a licence.[17]
4.34
On 19 February 2009 the committee received correspondence from
Monash University which stated that 'The University wishes to assist your
Committee in every way possible' and that the University would be in contact
with the committee to arrange how the university could 'meet the Committee's
needs as far as possible while protecting the University's interests'.[18]
4.35
On 11 March 2009 the Senate made a further order requiring the
production of information, on this occasion by 13 March 2009. This
order recognised that:
-
irrespective of the government's statement in the Senate on 11 February 2009
it is in the public interest that all underlying information used by Treasury
in its modelling be available to help facilitate proper scrutiny by the Senate
of the impact of the government's Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme;
-
models used in the modelling exercise developed using public funding
ought to be publicly available; and
-
where the public release of information is likely to cause significant
commercial harm to an external organisation every effort ought to be made to
prevent that harm while not preventing the Senate from fulfilling its proper
role to scrutinise the activities and proposals of government.[19]
4.36
The order specified that some of the requested information was to be
treated as confidential by the committee, any senator and any other person
authorised to access the information under the order. The order stated that:
...the committee may refer to the information produced to it in
accordance with this order and any conclusions reached from it in a report to
the Senate, but shall not disclose the information in such a report.[20]
4.37
These specific and strong confidentiality requirements mean that any
disclosure or use of the information otherwise than in accordance with the
order would be a contempt of the Senate and a criminal offence under the Parliamentary
Privileges Act 1987.
4.38
Following the above order of the Senate, on 12 March 2009 the
committee again wrote to Monash University informing them of the order and
seeking to establish whether the protections afforded by the Senate
sufficiently protect Monash University's intellectual property in relation to
the Monash Multi Regional Forecasting model (MMRF). The committee also
requested that the university write to the Treasurer, advising that the
university has no objection to the government releasing the requested
information according to the terms of the Senate order.
4.39
On 17 March 2009 Senator Stephens made a further statement to the Senate
regarding the required documentation. Senator Stephens, in response to the
Senate order of 11 March 2009, stated:
...the government continues to believe that the provision of
the proprietary model code and data related to the modelling conducted for
Australia’s low pollution future: the economics of climate change mitigation
would cause commercial harm to organisations that were contracted to assist
Treasury.[21]
4.40
Senator Stephens concluded by stating 'Until these serious matters of
commercial harm are resolved to the documented satisfaction of the external
consultants, the government will not consider this matter further.'[22]
4.41
The committee received further correspondence from Monash University on
18 March 2009 which included a letter sent by the university to the
Treasurer which stated:
I confirm that Monash University wishes to assist the
Committee and in accordance with the above mentioned letter agrees to waive its
confidentiality requirements on the basis that Order
SJ61-11 March 2009 applies to the disclosure and that it overrides
the provisions of Senate Standing Order 37 to the extent that Standing Order 37
would otherwise allow disclosure of information obtained from Monash University
to persons other than those detailed in paragraph 4 of Order
SJ61-11 March 2009.
Monash University waives its requirements of confidentiality
on the basis that confidentiality is protected under the provisions of Order
SJ61-11 March 2009 and disclosure will only be made to the persons
referred to in paragraph 4 of Order SJ61-11 March 2009 who are
subject to the confidentiality restrictions detailed in paragraph 5 of Order
SJ61-11 March 2009.[23]
4.42
Following receipt of the above correspondence from Monash University,
the committee wrote to the Treasurer on 18 March 2009 reiterating the
committee's judgement 'that contractual obligations to consultants do not
constitute a valid reason for declining to produce information' and pointing
out that 'given the information is required under an order of the Senate,
parliamentary privilege overrides any relevant contractual obligations of the
government.'[24]
4.43
Importantly, the committee also pointed out that the government's claim
of commercial harm related to only part of the information required under the
orders and ignores the majority of the information sought.
4.44
The committee requested from the Treasurer:
-
that you provide all of the information as ordered by the Senate on 11
March 2009 by midday 19 March 2009; and
-
if you do not provide the information, that you provide a statement by
close of business 19 March 2009 explaining:
-
the
basis on which the government continues to refuse to provide the information
sought by the Committee that does not relate to the intellectual property of
Monash University or Purdue University, including all of the information
required under 3(b) of the 11 March 2009 order of the Senate;
-
the
basis on which the government continues to refuse to provide the information
sought by the Committee that relates to Monash University given the university
has waived its requirements of confidentiality; and
-
the
reason the government continues to refuse to release to the Committee the
information relating to Purdue University given the specific confidentiality
requirements contained in the order.[25]
4.45
The committee again heard evidence from the Department of the Treasury
on 2 April 2009. When asked about the government's failure to comply
with the orders of the Senate, Ms Quinn stated:
The position that the government has made clear in the Senate
is that it believes there is the potential for commercial harm for aspects of
the information to be provided. It is a matter for the government.[26]
4.46
Following the above evidence from the Treasury, and the absence of a response
to the committee's letter of 18 March 2009, the committee again wrote
to the Treasurer on 3 April 2009. The letter stated:
The Committee has conscientiously sought to address the
concerns raised by the Government regarding the provision of the requested
information and has actively sought to protect the intellectual property of the
universities. Monash University's unusual and specific notification to you of
its willingness to release the information in question in accordance with the
Senate order clearly indicates that commercial harm is not an issue. The Committee
views this response from the Government and the Department of Treasury as
unnecessarily bureaucratic, baseless and deliberately unhelpful to the
Committee.
The Committee considers the responses received to date from
the Government to be seriously detrimental to the Committee's ability to
properly scrutinise the proposed Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme and
therefore at odds with the public interest.
The Committee yet again asks:
-
that you provide all of the information as ordered by the Senate on 11 March
2009 by midday 7 April 2009; and
-
if you do not provide the information, that you provide a statement by
close of business 7 April 2009 explaining:
-
the
basis on which the government continues to refuse to provide the information
sought by the Committee that does not relate to the intellectual property of
Monash University or Purdue University, including all of the information
required under 3(b) of the 11 March 2009 order of the Senate;
-
the
basis on which the government continues to refuse to provide the information
sought by the Committee that relates to Monash University given the university
has waived its requirements of confidentiality; and
-
the
reason the government continues to refuse to release to the Committee the
information relating to Purdue University given the specific confidentiality
requirements contained in the order.[27]
4.47
At the time of publishing, the committee has not received any of the
information ordered by the Senate, or any response to its letter to the
Treasurer dated 3 April 2009.
