Chapter 8 - Investment
Provisions of AUSFTA relating to investment
8.1
Chapter 11 of the AUSFTA sets out the obligations of
the parties in relation to investment.
8.2
In Australian public discourse, the term 'investment'
is often used in a somewhat narrow sense, to describe investment in financial
products or real property. In the
AUSFTA, however, 'investment' is given its technically accurate meaning, and
therefore includes almost any activity which involves the commitment of
resources in return for reward, with the acceptance of risk. The DFAT Guide to the Agreement offers a
series of examples of investments, including the following:
-
an enterprise, that is, virtually any form of
business for profit;
-
financial instruments including equity, debt,
and derivatives;
-
contracts for construction, management, or
revenue sharing;
-
and, most broadly, "other tangible or
intangible, movable or immovable property and related property rights, such as
leases, mortgages, liens and pledges."[595]
8.3
It can be seen from these provisions that the
investment provisions capture an extremely broad range of economic
activities. They are consequently
extremely important in the context of the agreement as a whole.
Requirements under AUSFTA
8.4
Under the AUSFTA, the Parties agree to provide
investors from the other Party either national treatment (that is, the same
treatment afforded to domestic investors) or most-favoured-nation treatment,
whichever is most advantageous to the investor.
It also contains a number of provisions designed to reduce sovereign and
other policy-related risks associated with investors from each Party investing
in the economy of the other Party.
8.5
Specifically, the Parties agree to:
-
provide national treatment or most-favoured
nation treatment to investors from the other Party (Articles 11.3 and 11.4)
-
provide the protection of law to investors and
investments, in a manner consistent with international law (Article 11.5);
-
provide investors and investments with
protection or restitution in the event that a civil or military emergency
requires the requisitioning or destruction of the investment in question
(Article 11.6);
-
refrain from nationalising or expropriating
investments from the other party, except in accordance with law, and with
appropriate compensation (Article 11.7);
-
allow the free transfer of funds connected to
covered investments from one Party to another (Article 11.8);
-
not to establish discretionary performance
requirements in relation to import or export content, local content, preference
for local inputs, transfer of intellectual property, or restrictions on sales
(Article 11.9);
-
refrain from requiring that senior managers or
board members be of a particular nationality (Article 11.10); and
-
reserve the capacity to implement policies which
may be otherwise prohibited under the agreement, but which are necessary for
environmental reasons (Article 11.11).
Reservations
8.6
Not all investment falls under the AUSFTA. Annex I and Annex II of the Agreement contain
reservations allowing Parties to maintain existing non-conforming measures. Both Australia
and the United States
have included measures relative to investment in Annexes I and II. Any matter not mentioned in Annex I or Annex
II is subject to the AUSFTA by default.
Such investments are referred to in the Agreement as 'covered
investments'.
8.7
Australia's
reservations include:
-
the preservation of current non-conforming
measures undertaken by State and Territory governments (Annex I- Australia 1);
-
retention of assessment by the Foreign
Investment Review Board, though with substantially increased financial value
thresholds (discussed below) (Annex I- Australia 2-5);
-
investment in urban land (Annex II- Australia
3);
-
additional support for indigenous involvement in
enterprises (Annex II- Australia 1);
-
measures relating to leases on airports (Annex
II- Australia 13);
-
preservation of export requirements in the
government IT outsourcing program (Annex I- Australia 8);
-
any measure with respect to primary education
(Annex II- Australia 10);
-
authorisation and levying of foreign fishing
vessels (Annex I- Australia 10);
-
wheat exports (Annex I- Australia 11);
-
foreign ownership and foreign director limits
for Telstra (Annex I- Australia 13);
-
foreign ownership and control of media companies
(Annex I- Australia 15-16);
-
votes of foreign shareholders for Board
positions on the Commonwealth Serum Laboratories board (Annex I- Australia
17); and
-
foreign interests in Qantas (Annex I- Australia
19-20).
8.8
The United States'
reservations include:
-
regulation of atomic energy for industrial purposes
(Annex I- United States 1);
-
regulation of leases relating to mining and
energy (Annex I- United States 4);
-
preferential treatment for minority groups
(Annex II- United States 4);
-
access to Overseas Private Investment
Corporation insurance and loan guarantees (Annex I- United States 5);
-
regulation of commercial aviation (Annex I-
United States 6-7);
-
securities exchange registration and initial
public offers (Annex I- United States 9);
-
ownership of broadcasting licenses (Annex I-
United States 10);
-
ownership of cable television facilities (Annex
II- United States 2); and
-
the preservation of current non-conforming
measures undertaken by States, the District of Columbia, and Puerto Rico (Annex
I- United States 12).
