DISSENTING REPORT

Higher Education Legislation Amendment Bill 1996
CONTENTS


DISSENTING REPORT

BY SENATORS CARR, CROWLEY AND STOTT DESPOJA

on the Higher Education Legislation Amendment Bill 1996

The Higher Education Legislation Amendment Bill 1996 has the potential to radically change the provision of higher education in Australia. The proposed changes have serious implications for equity, access and quality in Australian universities.

The bill was introduced into the Senate with the purported claim that it would expand access, widen equity and improve diversity and quality in higher education. The evidence presented to this Committee conclusively discredits these claims and reveals the bill as an attack on higher education.

The government's higher education policy and so called 'commitment to quality, diversity and innovative change' [1] is an abandonment of the principle of fairness that has been the hallmark of higher education in Australia.

The basic tenet underlying this system is that access is based on merit. This bill attacks this principle. Through a host of measures, it enhances opportunities for the rich and decreases them for the disadvantaged.

According to the Second Reading Speech for the Bill, it will 'introduce additional opportunities and choice for Australian students' and 'enable Australian students to have a greater chance of obtaining the higher education course of their first preference'. Poor students are not going to be in a position to take advantage of many of these purported additional opportunities. The measures introduced by the Billup front full fees for domestic undergraduates, the dramatic increases to the base level of HECS, the lowering of the repayment thresholds and the imposition of differential charges all these are likely to have the effect of raising the bar to entry for less well-off students

What is particularly disturbing about this Bill is that it introduces far-reaching changes before the Higher Education Review has been established, let alone had a chance to consult, to formulate its findings and provide considered advice to the Minister. In short, the Bill is preemptive in the extreme. Moreover, it presents those conducting the Review with a financial fait accompli which itself may require untangling before a coherent regime can be established. This conveys the impression that the Government has little interest in undertaking a serious examination of higher education, in thoroughly assessing its needs and carefully defining a vision of Australia's higher education future. The sense of urgency attached to the measures in this Bill suggests that it is driven by budget concerns, by the Government's deficit rEducation plan and not a well-defined philosophy of higher education.

In the context of Senate examination of estimates, the Department reported to the Committee cuts to the Higher Education System (Programme 2.1) for 1996-1999 of $1.956 billion. [2] The overall cuts to higher education for this period amount to $1.821 billion. [3] There is a receipt offset of $1.130 billion essentially generated by the modified HECS arrangements. As the Department stated with respect to Programme 2 Budget Estimates:

Again, this reveals that the real intention behind the changes to HECS is to raise revenue to fund the government's deficit rEducation plan. In other words, this Bill is not so much a statement on education policy but rather a vehicle for the government's budget cutting.

The changes provided for in this bill cannot be viewed outside the context of the Government's overall higher education policy, in particular, its decision to reduce operating grants to universities by one percent in 1997, three per cent in 1998 and a further one per cent in 1999. Translated into rEducations in target numbers, these cuts will result in a rEducation of 17,055 Commonwealth funded student places over the next three years. [5] The changes to the level of operating grants, at least for 1997 and 1998, do not require legislative amendment as the new levels of the grants are lower than the amounts already provided for in the Higher Education Funding Amendment Act (No.2) 1995. [6] They are, nevertheless, germane to any discussion of the implications of the Higher Education Legislation Amendment Bill 1996.

 

Major Concerns Arising From The Bill

The introduction of up front fees to Australian undergraduates

The amendment that has the greatest potential in the long term to change the provision of higher education in Australia is that relating to section 13(1) of the Act. As it currently stands, Section 13(1) of the Act provides for the charging of fees for postgraduate courses. If this bill is passed, the section will read

With the insertion of a mere two words, 'undergraduate or', the government will fundamentally alter the character of a higher education system that has been widely accepted in the community for its perceived fairness. Access to universities has been largely based on merit not on a student's capacity to pay.