4.48
The committee considers the government's failure to release the
information as ordered by the Senate to be a major failure of accountability
and transparency. The government is proposing a major policy change which the
Australian people should be able to properly scrutinise to assess the basis on
which the government has formed its views and the likely impact of the policy.
The government's lack of transparency has left the Australian people unable to
have a properly informed debate.
4.49
In this context the committee notes the government's stated commitment to
being open and accountable. Only recently Senator the Hon. John Faulkner,
Special Minister of State, stated on behalf of the government that:
...the best safeguard against ill-informed public judgement is
not concealment but information. As Abraham Lincoln said: "Let the people
know the facts, and the country will be safe."[28]
4.50
The committee is of the view that the only conclusion that can be
reached from the government's persistent refusal to release the information as
ordered by the Senate is an attempt by the government to cover up important
information that would help Australians to more properly assess the impact of
the proposed CPRS, in particular it effect on the economy and jobs.
4.51
The committee believes that there is a strong likelihood that the impact
of the scheme as proposed by the government on the economy and jobs is in fact
worse than what the Australian people are led to believe. Why else would the
government not agree to submit its modelling to rigorous scrutiny and peer
review, making all of the necessary information available?
Consequence of limited information
available for peer review
4.52
Dr Fisher's report included comment on the importance of transparency in
modelling exercises as well as the issues he faced given the limited
information available to him. Dr Fisher stated:
Although the public report on the Treasury modelling is
voluminous there remain aspects of the modelling that are not transparent...it
has been necessary to undertake this review without access to a complete set of
information about model documentation, databases, implementation and many of
the underlying technical model parameters. Given the major long-term structural
changes to the Australian economy implied by the introduction of an ETS and the
fact that the development of the key model employed to determine the
international effects on the Australian economy of the scheme was fully
tax-payer funded, it seems reasonable that full model datasets, codes and
comprehensive documentation be released.[29]
Dr Fisher also stated:
Among the factors that determine the integrity of any
modelling exercise include the quality of the data, the credibility of
assumptions and scenarios, the model closure framework and the ease with which
the model(s) results can be reproduced. In other words, a rigorous approach to
modelling demands a high level of transparency.
As already stated this review regards the transparency
surrounding the Treasury modelling process as unsatisfactory, notwithstanding
the efforts of the Committee to gain access to models, documentation, codes and
databases developed with public funding.[30]
Committee comment
4.53
The committee is of the view that it is in the public interest for the
government to release all of the information as ordered by the Senate on
11 March 2009.
Peer review report
4.54
This part of the report discusses the conclusions and key findings of Dr
Fisher's review. Given the broad range of issues covered in Dr Fisher's
report, the findings will be discussed by theme.
4.55
Dr Fisher's conclusions regarding the Treasury modelling and the
government's proposed CPRS include:
It is important, nonetheless, that Australia not be
complacent about the scale of economic transformation in prospect under an ETS,
either at an economy-wide or sectoral level. Those who suggest that the
Treasury modelling confirms that Australia’s economy could accommodate easily
much larger emission targets than those proposed by the Government seem willing
to overlook the limitations that surround even the most careful of modelling
exercises.[31]
And:
An emissions trading scheme and associated medium and
long-term targets will have profound economic implications for every Australian
business and household. That Australia’s economy may be on the brink of the
greatest economic slump in more than half a century only reinforces the need
for prudent decision-making, notwithstanding the results of the Treasury
modelling about Australia’s smooth transition to a low carbon future.[32]
4.56
As set out above, the key findings of Dr Fisher's review included the
likely underestimation of the economy wide and sectoral challenges associated
with emissions reduction targets, particularly in the short to medium term.
International action assumptions
and likelihood of global action
4.57
In relation to the international action assumptions in the Treasury
modelling, Dr Fisher stated:
The starting point for the modelling is the statement that:
‘Because responding to climate change is a global challenge, this report
evaluates the impacts on Australia in the context of global action to reduce
emissions’ (Treasury 2008a, p. 3). From this premise, Treasury’s analytical
framework yields a self-reinforcing, virtuous circle of domestic and
international benefits. Hence: ‘Strong global coordinated action accelerates
cost reductions in low-emission technologies, prevents lock-in of more
emission-intensive industry and infrastructure, and minimises distortions in
trade-exposed sectors’ (Treasury 2008a, p. 89).
...
A serious gap in the released Treasury modelling results is
the failure to publish the results from any policy scenario where ‘strong
coordinated global action’ on climate change is not forthcoming. This
deficiency is all the more notable given:
-
the
intrinsic nature of the collective action problem surrounding climate change;
-
the
manifest failings of the existing international climate change architecture;
and
-
the
explicit adoption by the Government of a medium-term national target range that
includes an unconditional commitment to reduce Australia’s emissions
irrespective of the actions of other countries.[33]
4.58
Dr Fisher also stated:
Ideally, Treasury’s scenarios should have taken account of
global, group and independent action by Australia, a view shared not only by a
range of stakeholders but also, it would appear, by the Government’s premier
advisory body on structural reform (Productivity Commission 2007, p. 11).[34]
4.59
Regarding term of reference 4.1, the consequences of more realistic
assumptions concerning the likelihood of the rest of the world taking similar
actions to Australia, Dr Fisher made the following statement:
The likely consequences of what this review regards as a more
realistic set of assumptions on global action include the following:
-
estimated
emission prices in Australia are likely to be higher for a given emissions
reduction trajectory;
-
the cost of
emission reductions to the Australian economy are likely to be higher;
-
the postulated
gains from early action by Australia are likely to be less or non existent;
-
the degree of
competitive disadvantage faced by Australia’s EITE sector would be greater; and
-
the risk of
serious disruption surrounding the transformation of Australia’s stationary
energy sector would be greater.[35]
4.60
Dr Fisher went on to say that there is 'little in the recent experience
of international climate change negotiations that points the way to the
Treasury scenario of "strong coordinated global action" involving all
major emitters'[36]
and:
In reality, there is almost no prospect of non-Annex B
countries taking on binding emission restraints under a post-2012 international
climate change agreement arising from the UN climate change summit in
Copenhagen. Any new agreement will have to allow for different types of
mitigation commitment. The best that could be hoped for in coming years is for
developing countries to engage gradually in an international framework via
policy-based commitments.[37]
4.61
In relation to term of reference 4.2, the consequences of more realistic
assumptions concerning the participation of China in a global ETS by 2015, Dr Fisher
concluded that the 'Treasury modelling assumptions appears to regard China's
position in international climate change negotiations as a giant bluff.'[38]
4.62
Dr Fisher, addressing term of reference 4.3, concluded that 'the
prospects of India pricing emissions by 2020 appear slim.'[39]
4.63
Addressing term of reference 4.4, Dr Fisher concluded that:
...there is little prospect of the United States agreeing in
the near term to anything approaching the national emissions allocation
framework modelled by the Treasury. The modelling relies on especially heroic
assumptions in terms of the timing and nature of future US commitments to
emissions reduction targets within an international agreement.[40]
4.64
In relation to term of reference 4.5, the consequences of more realistic
assumptions concerning the likelihood of a global agreement being sustained
through the year 2050, Dr Fisher stated that 'No less formidable than the task
of reaching a comprehensive global agreement on climate change will be
sustaining one'.[41]
He also stated:
Recognising that it is impossible to predict with any
precision the specific course of international developments, it would have been
useful if the Australian Government had explored likely areas of institutional
stress in formulating the parameters of the Green Paper, the White Paper and
the Treasury modelling.