8.9
Submissions and evidence raised a number of issues of
concern in relation to Chapter 11 of the AUSFTA. These were foreshadowed briefly in the
Committee's interim report[596] and
will be discussed in greater detail below.
Overall impact on investment
8.10
The central concern is clearly to determine the impact
the AUSFTA will have on investment in Australia. On the one hand, the Agreement may encourage
additional investment in Australia
by United States
investors. On the other hand, it may
encourage Australians to invest in the United
States where previously they may have
invested at home. Inevitably, of course,
both of these situations will occur, and a great deal of energy has been spent
during public debates on the AUSFTA in recent months trying to anticipate what
the net effect on investment is likely to be.
8.11
The Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade cited
investment as one of the most significant benefits of the AUSFTA:
It is in the area of
investment that the gains from the Agreement will perhaps be most significant
over time. Already the United States supplies nearly thirty per cent of Australia’s foreign investment, more than any other
economy. Australia ranks 12th among destinations for US direct
investment abroad. The United States is the biggest destination- 43 per cent-
for Australia’s foreign direct investment (FDI), and Australia is the 10th largest foreign owner of US
assets.
The Agreement will
enhance Australia’s attractiveness as a destination for US investment as it puts in place legal
guarantees and other measures that provide greater certainty for investors. The
negotiation of the Agreement has already made Australia a greater focus of US investor and media attention, and this will
continue during the US domestic approval process and beyond.[597]
8.12
The official analysis of the AUSFTA by the United
States International Trade Commission does not attach the same significance to
the investment aspects of the Agreement, offering a more subdued assessment:
The FTA will add transparency to the investment regimes of the united
States and Australia,
but is not expected to generate significant amounts of new investment between
the two countries, as the investment environment in each is already
substantially open.[598]
8.13
These more subdued claims are also reflected in the
government's own Regulation Impact Statement:
Similarly, Australia's
commitments under the Agreement with regard to screening of foreign investment
is unlikely to have a major impact on US
investment in Australia?
[599]
8.14
Attempts to quantify, or to quantitatively verify these
alleged gains have given rise to significant debate and various alternative
analyses. The Department of Foreign
Affairs and Trade commissioned the Centre for International Economics to assess
the economic impact of the AUSFTA, which it did using the G-Cubed and Global Trade
Analysis Project (GTAP) models. With
respect to investment, the CIE made the following observation:
Lowering transaction costs, strengthening the security of the
investment framework and highlighting the openness of Australia's foreign
investment regime in non-sensitive sectors have the potential to reduce a
proportion of the risk-related cost of capital in Australia (which reflects
investor uncertainty and transaction costs).
It is therefore likely that, whatever the impact on actual investment
flows, the overall impact of the investment provisions in AUSFTA will be
positive.
A difficult question is
how positive is the result likely to be and how will the gains be distributed,
particularly in more illiquid segments of the market?[600]
8.15
The CIE endeavours to quantify this benefit by
indicating the likely fall in equity risk premiums on the implementation of the
FTA. The term "equity risk
premium" is a useful measure of the cost of capital. A reduction in the restrictions and risks
associated with investing in a particular economy leads to a reduction in the
risk premium, and therefore to less expensive access to capital for investee
enterprises. The CIE, in a process
outlined on p. 34 of its report, arrives at a conclusion that under the AUSFTA
the risk equity premium would fall by 5 basis points (or .05 percentage
points). It should be noted, though,
that their analysis delivered an outcome of 10 basis points, which the CIE then
halved in order to deliver a conservative result. It should also be noted that this figure does
not appear to emerge from either G-Cubed or GTAP, but rather from a 'pragmatic'[601] series of calculations outlined in
the report.