Many witnesses expressed grave concerns about this amendment. One witness described it as the 'most fundamental, inequitable and grave of the entire package of policy measures announced in the 1996-97 Federal budget'. [7] Another declared it to be the 'most significant potential for change in this debate'. [8]

The concerns generated by this amendment centre on two issues, namely the impact on equity and the potential of the amendment to allow an unregulated and unlimited expansion of fee paying places.

 

Equity considerations

The principle equity concern relating to the proposal to introduce up front fees is, as expressed by the NTEU, a simple one. 'Only some people can afford to pay up front fees'. [9] It is, they argue, 'contrary to the egalitarian ethos of Australian society that something as fundamental as education might be available only to those who can afford to pay it'. Other witnesses, including the AEU, supported this view. 'To sweep away the fundamental equity for access to higher education and allow places to be again bought by those who can afford to pay is socially unjust'. [10]

Although the government presents the proposal as a measure that effectively increases access to universities and provides greater choice, it overlooks the fact that this is only the case for those who are in a sufficiently comfortable financial situation to take up the offer. Such opportunities have nothing to do with equity. What is equitable about a situation in which a rich student can buy a place in a university despite having a lower TER score than another who cannot afford to buy a place? What is equitable about a situation in which a rich student can turn down their second or third preference and opt instead for their first preference in the course or the university of their choice when a poorer student must accept what is offered? If there is a correlation between socio-economic status and TER Score, as many believe, it could be argued that students from higher socio economic backgrounds are already more likely to get higher TER scores and be offered government funded places in courses of their choice. Why double the advantage to such students by giving them, in essence, a fall back position of being able to buy the places they may not achieve through merit? What is equitable about a system 'where those who can pay fees have greater options and choice than those who do not?' [11]

The introduction of extra places for those who are rich enough to afford full fees contradicts the justification for HECS. Professor Chapman, a leading academic expert in the economics of education, addressed this point in some detail.

As the Australian Dental Association noted, this will have an unfortunate flow-on effect for the social profile of future practitioners.

In discussing the diversification of funding of public institutions, the World Bank report refers to the need to 'provide support to qualified students unable to pursue their studies for reasons of inadequate family income' and assistance measures to enable 'poor students to make the same choices as those with more financial resources'. [14] It argues that

The Labor Senators note Australia's success in introducing cost sharing in public higher education through HECS and identifies the existence of this comprehensive student loan system as enabling a significant expansion in enrolments without a dramatic increase in public subsidies. The essential feature here is the income contingent nature of the deferred loan scheme. This has allowed students, who might not have the financial resources to pay up front fees, to participate in higher education and pay back their HECS loan when they are financially able to do so. As the majority report notes, participation by Aboriginal students in higher education, for instance, has increased throughout the 1990s.

The basic flaw in the government's proposal to introduce full fee paying places is that it fails to provide in any way for 'students who do not have the financial capacity to pay'. [16]

The proposal to depart from the wholly income contingent repayment principle that underpins HECS is, according to Professor Chapman, a radical move.

The introduction of a scheme which favours the financially advantaged is untenable. The equity implications demand that the proposal to introduce up-front fees for undergraduates be rejected.

 

Merit equity scholarships

It is important to put into perspective the government's claim that it is 'further encouraging the participation of equity groups in higher education by introducing up to 4,000 merit equity scholarships between 1997 and 2000'. [18] This equates to 1000 merit equity scholarships per year to be distributed between 36 universities.

One university described the number of scholarships offered as 'derisory'. [19] The reason for this is abundantly clear when the number of merit equity scholarships is compared with the expected number of student enrolments over the next four years. Of the 600,000 students expected to be enrolled in universities by the year 2000, 4000 or 0.006% will have HECS exemption scholarships. [20] The government's claim, in the light of these statistics, is risible. Of the Merit Equity Scholarships proposal, Professor Chapman stated:

It is also interesting to put the proposal into some historical perspective. According to the National Union of Students, the 1996 HECS is 'roughly equivalent in real terms with the tuition fees charged to university students prior to the abolition of fees in 1974'. [22] In 1973, 41.4 per cent of full time students had their fees paid by Commonwealth scholarships. (An additional 38.8 per cent had their fees paid by State teachers' studentships). [23] Viewed in the light of such figures the current government's merit equity scholarships initiative reveals itself to be tokenism of the worst sort.