This would have assisted policy makers in gaining a better
understanding of the likely dynamics of future global cooperation. At the
moment, the dominant approach seems based on willing all national governments
to act without a clear understanding of the incentives of particular groups of
countries. Australia has put its faith squarely behind a Kyoto-based approach
which has demonstrated its incapacity to engender comprehensive engagement.[42]
Impact of the CPRS on the economy,
industry, employment and the environment
4.65
In relation to term of reference 2.1, the impact on global emissions of
the government's proposed ETS and the potential leakage of Australian jobs and
industry in emissions intensive trade exposed industries such as aluminium, liquid
natural gas (LNG), cement and agriculture, Dr Fisher stated:
...many Australian industries, particularly in the traded-good
sector, face a major competitive challenge under a domestic ETS. Just as
Australia is a climate taker, not a climate maker, it is also the case that
Australia is a price taker in global markets, not a price maker for the very
large majority of the commodities that we produce.
An ETS could impose significant costs on Australian
operations and bias investment decisions toward countries with lesser
constraints on emissions. Hence the competitive impact on Australia’s
emission-intensive, trade-exposed industries – including aluminium, LNG, cement
and agriculture – is likely to be substantial in an environment where
international action on mitigation is likely to be slow, fragmented and
partial.
On the basis of recent data, EITE industries account for 16
per cent of Australian business investment, 51 per cent of exports, 15 per cent
of gross value added and employ nearly one in 10 working Australians (BCA
2008). The imposition of additional costs not faced by competitors is likely to
constrain employment, investment and growth in these industries, with the
potential for economic activity to shift to locations without a carbon price.
...
Over 80 per cent of Australia’s exports go to countries that
are unlikely to be subject to a carbon constraint in the near term. Around 75
per cent of Australia’s imports come from similar countries. Notably, these
figures are significantly higher than developed countries in Europe given high
levels of intra-EU trade. For example, the relevant figures for the United
Kingdom are roughly 40 per cent (PJP 2008, p. 17). This suggests, in turn, that
competitiveness and carbon leakage problems may be more significant for
Australia’s EITE sector than for emissions-intensive industries in many other
developed countries.
Notwithstanding modifications in the White Paper, the
Government’s proposed ETS looks set to impose greater competitiveness imposts
on Australian EITE industries than will apply under any other current or
proposed scheme, including the European ETS.[43]
Further, he stated:
With its international action assumptions, the Treasury
modelling largely assumes away what Garnaut described as the ‘truly dreadful
problem’ of Australia’s EITE industries facing a carbon price while their
international competitors take no action (Garnaut 2008a, chapter 13).
...
The Treasury report also concludes that there is ‘little
evidence of carbon leakage’ at the relevant emission prices with noticeable
impacts only occurring at higher emission prices, roughly double the price of
the CPRS -5 scenario (Treasury 2008a, p. 169). Again, given the questions
raised above about the international action assumptions this is not an
especially credible result.
...
A final point worth noting is that the competitive impact on
EITE industries of an ETS is likely to be felt most keenly in regional and
remote Australia, often in locations with limited alternative sources of
economic activity of such high value. The minerals industry, for example, is
especially important to the economies of Western Australia, Queensland and the
Northern Territory.[44]
4.66
Regarding the impact on global emissions of the government's proposed ETS
and the potential leakage of Australian jobs and industry in non trade exposed
industries such as electricity, Dr Fisher stated that 'the Government’s
proposed ETS will have profound competitive implications for many operators in
Australia’s electricity generation sector.'[45]
Dr Fisher also stated:
In line with the treatment of other sectors, most of the
discussion of the electricity industry in the Treasury modelling report centres
on a smooth, long-run transformation of the industry toward decarbonisation.
There is relatively little that sheds light on the short- to medium term
adjustment path of the sector and, as noted earlier, what analysis there is
rests on assumptions about pass-through rates and strategic price setting
behaviour. Also significant is the statement that the report projects
retirement of electricity generators by modelling them as physical economic
assets, with no account taken of ‘the impact of financial considerations, such
as debt-equity ratios or ownership structures’ on retirement decisions’
(Treasury 2008a, p. 178).[46]
4.67
In relation to the third term of reference, the economic and
environmental consequences of the government's proposed eligibility thresholds
for emissions intensive, trade exposed (EITE) industry assistance, Dr Fisher
stated that the proposed scheme 'by design, delivers only partial assistance to
EITE industries.'[47]
Dr Fisher also stated:
There is no detailed economic analysis underpinning the
designated assistance thresholds which seek to identify Australian industries
that would be viable and sustainable under a global carbon constraint.
In these circumstances, there remains a clear risk under the
ETS that industries will move from Australia to elsewhere, with no benefit in
terms of global emissions reductions. This would be contrary both to economic
efficiency and to environmental effectiveness.
Second, there are major discontinuities in assistance rates,
which in turn can lead to unintended consequences and distorted investment
decisions.[48]
4.68
Dr Fisher further stated that 'there are obvious anomalies such as the
exclusion of the coal industry from the assistance regime that appear to
reflect an element of politicisation of the scheme.'[49]
4.69
Addressing term of reference 10.1, the impact on unemployment of the
government's ETS and a rising carbon price in all years that the scheme is in
place, Dr Fisher stated:
As far as the reviewer is aware the general equilibrium
models employed by the Treasury assume that real wages adjust downwards
following the introduction of the ETS to ensure that the long run equilibrium
rate of unemployment is maintained. This is a common closure for such models.