8.16
In a newspaper article in May 2004, Professor John
Quiggin made the following observation critical of the CIE finding:
- the CIE is right to focus on the equity premium. The difficulty is in the assumption that
capital market liberalisation will reduce the equity premium and will have no
offsetting adverse effects. The proposed
changes are tiny by comparison with the floating of the dollar, the associated
removal of exchange controls over the 1970s and 1980s and the associated
domestic liberalisation. Yet there is no
convincing evidence that these changes had any effect on the risk premium for
equity.[602]
8.17
In an assessment of the CIE findings for this
Committee, Dr Philippa Dee argued against the CIE's link between the AUSFTA
changes to Foreign Investment Review Board (FIRB) assessment of investments
(discussed further below) and the equity risk premium in Australia:
The equity risk premium is a concept that captures the effects
of events that happen ex post, after an investment is made, that reduce or
eliminate the expected returns on that investment. A negative ruling does not put at risk the
entire amount that would have been invested.
The potential investor still has their uninvested capital that they can
put elsewhere-
There is no doubt that events that affect a country's equity
risk premium can have a powerful effect on investment inflows, and hence on output
and consumption levels in a country- A key factor likely to account for
Australia's apparent equity risk premium is that we have a commodity-driven
currency, so that the repatriated value of an investment in Australian
manufacturing can be greatly affected 'after the event' by the price Australia
gets for its wheat or coal.[603]
8.18
If Professor Quiggin and Dr. Dee are correct, and the
AUSFTA does not result in a significant reduction of equity risk premiums in
Australia, this in turn is likely to result in a dramatic reduction in the
forecast economic benefits from the AUSFTA.
DFAT, however, rejects Dr. Dee's assessment of the impact of the changes
to FIRB review thresholds:
The CIE found substantial gains to Australia from the
liberalisation of FIRB restrictions under AUSFTA. These findings are rejected by Dr. Dee on the
ground that FIRB liberalisation will not reduce the risk premium on investment
in Australia. But there is evidence that
complying with its provisions is seen by investors as onerous. In addition, other provisions of AUSFTA will
improve the investment climate and create added certainty for investors. The CIE's modelling assumes a very small
reduction in the risk premium of only 5 basis points, and in sensitivity
analysis, this is reduced to 2 basis points.[604]
8.19
In evidence the Department of the Treasury was
reluctant to endorse the CIE's expectation of a 5 basis point reduction, but
noted that in its view the precise number was less important than the policy
message it signalled:
Investment in particular is a very difficult activity to model,
so the modellers have come up with something that is logically consistent and
fits with what we call mainstream theory, but we also need to keep in mind that
this is giving us an indication.[605]
Dynamic productivity gains and
economy-wide benefits
8.20
As the Committee noted in its interim report, the
impact of Chapter 11 of the AUSFTA on the overall economic outcomes for
Australia will depend substantially on the impact of dynamic productivity gains
(or losses) arising from the AUSFTA. The
CIE Report outlines the concept in the following terms:
It is widely accepted that trade liberalisation allows countries
to move resources to more valuable sectors of the economy and consequently
brings about allocative efficiency gains.
However, trade reform does more than simply shift resources. When trade barriers are reduced on an
industry, competition increases.
Increased competition can change the behaviour of firms in that
industry, encouraging businesses to use better technology and business
practices either through innovation or quicker adoption of new ideas. Improvements to efficiency due to improved
work practices (as opposed to resource re-allocation) are referred to as 'dynamic
productivity gains'.[606]
8.21
Following World Bank research, the CIE identifies four
sources of dynamic gains, two of which are relevant to investment. The CIE describes those two as follows:
-
Dynamic
investment- As tariffs are often imposed on investment goods, a reduction
in trade barriers on these goods can lead to an increase in the return to
capital and therefore a rise in real investment and productivity. Higher incomes from increased productivity
lead to higher savings anf thus further capital accumulation.
-
Endogenous
capital flows- There is significant empirical evidence that gains from
international capital mobility are quantitatively important. Foreign direct investment from abroad may
bring new and improved technologies that could flow into the domestic economy
and increase market productivity.[607]
8.22
Because of the multitude of factors which can influence
the dynamic productivity changes associated with a policy measure, and because
consideration of dynamic productivity changes is a relatively new science, such
gains are extremely difficult to quantify with any accuracy. The CIE has dealt with this difficulty by
developing, based on a series of empirical studies, assumptions about the
likely dynamic productivity gains in several economic sectors.[608]
These productivity gains have then been used as inputs into the
calculation of the macroeconomic impacts of the AUSFTA on Australia. As can be seen below, the importance of
dynamic productivity gains in terms of overall gains in real GDP is
significant:
Figure 1- Changes in Real GDP[609]
8.23
The potential benefits arising from dynamic
productivity gains have underpinned much of DFAT's process of selling the
AUSFTA. The following extract from their
submission gives an indication of both the tone, and the significant extent to
which the outcomes of the AUSFTA rely on the forecast (direct and dynamic)
benefits from investment liberalisation:
According to the CIE's modelling, Australia's
annual GDP could be up by around $6 billion (about 0.7 per cent of GDP) as a
result of the AUSFTA a decade after the Agreement's entry into force. Total GDP
increase over 20 years is expected to amount to almost $60 billion in today's
dollars.