 

The de-regulation of fees for undergraduates

The amendments to Section 13(1) of the Act de-regulate fee paying arrangements for undergraduates. Importantly, the parameters within which fees operate are not specified in the legislation but are governed by Ministerial guidelines. According to the NTEU this

The amendments have the potential to seriously undermine Australia's commitment to an accessible, equitable higher education sector, and have aroused strong concerns from many quarters. The fears range from the amendments heralding a 'progressive substitution of full fee-paying students for HECS paying students in the more sought after courses' [25] to a situation sometime 'in the future for all students to be charged tuition fees'. [26] While the current government may protest that this is not its intention, there is certainly nothing in the proposed legislation to stop the current or any future Minister from implementing drastic changes.

The government's stated intention is to limit the number of fee-paying places available to Australian students to twenty five per cent of domestic undergraduates in any course. By refraining from enshrining this limit in legislation, the government is very clearly reserving the option to change the proportions at any time in the future. The point warrants repetition - if this amendment is passed there will be no legislative impediment to prevent the Minister from so acting.

The Minister's explanation to the Committee for not specifying the 25 per cent ceiling in the bill was that 'the proposal was put and accepted that this is a clean way to do this. It is neat'. [27] The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee are not satisfied that such a reason justifies its exclusion. Legal tidiness should not take precedence over sound policy making.

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee suggest that it would require a leap of faith to believe the government will maintain the twenty five per cent ceiling in the long term. The following extract from an interview with Senator Hill in February 1996 is an indication of the credibility of the government's stated intention.

The experience of post graduate students since the de-regulation of fees demonstrates how swiftly the absence of specific prohibitions in the legislation enables a shift in the balance between government funded and full fee paying places. Fees for postgraduate coursework were introduced in 1989 and in 1994 all regulations were removed in the postgraduate coursework area. Although this was followed by a substantial increase in the number of fee-paying courses, according to the Council of Australian Postgraduate Associations, 'a substantial core of HECS-liable places postgraduate courses remained.' [29] However, in the absence of any legislative prohibitions, a change in policy such as the cuts in operating grants (which are to be primarily translated into cuts in government funded postgraduate places), can overnight alter the postgraduate landscape. CAPA sketched the immediate impact of these changes to the Committee.

In the absence of any legislative prerequisites and restrictions, it is possible to imagine a change of government heart about the twenty five per cent ceiling drastically altering the provision of publicly funded higher education for Australian undergraduates.

 

Access to education

In presenting the case for the introduction of full fee places the government has made a number of assertions. One of these concerns access to education. In evidence before the Committee, the Minister asserted:

According to the Minister, children of parents who 'may not have the money to be able to fully fund a place for one of their children in universities' will also have increased opportunities.

The Minister later corrected the amount by which the undergraduate places are to increase and identified that in 1997 there would be an additional 6000 undergraduate places above 1996 levels. This means that for 1997 the budget cuts will result in no loss in undergraduate places against forward estimates. Nor, it should be noted, will there be any increase. By 1998 there will be an additional 10,000 government funded places above 1996 levels. Here we start seeing rEducations in undergraduate places against forward estimates. Although in 1998 there will be an increase of 10,000 government funded undergraduate places, this represents a rEducation of approximately 2000 government funded undergraduate places against forward estimates. [33]

The second opportunity of increased access for less well-off people to higher education, according to the Minister, will come from rich students buying full-fee places and leaving vacant HECS-liable places for other students, including those from less well-off backgrounds, to fill. [34] The extent to which less-advantage students will benefit from this is open to question. It would be realistic to expect vacant HECS places being filled by a cross-section of socio-economic groups, including students from well-off backgrounds and equity groups. Given that the socio-economic profile of university students has, as the majority report notes, barely changed over the last two decades, equity groups are unlikely to be the major beneficiaries of any shift in well-off students to full fee places.