It follows that estimates of possible additions to unemployment have not been
made as far as the reviewer is aware.
Real wages decline steadily over time, relative to the
reference scenario. This assumes that individuals will willingly accept ongoing
downward real wage adjustments below what they otherwise would have received,
without any adverse impacts on labour market outcomes at the sectoral or
aggregate level. Labour inputs are assumed to costlessly shift between
sectors. These assumptions ignore some of the key existing institutional
realities of the Australian labour market, as well as any impact that the
introduction of new regulatory arrangements on labour markets might have. These
appear to be major oversights.[50]
4.70
Addressing term of reference 14, the economic impact of the government's
ETS on farming and agricultural industries, even if those industries are not
covered in any scheme before 2015, Dr Fisher stated:
The overall impacts of the scheme on the farm sector will be
largely determined by the actions of our overseas competitors. If those
competitors do not introduce equivalent schemes and agriculture is not
effectively shielded then a large share of the input cost increases of a scheme
will be borne by farmers who will become less profitable relative to what
otherwise would have occurred.
In a practical sense there are no commercially available
technologies that exist today that could be applied to reduce methane emissions
in the extensive rangeland based livestock industries. In addition, it will be
challenging to devise a means of determining which producers have actually
reduced emissions and which have not so it is likely that the monitoring and
enforcement costs in agriculture will be much higher than in other parts of the
economy.[51]
Global financial crisis
4.71
In response to term of reference 5.1, the failure to include the impact
of the GFC on Australia's capacity to bear the costs of participation in a
global ETS, Dr Fisher stated:
The global financial crisis and its flow-on to the real
economy has altered dramatically the context in which Australia will be
introducing an ETS and taking, in all likelihood, unconditional action to reduce
emissions. By contrast, the Treasury modelling exercise and much of the
decision-making on scheme design has assumed, often explicitly, a continuation
of strong global and domestic growth, both in the implementation phase of the
ETS and in the longer term.
...
The simple fact is that an ETS imposes a new cost on
Australian producers and consumers. A critical concern surrounds the impact of
the imposition of this additional cost of production on Australian firms at a
time when company balance sheets have deteriorated dramatically, investment
plans have been shelved and workers are being dismissed.
Other concerns relate to the impact of the financial crisis
on the effective cost of capital. With the Treasury modelling already
underpinned by very optimistic cost of capital assumptions relating to new
electricity generation plant, it seems naïve to expect new low-emissions
technology suppliers to seamlessly replace any short-fall in capacity due to
the closure of fossil-fuel based plants.
The global financial crisis should also puncture the air of
complacency that has surrounded the financial burden an ETS places on
Australian businesses competing in the global marketplace. Against a backdrop
of high commodity prices, there was a widely-shared presumption in official
circles that the imposition of a carbon price in advance of other competitor
nations would have only a minor adverse impact on key Australian export
industries.
With commodity prices in some cases down 50 per cent from
their peak and export-oriented companies looking to reduce costs wherever
possible, measures that cannot be recovered through increased prices establish
a significant disincentive to investment in Australia, both in existing
operations and in future development as the time of the introduction of the
scheme approaches.[52]
4.72
Dr Fisher, addressing term of reference 5.2, the failure to include the
impact of the GFC on the rate at which other countries will commence
participation in a global ETS, stated:
In many countries, including Australia, the global financial
crisis has reinforced the primacy of economic growth and jobs in national
policy debates. While the full economic implications of the crisis remain
unclear, there is a strong probability that policy-makers in many jurisdictions
will regard global emissions trading based on an internationally binding carbon
constraint as a distinctly weak priority until strong economic growth has been
restored.
Given (a) their respective shares of global emissions, (b)
their assumed early participation in global emissions trading in the Treasury
CPRS scenarios (2010 for the US and 2015 for China), and (c) the close
strategic link between their likely actions, particular significance surrounds
the implications of the current economic crisis for the United States and China
in the short to medium term.[53]
Timing of implementation
4.73
In relation to term of reference 11, the economic impact of Australia
introducing a poorly designed scheme in 2010, rather than a better designed
scheme in 2011 or 2012, taking into account the decisions of major emitters,
stated that 'Treasury's modelling of the costs of delay is inadequate'[54]
and that 'the key economic and policy issues relating to delay and timing
appear not to have been considered. This is a major oversight.'[55]
Dr Fisher also stated:
That major decisions on scheme design and medium-term
emissions targets have been taken without any clear knowledge of the post-2012
international climate change architecture suggests the need for further
consideration of policy and governance arrangements to ensure the ETS works as
intended. In December 2008, EU members agreed to a review of the current EU
climate package in March 2010 to reflect the outcome of the Copenhagen
conference. A similar review process to take stock of Australia’s policy
settings should be implemented to ensure the domestic scheme maintains
community confidence and credibility.
More generally, it remains a major gap in the national
climate change policy approach that Australia’s premier, independent structural
reform advisory body has not been asked to report formally on the nation’s
‘most difficult ever regulatory challenge’. The Productivity Commission should
be given a brief to assess formally the Government’s White Paper proposals
against the Government’s own Best Practice Regulation Guidlelines.
This would doubtless shed light on improvements to ensure
that the ETS is both durable and flexible, able to meets its core objective of
supporting least-cost emissions abatement and soundly based in a way that is likely
to maintain community support for climate change action over many decades. It
would, for example, expose the full costs to businesses and households of the
interaction of the ETS and the expanded RET.
The reality is that there is nothing sacrosanct about 2010.
If the scheme is rushed or implemented alongside measures that simply add to
the costs of mitigation there is a genuine risk that public support for
long-term action on climate change will be eroded.[56]
Emissions pricing and permit
trading assumptions
4.74
In relation to emission pricing and permit trading assumptions Dr Fisher
stated:
More generally, Treasury assumptions virtually guarantee that
the permit prices from the modelling are unrealistically low. In addition to
the assumption of coordinated global action, the results appear reliant on
international climate negotiations delivering ‘optimal’ institutional and
permit trading arrangements.
...