Much of this growth will be generated by the dynamic gains
expected from the deeper links the Agreement establishes between Australia and
the US, with the CIE finding investment liberalisation the biggest contributor
to the projected increase in Australia's GDP. But even if these benefits and
other 'dynamic' effects of trade liberalisation are excluded, liberalisation of
trade in goods and services alone would contribute about $1 billion to real
GDP.[610]
8.24
The CIE's assessment of dynamic productivity gains under
the AUSFTA has been criticised. In her
report for the Committee, Dr. Philippa Dee did not reject the consideration of
dynamic impacts altogether, but argued that a more conservative approach would
have discussed dynamic impacts without including them in the modelling:
The DFAT/CIE study draws on empirical work that shows that, in
addition to having so-called static effects on allocative efficiency, tariff
cuts can also have a so-called dynamic effect on sectoral productivity. The study quantifies these dynamics effects
by assuming them to be proportional to the size of their tariff cuts.
The studies that the DFAT/CIE study draws on examine
productivity levels in Australian manufacturing during a period of substantial
unilateral tariff cuts. AUSFTA does not
cut tariffs unilaterally, but preferentially- this means that the reductions
in price on any given import can be substantially less than the size of the
preferential tariff cut.-
The existence of such 'cold shower' effects of tariff cuts on
productivity has been hotly debated.
Conservative evaluations might note their possible existence, but do not
include them in the quantitative analysis.[611]
8.25
Dr Peter Brain of the National Institute of Economic
and Industry Research made a similar point:
In terms of a general
methodological issue or how the economic assessment should be made, the idea of
bottom line point estimates is absurd. I think we can all agree that whatever
the dynamic of flow-on effects will be, they will be large-whether it be a
multiplier of two, four, six or whatever-compared with the direct effects.
Therefore, the analysis should simply focus on the direct effects. This should
be done with some humility because there is a wide range of possible outcomes.
To accommodate this as best we can, one should try to take into account all
possible outcomes in a framework of decision making which allows an assessment
of the probable range of outcomes, which we have tried to do.[612]
8.26
Other evidence suggested that, even accepting the
inclusion of dynamic effects in the CIE model, the outcomes forecast are far
too optimistic. Professor Ross Garnaut,
for instance, stated:
The third element of gain is so-called dynamic effects which, if
you read the logic of the report, depend on the trade liberalisation being
genuinely liberalising. But if the trade liberalisation is not liberalising, if
it moves in another direction, then there is no reason to think the dynamic
gains will be positive. In fact it is very likely that if the trade
liberalisation effects are negative the dynamic defects will be negative as
well. So just on a straightforward application of the logic of the models-not
the words, and above all not the words of the executive summary, but the logic
of the models-suggests that the median estimate of gains would be approximately
zero. It would be possibly slightly negative but approximately zero, way below
the bottom end of the range of outcomes that CIE and DFAT suggested and put the
95 per cent probability bounds around.[613]
8.27
In other appearances before Senate Committees, officers
of the Treasury have been reticent about relying on dynamic effects as a basis
for policy decisions, instead adopting an approach more in line with that
suggested above by Dr. Brain and Dr. Dee.