The other problem with the claim that lower socio-economic groups will take up HECS places left by the rich is that it ignores the impact on equity of the new differential HECS and related measures. As we detail later in the minority report, the Opposition and Democrat Senators have grave concerns over the ramifications for equity groups of the government's new HECS regime. These changes effectively introduce new hurdles to access for equity groups (the three HECS bands, the 68 per cent overall increase in HECS charges and the lowering of the income threshold for debt repayment below the average weekly wage).

It is worth noting also that this Bill deals with higher education provision as a whole. As described earlier in this discussion, the operating cuts will lead to a rEducation in approximately 17,000 places against forward estimates in 1998. This is the equivalent of 4 per cent cut in places overall. It is in the context of total figures that one should evaluate government claims that access will be expanded.

 

Over-enrolled students

The government has argued that additional HECS places are likely to eventuate because the government will pay direct to institutions the minimum upfront HECS payment for any HECS-liable students enrolled above the target load.

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee question the extent to which this is likely to happen. Universities which meet HECS target loads are more likely, in the first instance, to offer places to full fee paying students than they are to enrol further HECS-liable students. It could be argued that institutions which have filled courses' twenty five percent quota of fee paying places may be encouraged to offer additional government funded places to enable them to take in additional fee paying places. However, given that for every additional fee paying place it offered, the institution would have to take in three extra HECS-liable students, the financial incentive would not be great.

If the degree to which institutions have over enrolled students in the past is any measure, indications from DEETYA suggest there is little interest in this practice. The Department has advised that in the last three years there has been virtually no instance of over-enrolment. Nor was the issue referred to in any submissions received by the Committee from universities.

The government insists, however, that this is a real incentive:

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee argue that if the measure does lead universities to squeeze another 10 or 15 students into a course, there are issues that need to be considered. An additional 10 or 15 students may be able to be absorbed into a lecture theatre. An additional 10 or 15 students, however, also represents another tutorial group that has to be provided for, another set of essays and examinations to be marked and so forth. There are serious implications here for quality, particularly in terms of class sizes and teacher workload.

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee believe that every Australian award course should have legislative protection guaranteeing that domestic students are not charged up front fees.

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee recommend that the proposed amendment to section 13(1) of the Act, which allows for the charging of upfront full fees to domestic undergraduates, be rejected.

 

Changes to HECS

The amendments to the Bill include a number of changes to HECS. The three most significant include increases to the level of HECS, the lowering of the thresholds for repayments and the introduction of differential charges.

 

Lowering of the HECS Repayment threshold

In outlining the essential elements of the HECS, the Wran Committee recommended

The government's proposal to lower the threshold represents a considerable departure from this philosophy. The new lowest threshold has been lowered to the second income taxation threshold. The changes have been justified on the grounds that students start to pay when they reach average earnings, as at present, and at that point they are in fact earning above what most other taxpayers earn. [37] A further explanation was offered by the Department in answer to a question about the basis for the new threshold.

These arguments must be considered in the light of the consequences that flow from them, particularly their impact on low income earners. The following tables, comparing the current thresholds with the proposed thresholds, were provided to the Committee by NUS.