The current architecture for the global carbon market remains
a long way short of that envisaged for an effective and efficient international
emissions trading regime with developing countries participating actively in
the global abatement effort. Major hurdles need to be overcome if Australia is
to secure the cost reductions from expanded access to international mitigation
through market-based mechanisms such as international emissions trading and the
Clean Development Mechanism (CDM).[57]
4.75
Dr Fisher, addressing term of reference 4.7, the consequences of more
realistic assumptions concerning low or non-existent barriers to international
trade in carbon permits, stated:
In the efficient global emissions trading scheme assumed by
Treasury, there are no barriers to permit trading. In the world as it is likely
to unfold the Australian government will be faced with decisions about whether
permits or credits generated in particular countries are verifiable and
represent a genuine emissions reduction and whether to allow the import of such
permits. This may have important implications for both the domestic permit
price and the international credibility of the Australian scheme. There appears
to have been no analysis of this issue.[58]
Availability of carbon capture and
storage technology
4.76
Addressing term of reference 4.6, the consequences of more realistic
assumptions concerning commercial scale availability and use of carbon capture
and storage technology, particularly in the light of assumptions regarding the
path of the carbon permit price, Dr Fisher stated:
Analysis by Concept Economics of those electricity technology
assumptions suggests that in the critical cases of conventional coal and
CCS-related technologies capital costs for new plants appear to have been
underestimated by up to 50 per cent. In turn, Treasury appears to have
underestimated the price at which CCS technology will be viable...
The Treasury report also appears somewhat inconsistent on the
implications for Australia if CCS technologies fail to materialise at the sorts
of emission prices postulated by the modelling. It implies, for example, that
the commercial viability of CCS is a key determinant of Australia’s emissions
falling significantly from around 2035. It also states that the ‘global
adoption of carbon capture and storage technology will affect significantly the
long-term viability of Australia’s coal industry’, the nation’s largest export
industry by a considerable margin (Treasury 2008a, p. 144). It nonetheless
concludes that whether or not CCS technologies become a commercial alternative
for electricity generation ‘is not crucial for the aggregate mitigation cost
results’ for Australia (Treasury 2008a, p. 144).
This depends on one’s definition of crucial’. Elsewhere in
the report when examining the global role of carbon capture and storage it is
stated that: ‘Australian mitigation costs are more than the global average.
Without carbon capture and storage, Australian mitigation costs rise by 23 per
cent in 2050’ (p. 127). A figure of 23 per cent may or may not be considered
‘crucial’, but it is surely significant.[59]
Renewable Energy Target
4.77
Responding to term of reference eight, the economic cost of the government's
expanded Renewable Energy Target (RET) compared to the costs of alternative
policy approaches, Dr Fisher stated:
The RET policy places an unnecessary burden on Australian
consumers of stationary energy. With an effective ETS in place, it merely
imposes additional costs but without any additional abatement. Electricity
prices would be higher than otherwise. It also distorts economic
decision-making by favouring certain low emission technologies over others,
directing investment toward higher cost abatement options and reducing
incentives to abate emissions or innovate in ways that do not meet the eligible
technology criteria. This is directly contrary to the intended purpose of an
ETS based on least-cost, market-driven abatement.
Contrary to the view that a policy such as the RET generates
jobs, the overall effect on the economy is less job creation than would
otherwise have occurred and a loss of economy-wide output compared with a
well-designed ETS alone.[60]
4.78
Dr Fisher stated that his analysis of the additional costs of the RET
was broadly consistent with the Treasury analysis. Modelling undertaken by Dr
Fisher:
...found that the interaction of the ETS and the 20 per cent
renewable target:
-
costs
Australia $1.8 billion more in 2020 than a pure ETS policy in terms of GNP
losses;
-
costs
Australia $1.5 billion more in 2020 than the ETS in output (GDP) losses;
-
results
in the loss of an additional 3,600 full time equivalent jobs in 2020;
-
causes
substantial switching away from gas fired generation compared with an ETS in
the order of 12,620GWh per year by 2020;
-
results
in electricity prices rising at least 6 per cent more than would be the case
under an ETS alone - the price of electricity rises 24 per cent under the
combined policy approach, and by 18 per cent under an ETS that delivers
equivalent emissions abatement.
These results confirm that an ETS alone is preferable to an
ETS and a renewables target that results in higher costs and no additional
mitigation. If a case could be made for supplementary policies based on
persistent market failures in the presence of an ETS, any low emissions policy
should be inclusive of all technologies, including clean coal technologies such
as CCS.[61]
Issues not considered by the Treasury
modelling
Adaptation opportunities
4.79
Dr Fisher, addressing term of reference 13, the adaptation opportunities
that could be foregone as a result of implementing a poorly designed ETS, and
the economic costs of not implementing these opportunities, stated:
Treasury’s modelling completely ignores adaptation and in
doing so ignores the adaptation opportunities that will be foregone as a result
of lower GDP. Treasury’s modelling therefore ignores a key component of the
opportunity costs of reducing emissions and ignores a vital aspect of the
policy response to climate change.
National policies geared to adaptation to climate change are
just as important as those geared to mitigation. And unlike mitigation,
adaptation can effectively be pursued unilaterally (Productivity Commission
2008).[62]
4.80
Dr Fisher also stated that responding to the adaptation challenges:
...will demand a major national investment over many decades.
To the extent that a poorly designed ETS has the potential to weaken
Australia’s economy, it has a capacity to delay and diminish necessary
adaptation responses. Finally, it is the case that climate change will occur
everywhere, with many projections suggesting that impacts will be large on the
Indian subcontinent, Africa and elsewhere. Australia is therefore likely to be
called on to increase support to other countries for climate change adaptation.
Again, this can only occur based on a strong domestic economy.[63]
Fixed-price permits versus a price
cap on permits
4.81
In response to term of reference 15, the desirability of fixed-price
permits, versus a price cap on permits, Dr Fisher stated:
Treasury’s modelling does not analyse or shed any light on
the economic effects of a price cap of $40 as opposed to a fixed price or
floating price. This is a major oversight.[64]
Financial viability of coal fired
electricity generators
4.82
Addressing term of reference 16, the impact of the government's proposed
ETS on the financial viability (as opposed to economic viability) of coal-fired
electricity generators, both in the short run and long run, Dr Fisher stated that
in the Treasury modelling:
...the financial viability of coal-fired power stations is not
considered. This means that the issue of whether the White Paper’s proposed
assistance is sufficient to maintain the financial viability of these assets –
and whether this is consistent with Treasury’s assumptions regarding their
continued operation - is not examined.
This is yet another element of the government’s preferred
policy approach that does not appear to have been modelled by Treasury.[65]
Cost of compliance
4.83
Dr Fisher, responding to term of reference 17, the cost of compliance
measurement, both in Australia and internationally, stated:
An emissions permit constitutes a legal right to emit; it is
a property right. Enforcing and monitoring these rights requires accurate
measurement, which in turn can be difficult and costly. A small percentage of
measurement error on a large volume of permits can have significant economic
implications for the individuals trading or surrendering those permits. Treasury’s
modelling does not analyse the economic implications of these issues.