During an appearance before the Senate Economics Legislation Committee's
inquiry into the International Tax Agreements Amendment Bill 2003, Mr Greg
Smith, Executive Director, Revenue Group, Department of the Treasury, made the
following statement in relation to a double taxation treaty:
The Treasury, perhaps
conservatively, but along with longstanding practice and what is also a common
practice in many countries-I will not say every country, but in most
countries-take the first-round effect and publish that. We draw attention to
the other effects-second-round effects, assumption driven effects or other
things which we are less certain about-but we have not incorporated them in the
official costing- We do a similar thing
really, when you think of it, with most of these sorts of things. For example,
we may well publish a costing for the research and development tax concession,
but of course the purpose of the research and development tax concession is to
create dynamic benefits in the Australian economy. We do not publish, and we do
not seek to estimate, in our costing what those benefits are.[614]
8.28
Treasury made similar statements directly in relation
to the FTA at an Estimates Committee hearing in October 2003:
The long term,
significant benefits from this agreement will come from the dynamic interrelationship
with the intangibles: competition policy; certainty; work programs on financial
services, which will be done through a financial services committee that is
being established between the two countries; and work programs on recognising
professional qualifications, which is one of the big impediments to service
trade at the moment. All of those things are very powerful but they are
impossible to quantify, so what you are left with when quantifying the model
are things that are easy to measure but perhaps not the most important part of
the agreement.[615]
8.29
DFAT, however, rejects criticism of the CIE's
assessments of dynamic productivity gains.
In a rebuttal of Dr. Dee's comments on this issue, DFAT stated:
Dr Dee rejects the idea
of including 'dynamic gains' which flow from the greater competition under
trade liberalisation because 'their existence has been hotly debated, and
conservative evaluations omit them.' But
there is a wealth of econometric evidence which supports the existence of these
effects. The CIE has been conservative in
its assumptions and has adjusted the magnitude of the gains to reflect the fact
that it is a bilateral agreement which has been negotiated.[616]
8.30
The Committee
is interested in DFAT's claim of 'econometric' evidence. If such evidence exists and is sufficiently
reliable to support this claim, why did the CIE rely instead on assumptions
based on empirical evidence?
8.31
It is clear to the Committee that the CIE's estimates
of the dynamic benefits of the AUSFTA should, at the very least, be treated
with a great deal of caution and scepticism.
Instead, the Committee should follow the approach recommended by Dr Dee
and Dr Brain, and indeed by Treasury in previous inquiries. The Committee recognises that dynamic effects
may result, and may have substantial benefits.
However, as Professor Garnaut points out, they may not. Policy decisions in relation to the FTA
should therefore be made principally on the basis of the direct effects, with
the recognition that dynamic effects may eventuate.
Changes to Foreign Investment
Review Board Thresholds
8.32
The Foreign Investment Review Board (FIRB) is a
statutory body whose principal function is "to examine proposals by foreign interests for acquisitions and new investment
projects in Australia and, against the background of the Government’s foreign
investment policy, to make recommendations to the Treasurer on those
proposals."[617]
8.33
Currently, FIRB reviews all proposals for
foreign investors obtaining substantial interests in Australian companies valued
in excess of $50 million, and all proposals by foreign interests to establish
new businesses in Australia valued at $10 million or more.[618]
If FIRB considers that such a proposal is not in Australia's national
interests, it may recommend that the Treasurer block the proposal.
8.34
As such, FIRB is clearly a non-conforming
measure under AUSFTA. For it to continue
in operation, appropriate provisions must be included in Annex I or Annex II of
the AUSFTA. Annex I includes provisions
which enable FIRB to continue to operate, but it lifts the thresholds. Under the AUSFTA, FIRB will only review the
acquisition of a substantial interest in companies valued in excess of $800
million.
8.35
The
Department of the Treasury has indicated that the new FIRB thresholds did not
emerge as a result of any perceived problems with FIRB from an Australian
perspective. Rather, the new thresholds
represented a compromise between the United States' wish to eliminate screening
and Australia's wish to retain it:
Ultimately, of course,
this was a negotiation, so there was a give and take, if you like. The US were, and remain, very strongly opposed to
screening in any form, and they see our arrangements as a potential restriction
on investment flows. From our point of view, we felt comfortable raising-and
the government’s judgment was that it was comfortable raising-it that far
because it achieved the balance between, if you like, the level at which
national interest concerns are likely to be real and tangible and, below that
level, the level at which they are not likely to be sufficient to warrant the
compliance costs associated with the screening.[619]
8.36
The
Government has also argued that the raised threshold is essentially a benign
change for two reasons. First, while the
reduced number of cases referred to FIRB would be substantial, "in terms of
value of investment-that is, not the number of transactions but the value of investment-under
the proposed arrangements with the US we will continue to screen over 70 per
cent of investment by value."[620]
8.37
Second,
Treasury pointed out that that FIRB has not been a barrier to US investment in
the past. Mr Chris Legg, from Treasury,
stated that "I do not think there have been many, if any, cases where US
investors have been rejected. There may have been one or two."[621]
8.38
A
number of submissions remained concerned about both of these issues. On the issue of the reduction in referrals to
FIRB, the Australian Council of Trade Unions noted:
The Office of US Trade
Representative estimates that 90% of US investment in Australia over the last
10 years would have escaped screening had the new rules applied
retrospectively. Using a three-year
retrospective time horizon, DFAT estimates in its Regulatory Impact Statement a
reduction in screened proposals by 65-70%.