Current HEC fees repayments (1996-97) Current rate applied to total HEC repayment income
$28,494 - $30,048 3%
$30,049 - $32,380 3.5%
$32,381 - $37,562 4%
$37,563 - $45,334 4.5%
$45,335 - $47,717 5%
$47,718 - $51,291 5.5%
$51,292 and above 6%
Proposed HEC fees repayments (1996-97) Proposed rate to be applied to total HEC repayment income
$20,701 - $21,830 3%
$21,831 - $23,524 3.5%
$23,525 - $27,288 4%
$27,289 - $32,934 4.5%
$32,935 - $34,665 5%
$34,666 - $37,262 5.5%
$37,263 and above 6%

As NUS points out, the new threshold is only 74 per cent of Average Weekly Earnings and 94 per cent of average workers earn in excess of it. NTEU claims that, in effect, the new threshold 'will require students living well below the poverty line to actually start repaying their debt'. [39] Similarly the University of Queensland noted that the 'proposed threshold is below the recognised "poverty level" which is described as $24,000 in the guidelines relating to Workers Compensation'. The University of Queensland is so concerned that it 'has forwarded a protest to the Government about the lowering of the threshold for HECS repayment to taxable earnings of $20,701 and has asked the Government to reconsider this matter'. [40]

Figures from NUS substantiate the claims from NUS and UQ.

 

Poverty lines & the new HECS threshold (d)

  poverty line ($) (b) % of HECS threshold (c)
couple (a) 297.87 106.21%
couple + 1 358.06 88.35%
couple + 2 418.24 75.64%
couple + 3 478.43 66.12%
couple + 4 538.61 58.74%
  poverty line ($) (b) % of proposed HECS threshold (c)
Single person 222.67 142.07%
Single parent + 1 285.67 110.66%
Single parent + 2 346.01 91.43%
Single parent + 3 406.20 77.88%
Single parent + 4 466.38 67.83%

The following comments from NUS bring these figures to life.

Many witnesses expressed concern that the lower threshold would act as a deterrent to some potential students from participating in higher education. The University of Southern Queensland noted that applications for external study (70 per cent of its students study externally) were 30 per cent lower than at the same time last year. They considered the proposed amendment to the repayment threshold a 'major contributing factor'. The implications for the university are serious: 'USQ will find it difficult to meet its 1997 undergraduate intake targets in the circumstances, and the consequences to this institution of not meeting these targets are significant'. [42] The ANU thought that it would act as a significant deterrent to part-time students, low income earners and single parent families. [43] The NTEU also thought that it would particularly affect all of the designated equity groups.

It is to be hoped that graduates do have better employment prospects after they graduate. But the essence of HECS as originally conceived was to seek repayments from graduates when they had the capacity to pay. The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee consider that the lower thresholds will require many graduates to start repaying their debt well before this time.

It should also be noted that the lowering of the threshold affects all current HECS debtors. In introducing this Bill the government made the following assurances:

In giving evidence before the Committee, Professor Chapman challenged these claims. According to Chapman, 'the effective financial cost for all current debtors, so long as they pay back any part of it, is higher than it was'. The following example illustrates his point:

The Opposition and Democrat member of the Committee recommend that the repayment threshold for HECS remain at the level of average weekly earnings.

 

Increases to the Level of HECS Charges

The current HECS is based on principles of cost sharing and cost recovery. It was designed to reflect the public and private benefit from higher education. The Wran Committee recommended that students be required to contribute twenty per cent of the cost of their higher education. [47] Under the proposed changes, the 'weighted average proportion contributed by students, when the 25 percent discount, implicit interest rate subsidy and course enrolments are taken into account, is estimated to be 27 per cent'. [48]

This Bill proposes to increase the level of HECS contributions by an estimated 68 per cent. [49] The rationale for this is 'the government's assessment that the private contribution through HECS is about one-fifth of the cost of the course. Most data would indicate that the private rates of return are somewhat higher than that'. [50]

The ANU argued the increases make the proportion of the cost borne by the student high by world standards and expressed concern that this sends a message to the 'best brains of the next generation that it [the community] does not place a particularly high value on the public benefit to be gained from their further education'. [51] The ANU added that any short term gains may not be in the country's long term interest in terms of its investment in its future intellectual capital.