The Treasury modelling also ignores the compliance costs of
the scheme. The design of penalties for non-compliance influences the incentive
to comply. The nature of the scheme’s regulatory and enforcement regime will
determine the probability of detection and punishment. This, together with the
design of punishments – the size of fines and imprisonment terms - will
determine the expected punishment, which is the effective ‘price’ of
non-compliance.
...
Treasury's modelling appears to have ignored these important
institutional and regulatory features.'[66]
White Paper policy
4.84
Addressing term of reference 18, the economic and environmental
implications of the White Paper, Dr Fisher stated:
The Treasury document considers four policy scenarios.
However, the policy proposed in the White Paper is that in the absence of a
comprehensive global agreement Australia will undertake unilateral action to
attempt to achieve a 5 per cent reduction in emissions on 2000 levels by 2020.
Treasury modelling does not include this unilateral scenario.
As already mentioned the Treasury CPRS -5 (5 per cent reduction) scenario is
based on the assumed multi-staged introduction of equivalent climate change
policies in overseas countries.
Moreover, Treasury’s modelling assumes ‘shielding’ for EITE
industries according to the proposed scheme outlined in the Green Paper. But
the White Paper proposes a different, more complicated shielding scheme.
Treasury’s modelling, published prior to the release of the White Paper, does
not analyse this revised shielding scheme.
Finally, as noted earlier, the White Paper proposes a permit
price cap in the first five years of the scheme. Treasury’s modelling,
published prior to the release of the White Paper, does not analyse the
economic effects and implications of this policy.
In summary, the Treasury modelling does not actually model
the government’s preferred policy approach. A complete analysis and assessment
of the economic costs and benefits of the government’s preferred policy
approach has yet to be published by Treasury.[67]
Recommendations
4.85
Following analysis of the modelling undertaken by the Department of the Treasury,
Dr Fisher made the following recommendations:
-
that given indications of the worst global economic crisis in
more than half a century, Treasury provide stakeholders with updated GDP
forecasts from the IMF, OECD and Consensus Economics so that these can be
compared with those used in the climate change modelling;
-
that full model documentation and databases together with any
additional scenario implementation code be released so that stakeholders can
better understand the full implications of the Treasury modelling;
-
that ETS governance arrangements incorporate a review process to
confirm that the Treasury modelling results were reasonably accurate. This
process should specify the way that any unintended consequences in ETS
performance can be quickly corrected;
-
that further analysis be done on the short- and medium-term
impact of an ETS on the electricity generation sector and other emissions
intensive industries that may be subject to significant structural adjustment
particularly as it affects regional Australia and that such modelling be done
using tools that take into account the lumpy nature of investment and the
likely timing of the retirement of large capital assets;
-
that additional sensitivity analysis be conducted around at least
one policy scenario involving slow, fragmented and partial global action in the
medium to long term;
-
that additional sensitivity analysis also be conducted around
less optimal international permit trading assumptions and the availability of
Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) certificates;
-
that a formal review follow the UN Conference of the Parties in
Copenhagen in late 2009 to take stock of the likely configuration of global
climate action in the next decade and Australia’s actions in that context (this
would mirror the review mechanism agreed by European Union leaders at their
summit in December 2008);
-
that Australia undertake a significant, pre-emptive diplomatic
effort in Europe and the United States in order to counter the possible
imposition of border barriers in the likely event that global action on climate
change is slow, partial and fragmented;
-
that the Productivity Commission formally review the Government’s
proposed ETS against its Best Practice Regulation Guidelines.[68]
Concerns about the Department of the Treasury modelling
4.86
The committee received evidence from a number of witnesses regarding
concerns about the modelling undertaken by the Department of the Treasury. The
main areas of concern were:
-
assumptions regarding global action;
-
failure to include the impact of the GFC;
-
overstating the assistance to be provided to EITEs;
-
failure to model more scenarios;
-
optimistic assumptions regarding the impact of the CPRS on the
asset value of coal fired power stations; and
-
lack of modelling regarding the impact of the CPRS on regional
areas.
4.87
Other issues raised about the modelling include the underestimation of
price increases, failure to balance the costs on the economy of reducing
emissions with the benefits of avoiding climate change, the assumption of full
employment, failure to take account of the specific circumstances of the
Western Australian electricity market and failure to recognise the costs of the
people adjusting to the changed economy.[69]
4.88
The conclusion reached by a large number of witnesses that commented on
the modelling was that the limitations of the modelling resulted in the
modelling having underestimated the impact of the CPRS on the economy,
particularly during the transitional period.
Assumptions regarding global action
4.89
The most commonly raised concern regarding the modelling undertaken by
the Department of the Treasury was concerning the assumptions regarding global
action. Organisations which raised this concern include the Chamber of Commerce
and Industry of Western Australia, the Cement Industry Federation, the
Construction, Forestry, Mining and Energy Union, the Minerals Council of
Australia, ExxonMobil Australia, the Australian Chamber of Commerce and
Industry and BlueScope Steel.
4.90
Specifically, Mr Mitchell Hooke from the Minerals Council of Australia,
stated:
...the real issue that we had with Treasury modelling was the
assumption that the impact on Australia’s international competitiveness would
be negated by the prospect of a global protocol, and I think the words were
‘other countries taking comparable action to Australia’s emissions trading
scheme by 2010 for developed economies, by 2015 for China and by 2020 for
India’.
That is, quite mildly, an heroic assumption...
That is the area of modelling that has caused us great
disquiet.[70]
4.91
Mr Gregory Evans from the Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry
stated:
Our principal area of concern in relation to the modelling
was that it assumed that other countries would pretty much join the scheme
initially, or soon thereafter, and in fact developing countries would also do
that in a staged approach. It would have been helpful, I think, in terms of
assessing the impact of the scheme, to perhaps model, or at least have some
scenario or sensitivity analysis on various levels of uptake internationally
and what that effect might be on Australia, because obviously the more slowly
it takes other countries to join, the higher the potential cost would be on the
Australian economy. So we did make the general point that there should have
been a go-alone or a staged modelling as other countries may have gradually
joined the emissions trading scheme.[71]
4.92
When challenged about the assumptions contained in the modelling
regarding the actions of other countries Ms Quinn from the Department of the Treasury
stated the modelling included:
...the more realistic scenarios relative to the Garnaut review
with the multistaged process of China taking action from 2015, India taking
action from 2020 and other low income developing countries not taking any
action until 2025, that multi-staged stepping out was judged to be more
realistic in the context of the international negotiations.[72]
Failure to include the impact of
the global financial crisis
4.93
Another commonly raised issue regarding the modelling was that of the
failure to consider the impact of the GFC. Ms Quinn from the Department of the Treasury
explained the failure to include the impact of the GFC as follows:
The economic analysis modelling was undertaken over 18
months. The report was released on 30 October. There is an issue of timing in
terms of getting modelling results and getting a report ready for a particular
point in time. There was no explicit decision to exclude the implications of
the global financial crisis. It was judged in the context of the knowledge at
the time that it would not materially affect the analysis in the report.