Some commentators have claimed that, under the proposed AUSFTA rules,
around 86% of companies listed on the Australian Stock Exchange could be
acquired by US interests without being
screened.[622]
8.39
The
Australian Manufacturing Workers Union argued:
While the AMWU acknowledges
that the national interest test has rarely been invoked to prevent foreign
investment in Australia, the AMWU notes that the changes would mean that almost
99% of Australian manufacturing companies could be acquired under the proposed
AUSFTA with no regard for whether such an acquisition is in the best interests
of Australia or Australian workers. [623]
8.40
The
Federation of Australian Scientific and Technological Societies made a similar
point:
The second area of major concern in terms of allowing for the cherry
picking is the change in the threshold for FIRB, lifting its report threshold
from $50 million $800 million means that all R&D-intensive science and
technology SMEs would fall under that $800 million threshold and there will be
no examination. As you are aware, because of the ratchet mechanism, if a future
government decided it was concerned about an emerging trend of US
firms purchasing Australian R&D companies and taking them offshore, it
would not have the capacity to use FIRB as the instrument to address that
policy problem.[624]
8.41
In
relation to the argument that FIRB has not rejected incoming investments from
the United States, the ACTU made the point that:
We acknowledge that the
vast majority of applications that are screened by the Foreign Investment
Review Board are approved. However, the
Board also has a track record of approving applications subject to conditions
set to safeguard the national interest.
This aspect of the screening process should be borne in mind when it is
argued that the current process is simply a time-consuming one that leads to
approval anyway.[625]
8.42
It is
useful to also note the United States perspective on this issue, which confirms
that the increase in FIRB thresholds is likely to increase US investment in
Australia, but that the size of this increase will be muted by the relatively
open current arrangements:
US industry representatives
would also have preferred to discontinue the investment screening performed by Australia's FIRB.
However, the minimum size of most foreign investments that require
screening has been substantially raised. In general, U.S. investors in Australia must notify the Australian Government
(through the FIRB) of investments only if an investment is value at more than
A$800 million (US $443.2 million). The
previous investment threshold was A$50 million (US $27.7 million). Industry
representatives have stated that the higher limits are an improvement in the
investment approval process- Industry representatives indicate that due to
Australia's fairly liberal existing investment regime, they have been free to
invest in most industries despite FIRB screening, and that is not expected to
change.[626]
8.43
The
Committee notes that there is substantial evidence that the increased FIRB
thresholds will have little impact on US investors because the FIRB review
process is not currently a substantial barrier to US investment. However, despite this widespread evidence
that the impact is likely to be mild, the changes in FIRB arrangements are
considered by the CIE as a major factor underpinning the decrease in
Australia's equity risk premium (discussed above) and therefore as a major
factor underpinning the predicted benefits of the AUSFTA as a whole.
8.44
The CIE
report argues that "Australia
has relatively high [foreign direct investment] restrictions compared with
other countries in the OECD, surpassed only by Iceland, Canada, Turkey and
Mexico. These restrictions range from limits on foreign ownership in
certain sectors to modest screening procedures for a wide range of investment
proposals."[627]
8.45
Under
the AUSFTA Australia continues to maintain specific limits on foreign
investment in a range of sensitive areas such as newspapers, broadcasting,
Telstra, Qantas, airports, and urban land.
That is, Australia's 'relatively high foreign direct
investment restrictions' on sensitive sectors will not be reduced under the
AUSFTA. This leaves only the reductions
in the 'modest screening procedures' as the source of increased liberalisation
of foreign direct investment- and the impediment raised by this screening
process has been shown to be minimal. The AUSFTA will therefore do little to
reduce those core factors which result in Australia having 'relatively high foreign direct
investment restrictions'
8.46
It is
difficult to reconcile such a view with the view expressed above by the United
States International Trade Commission that Australia's investment environment is 'already
substantially open'.