Many submissions and witnesses expressed concern that the increased charges would serve as a disincentive to students.

NUS made the observation that the increase in HECS is 'predicated on the belief that the current system of HECS has not discouraged significant numbers of students from studying and would therefore cause no harm to equitable participation'. NUS argued that this is 'an untested and illogical hypothesis which if taken to its logical conclusion suggests that the level of fee is immaterial, so long as payment can be deferred'. [52]

The Committee heard claims from the Minister, the Department and others including Professor Chapman that the introduction of HECS has not acted as a deterrent for students from lower socio-economic backgrounds. [53] While accepting this evidence, the Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee sense that the justification for the changes to HECS is framed by a perception that most students in universities are from non-government schools and wealthy backgrounds. In presenting evidence to the Committee about the relative advantage of students in private schools, the Minister selected three schools and identified the percentage of students in those schools that went on to higher education. The three schools chosen were Knox Grammar in Sydney (90%), Canberra Boys Grammar (80%) and Korowa Anglican School in Melbourne (85%). The Minister's stated intention in showing these figures to the Committee was to underline 'when we are talking about HECS contributions, what sort of students we are talking about'. [54]

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee suggest that many students do not fit this description. Rather than using evidence about the continuing low participation rates of students from lower socio-economic backgrounds as a justification for altering HECS, the government should focus on finding ways to improve participation rates of these students. A dramatic increase in HECS accompanied by the lowering of the threshold is likely to exacerbate rather than ameliorate disadvantage.

 

Differential HECS Contributions

According to the government, differential HECS contributions strike 'a better balance between the public and private funding of higher education' by linking students' contribution to the cost of their education more closely 'to both the actual cost of the course undertaken and the likely future benefits to the individual in terms of increased life-time earnings'. [55]

A proposal to have a differential HECS, based on the cost of courses, was considered and rejected by the Wran Committee. The current proposal is a more complicated model and introduces two more factors as determinants of the charge, namely the likely future earnings of graduates and demand for those disciplines. [56] It is, as explained by Professor Chapman, a hybrid system.

According to DEETYA, future earnings are calculated on the basis of ABS data on the median income of graduates in various years following completion of their studies. [57] The presumptions involved in this method of calculating future earnings make it, according to one witness, overly simplistic.

The Committee heard strong criticisms of the differential HECS model. Prominent among critics were representatives from science, engineering and technology interests. Their very valid concerns are described in the majority report which recommends that there is a strong case for assigning science units to a lower HECS band than currently proposed.

This recommendation is problematic in that it implies that the inappropriate classifications apply only, or more, to science than to other disciplines. The Committee heard other examples of units of study being placed in the higher HECS bands but which are part of courses that lead to very ordinary salaries. For example:

The differential HECS will introduce further anomalies that undermine the very philosophy on which the government has based the new model. Under the new system, there will be cases where school teachers on the same salary will be saddled with different levels of HECS debt because of the different disciplines in which they majored. For example, a maths-science teacher will have a significantly higher HECS debt than a humanities teacher. This is because maths and science are in a higher, more expensive HECS band than humanities subjects.

The Minister, in response to the Committee when this anomalous situation was put to her, stated:

This response highlights the anomalies the differential HECS will introduce. For a doctor, it is a case of repaying HECS for a high-cost course which generates a high private benefit. For a humanities teacher, it is a case of repaying HECS for a low-cost course which generates a relatively low private benefit. In these two cases, there is at least some degree of correspondence between course costs and private benefits. For a maths-science teacher, however it is a case of repaying HECS for a high-cost course which generates a relatively low private benefit. In other words, the HECS debt of a maths-science teacher reflects an inverse relationship between costs and private benefits. This is an example of some graduates being penalised for not only their choice of courses but also their choice of career.