There is an explanation in the executive summary to that
point. What is important for greenhouse gas emissions over the long run is the
long-run trends in the Australian economy and the world economy, and cyclical
ups and downs around that long-run trend are important in the context of the
macroeconomic stability and macroeconomic cycle. However, in the context of
looking at trajectories and targets over 20, 30, 40 and 50 years, we do not
feel that it is material to the analysis in the report.[73]
4.94
Ms Quinn provided further explanation that short term economic changes
are not likely to significantly affect long term outcomes:
What typically happens is that economic growth goes below
trends in response to a shock. There is a reaction at both the policy level and
within companies, and the response is to go above trend. To the extent that
that historical behaviour continues into the future, any cyclical deviation
around the trend will affect in the near term possibly, one, two, three, four, five
years. Looking at the 2020 targets and the 2050 targets and at the action to
reduce greenhouse gas emissions, it is not clear, and certainly the judgement
was that it is not material to the analysis in the report.[74]
4.95
Mr Gordon Keen from ExxonMobil Australia also expressed his view of the
need to consider the long term:
Our industry, and our company in particular, looks very much
at a longer term view. Whilst it is unfortunate that there is a downturn now,
and no doubt it will have impacts in the near future and we hope they are not
protracted, the way we work in our company is very much long term. We average
prices out and we try not to be influenced in decision making by shorter term
factors. Despite the size of those factors now, which may actually be quite
large, nonetheless we do look to the longer term. That is because of the size
and scale of the investments that we make.[75]
4.96
Mr Andrew Canion from the Chamber of Commerce and Industry of Western
Australia stated why it would be useful for the GFC to be factored in to the
Treasury modelling:
The global financial crisis is important, and it would be
helpful to see that factored into the modelling. We understand that Treasury is
saying that it is a longer term model that they have used, so short-term fluctuations
may not influence it. However, we believe it would probably change the base.
The starting point essentially becomes lower. We think it would be worthwhile
and beneficial to the Australian public to see the results of that modelling
undertaken.[76]
4.97
Mr Tony Westmore from the Australian Council of Social Service agreed
that 'the Treasury modelling ought to be revisited in light of the global
financial crisis.'[77]
Similarly, Professor McKibbin agreed that it would be useful for Treasury to
model the impact of the GFC.[78]
4.98
Mr David Pearce from the Centre for International Economics also stated
that further modelling should be undertaken to take account of the GFC:
I certainly think it is worth modelling. You would model this
as alternative baselines or alternative reference cases. It is certainly worth
modelling reference cases where you have declines in output of our major
partner countries and Australia. Actually, it is hard to predict in advance
what the results of that might be on the cost implications of the CPRS. That is
exactly why it is worth modelling.[79]
Overstating the assistance to be
provided to emissions intensive trade exposed industries
4.99
Representatives from BlueScope Steel argued that:
Although the headline rate of assistance for integrated iron
and steel makers in the white paper is 90 per cent free permits, the effective
rate of assistance is considerably lower. In fact, it could be as low as 64 per
cent as our total scope 1, 2 and 3 emissions are taken into account. This is because
significant parts of our business will be excluded from assistance under the
white paper proposals. At $25 a tonne of CO2 equivalent, the cost of the CPRS
for scope 1 and 2 emissions in the first year alone is tens of millions of
dollars, after taking into account the government’s proposed assistance. Adding
scope 3 costs would see this increase even further.[80]
4.100 BlueScope Steel officers further explained:
...the 90 per cent headline number does not apply to the whole
iron and steel industry. The federal government modelling that was done assumed
that it did, but it actually only applies to the really intensive steelmaking
operation, where you are dealing with red-hot liquids and red-hot materials.
All of the downstream processes, which is a very substantial operation—where
steel is rolled and shaped and galvanised and painted and formed and turned
into marketable products—will receive no assistance. So when you take into
account those emissions, plus the emissions from the really intensive part,
that dilutes the amount of compensation.[81]
4.101 BlueScope Steel argued that the inaccurate assumptions in the Treasury
modelling such as the one explained above indicate that the results of the
modelling underestimate what would actually occur under the CPRS.[82]
4.102 The committee put a summary of the above point made by BlueScope Steel
to Dr Fisher and asked for his view. Dr Fisher agreed that the assumption of 90
per cent free permit allocation as used in the modelling was an overly generous
assumption.[83]
Failure to model more scenarios
4.103 Mr Pearce from the Centre for International Economics argued that it
would be advantageous to model more scenarios. He stated:
...models are a very powerful tool in understanding the
trade-offs that face us. Given that this is something totally new—this is not a
policy we have contemplated before—models are one of the few tools we have for
peering into the alternatives that face us. But models are not particularly
good at forecasting. I would not claim that economic models can forecast the future
very well. What they are good at and what models like MMRF-Green and the other models
that the Treasury has used in their analysis is in comparing alternatives are
good at is in using the same basic model configuration to run a simulation of
the CPRS as it stands and compare that with a simulation of, for example, a
CPRS in which the auctioned revenue is used to reduce other taxes or to run a
simulation of the CPRS as it stands in comparison with the output based
allocation approach that Danny Price just talked about, or to compare the CPRS
as it stands with a number of other alternatives. That exercise of comparing
viable alternatives using a quantitative framework I believe will give a much
better understanding than we currently have of the trade-offs that have been
made in this policy at the moment.[84]
He added:
[Treasury] have not modelled very many scenarios—they have
modelled one scenario of global contributions to emissions. I think it is very
important to model different scenarios.[85]
Optimistic assumptions regarding the impact of the CPRS on the asset value
of coal fired power stations
4.104 Electricity generators raised concerns about the modelling associated
with the impact on the asset value of existing assets. Mr John Boshier from the
National Generators Forum stated:
Treasury modelling conducted for the white paper is
optimistic in its assumptions about the potential impact of the CPRS on
existing assets in the coal fired electricity generation sector...The
Commonwealth government commissioned three different models from MMA, ACIL and
ROAM to examine the wealth impacts of a CPRS on the coal fired electricity
generation sector. It should be noted that economic modelling of the
electricity generation sector is highly sensitive to fuel costs, demand growth
and the volume of international abatement credits. MMA results were the lowest
in terms of the negative wealth impacts on the coal fired electricity
generation sector, followed by ROAM, with ACIL reporting the highest negative
wealth impacts.