8.47
Despite
all of this, and without any further explanation, the CIE argues that "we are still left with the fact that
Australia’s FDI rules are at the ‘restrictive end’ of the OECD scale"[628] and uses this as a justification for
assuming these restrictions are responsible for fully half of Australia's
current equity risk premium. This
provides the basis for a further series of calculations resulting in the claims
of a 5 basis point reduction in the equity risk premium under the AUSFTA.
8.48
The
Committee observes that the assumption that investment rules account for half
of Australia's equity risk premium is at best unproven, and may be
substantially exaggerated. Even if the
assumption is accurate, the AUSFTA appears (on the above analysis) unlikely to
reduce investment restrictions substantially.
In either case, there would be flow-on consequences which may reduce the
predicted benefits from the AUSFTA by billions of dollars.
8.49
Professor
Ross Garnaut criticised the CIE analysis of the impact of the changes to FIRB
in these terms, arguing that they failed what he described as the "laugh
test":
The Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade has now released the
results of the consulting firm’s assessment of the agreement as negotiated.
While the main sources of gain in the original estimate resulting from access
to highly protected US agricultural markets have disappeared or shrunk
dramatically, somehow the total benefits have greatly increased to $5.6
billion. That somehow turns out to be mainly through what are described as back
of the envelope calculations of gains, hitherto overlooked from easing FIRB
restrictions. There is an air of unreality about this revised estimate. The
magnitude of the contribution now attributed to changes in FIRB rules and the
basis used to assess it heighten the need for an independent analysis conducted
at arm’s length from those whose job it is to sell the agreement to the
Australian community.[629]
8.50
In her
report for the Committee, Dr. Philippa Dee also took issue with the CIE
findings. She argued as follows:
- it is highly doubtful
that ex ante FIRB screening has any general effect at all on Australia's risk
premium- FIRM screening has an unknowable, but probably small, deterrent
effect on a few particular investments, but nothing like the number of
investments that would be affected by a generalised change in the risk premium.
8.51
The
Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade continues to support the CIE's views:
In summary, the CIE found substantial gains to Australia from
the liberalisation of FIRB restrictions under AUSFTA. These findings are rejected by Dr Dee on the
grounds that FIRB liberalisation will not reduce the risk premium on investment
in Australia. But there is evidence from
investors that complying with its provisions imposes some costs. This reflects the fact that the existence of
a screening mechanism may reasonably be expected to have some impact on the
level of uncertainty for prospective investors and to contribute to their
general perception of risk, notwithstanding genuine efforts to implement the
policy in a way that minimises such effects.
In addition, other provisions of AUSFTA will improve the investment
climate and create added certainty for investors. The impact on the equity risk premium is
inherently difficult to quantify: however the sensitivity analysis does
indicate that the gains are significant even with a much smaller reduction than
assumed in the base case.[630]
Select Committee's view
8.52
The Select Committee, informed the weight of evidence
presented during the inquiry, is sceptical of the forecasts made by the CIE and
promulgated by DFAT during public debate on the Free Trade Agreement. The loudly proclaimed benefits to Australia
arising from a liberalised foreign investment regime and from dynamic
productivity gains are based on a series of inferences and educated guesses. The
fact that the US International Trade Commission states that the AUSFTA is 'not
expected to generate significant new investment' cannot be easily dismissed.
8.53
However accurate
the CIE and DFAT predictions may turn out to be, educated guesses do not
provide an adequate basis for informed policymaking by parliamentarians,
investors or citizens. The CIE report's
highly-contested views on investment and dynamic gains have inevitably led to a
debate played out in academia, in the media, and before this Committee. The result is that the modelling work which
was intended by the government to clarify the impact of the AUSFTA and justify
its adoption has in fact led to increased confusion.
8.54
Notwithstanding this, the Committee recognises that the
AUSFTA, by liberalising investment between Australia
and the United States,
is likely to provide a net benefit to Australia
in the investment arena. The Committee
is far from convinced that the benefit will be as great as that claimed by the
Government and the CIE, but it remains likely that a benefit will eventuate. Consequently the Committee does not oppose
Chapter 11 of the agreement, but its concurrence occurs despite, rather than
because of, the analysis undertaken by the CIE
and endorsed by DFAT.