But it appears that only one of these models, MMA, was used
as part of Treasury’s broader modelling of the CPRS impact. It seems that
little if any sensitivity analysis was conducted, emphasising the need for
caution when designing a public policy response to such significant issue...The
NGF has engaged Intelligent Energy Systems or IES to conduct a further
assessment of the white paper modelling results. The IES market based modelling
was strongly consistent with results from the ROAM and ACIL models and suggests
that the MMA modelling is based on highly optimistic assumptions. IES estimated
a negative wealth impact of $12 billion. This is well in excess of the $3.5
billion proposed in the CPRS white paper.[86]
4.105 A similar view was expressed by Griffin Energy:
The Treasury modelling forecast for asset value losses,
whether intentional or not, is conservative compared to other credible industry
modelling. Understating the potential losses that might be expected by rational
investors only serves to undermine the credibility of the Electricity Sector
Adjustment Scheme in mitigating the perception of regulatory risk.[87]
Lack of modelling regarding the
impact of the CPRS on regional areas
4.106 The majority of witnesses from regional areas that commented on the
Treasury modelling expressed that modelling should be undertaken to determine
the impact of the CPRS on regional areas. For example Mr Arthur Rorris, Secretary
of the South Coast Labour Council, supported the release of as much information
as possible regarding the impact of the scheme on jobs and members.[88]
4.107 Mr Christopher Fitzhardinge from the South West Group, which is a
voluntary regional organisation of six councils in the south west metropolitan
region of Perth, stated:
There are a number of statements which have been made in the
documentation which are not followed through. Firstly, it is indicated in many
of the Treasury and Department of Climate Change publications that regions will
be significantly impacted by policy changes on energy, but there is no
region-by-region analysis of the impacts, nor is there any assessment of
support to individual regions to be able to offset any impacts that may arise
from the federal government’s change in energy policy.
...
...you need to look at a region-by-region approach and not
aggregate up the impacts. Australia is made up of separate regions that make
significant contributions to the Australian economy and treating the Australian
economy as a homogenous block does not fairly reflect impacts on Western
Australia.[89]
He continued that the Treasury modelling:
...needs to have greater detail on its regional impacts because
in some cases it may be regions that need to be compensated rather than
individual industries. The impacts, which may appear small on a national scale,
may be significant locally.[90]
4.108 The Mackay Regional Economic Development Corporation, Mackay Area Industry
Network, the Gladstone Chamber of Commerce and Industry and the Gladstone Area
Promotion and Development Limited also expressed the need to conduct modelling
aimed at determining the impact of the CPRS on regional areas and then use this
to inform the local people of the likely impacts.
4.109 For example, Mr Glenn Churchill, Chief Executive Officer of Gladstone
Area Promotion and Development Limited stated:
...we would be certainly pleased and encouraged if the Senate
inquiry was to determine that there could be some economic modelling from it. I
think that is what everybody is looking at...I think people just want to know how
this will affect them financially.[91]
4.110 The committee heard evidence from Mr Daniel Price noting that Frontier
Economics has conducted modelling which shows the greatest impact of the
proposed scheme will be on regional areas across Australia. Mr Price stated:
I heard some comments about the regional state effects not
being robust, which I thought was curious. The model that they used is
something called MMRF-Green, which is the same model that we used. We operated
the model using the same people that the Treasury used. In fact, Brian
Parmenter, who works for Frontier Economics, is one of the builders of that model,
so he knows how to use it. That model in fact builds up a picture of the
economy from a state level, so it is impossible to say that state levels are
unreliable, because it aggregates those results. The use of these models to dig
down into regional economies is pretty common practice. Governments all over
Australia use this model to look at regional effects. So it is not true that these
results are not robust. That is not to say that any macroeconomic model is
perfect; they are far from it; they are a very gross simplification of how an
economy works.[92]
4.111 When asked about the lack of published Treasury modelling at a regional
level, Ms Quinn stated:
There are some issues about using simplistic reporting
measures of regions. The MMRS [sic] model that was used by Frontier Economics
and has been developed by the centre of policy studies at Monash University
does not have a comprehensive analysis at a regional level. It does not allow
for abatement opportunities at a regional level. It does not allow for adjustments
between capital and labour at a regional level. It does not actually do any
modelling at a regional level. It simply reports on the basis of simplistic,
historical relationship results for regions. So Treasury did not consider that
analysis to be robust enough to actually use in a modelling exercise.[93]
4.112 Ms Quinn also stated that 'Unfortunately, there are no tools available
for us to easily model regional implications.'[94]
Further, Ms Quinn stated:
And I would restate my previous comment that the Australian
Treasury did not consider the regional reporting in the MMRF model to be of a
robust nature and, therefore, we did not judge that it would be in the public
interest for that information to be provided, that the underlying economic
modelling is not done at a regional basis in the MMRF model. It is simply a
reporting metric based on very simple assumptions and they are a very, very
broad brush. They do not take account of all of the things that we know are
important for thinking about the economic costs of mitigation.[95]
Committee comment
4.113 The committee is of the view that the modelling undertaken by the
Department of the Treasury, as published, is flawed and inadequate and the
government should direct the Treasury to undertake further modelling as
recommended below.
Recommendation 7
4.114 The committee recommends that the Senate not consider any legislation to
give effect to the government's proposed CPRS until the government has fully
complied with the relevant order of the Senate of 11 March 2009 and has
released all of the information currently being kept secret.
Recommendation 8
4.115 The committee recommends that the government direct the Department of the
Treasury to undertake and publish modelling of the impact of the proposed CPRS:
-
assuming little or no action by Australia's major competitors to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions;
-
taking account of the economic conditions due to the global financial
crisis;
-
on industry at a sectoral level, including the effective rates of
compensation to industry;
-
on regional areas of Australia; and
-
in comparison with modelling of a variety of viable alternative policy
scenarios aimed at Australia contributing to the reduction of greenhouse gas
emissions.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page