This example also exposes how the new system works at cross-purposes to its own rationale. HECS is supposed to be about striking a balance between public benefits and private benefits, in addition to balancing public costs and private benefits. The considerable public benefits that flow from maths-science graduates working as teachers do not figure in the calculations behind allocating maths-science units to the higher HECS bands.

Furthermore, this example highlights the difficulty in using future average incomes as a factor in allocating subjects to HECS bands. This is because it is highly presumptive to tie a student's choice of course to his or her future career. The Department admitted that it has no data that links units studied by students to their ultimate profession. [61] This means that under the new HECS regime there are going to be some graduates, such as maths-science teachers or lawyers working with community-based organisations, for whom HECS will represent a very high cost relative to the private benefits that they can expect to receive.

In a private briefing to the Committee, the NSW/ACT Higher Education Network explained that many Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander graduates prefer to work in community enhancement areas. These are not highly paid positions. Although the community needs Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander workers with training in health, dentistry, medicine, law and legal studies, the Network is convinced that the combination of the differential HECS and the lowering of the thresholds would discourage many Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islanders from enrolling in university courses.

Other witnesses concurred with the view that a differential HECS will act as a deterrent. It will not only deter many students from undertaking whole courses such as law, medicine and engineering but will influence the selection of individual units. Academics from the University of Newcastle noted that the placement of economic history in a high HECS band would discourage many arts students from studying economic history. [62] The ANU suggested that many students in social and behavioural sciences will refrain from including legal and paralegal units; arts and humanities students will be less likely to include computer, science or mathematical subjects and, conversely, science students will include units from band one regardless of whether they are a sensible choice for their degree because they will be relatively cheap. The ANU claimed that 'it is difficult to see the rationale for the proposed allocation of discipline groups to the proposed HECS bands' and argued that the 'ad hoc combination of market and cost factors such as that proposed must inevitably distort student choices'. [63]

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee are convinced that the problems with a differential HECS go far beyond the inappropriate allocation of units to different bands. The system relies for its integrity on the reliability of the three factors that are combined to determine the different charges. The difficulty of accurately assessing the likely future benefits for graduates is a fundamental flaw in the system. A differential HECS will deter some students, especially those from equity groups, from participating in higher education. A differential HECS will also distort the course choices of some students, while penalising others for their choice of units. In the long term, it will impact on Australia's investment in its intellectual capital.

The Labor Senators believe that the current uniform HECS, on the other hand, is well accepted by the community. It has neither deterred students from participating in higher education, nor has it distorted their course and career choices. It should be maintained.

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee recommend that the Senate reject the provisions in the Bill relating to the introduction of the differential HECS, the increases in HECS fees and the lowering of income thresholds for repayment of HECS debt.

 

The Open Learning Agency

The bill provides for the de-regulation of fees charged by the Open Learning Agency. It also provides for a new definition of 'basic charge'. According to this definition, basic charge refers to the smaller of either the statutory amount or the fee actually set by the agency. Under the Act, clients will still be able to defer their payments under the Open Learning Deferred Payment Scheme. However, the 'effect of the amendment is to maintain the amount the Commonwealth may lend to clients under the OLDPS, although fees may be set by the Agency at a higher level'. [64]

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee consider it unacceptable that there should be a gap between the charges set by the OLA and the amount the government will lend to clients. Any gap will have an immediate impact on access and restrict participation to those with the means to pay the difference upfront. The commercial lines along which the agency operates already means that additional charges are levied for services such as 'tutorial assistance, counselling, academic support and, from 1997, library services'. [65]According to the NTEU, 'the idea of allowing this charge to be

increased in a deregulated manner is anathema from the point of view of access and equity, especially when the needs of rural and other isolated students (the disabled, the housebound, those with young families) are considered'. [66]

The fees announced by the OLA for 1997 are $425 per unit. This is approximately twenty five per cent above the statutory amount specified in the bill. The absence of any form of a limit on the level of fees in the legislation may well result in the gap significantly increasing in the long term. The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee reject the amendments relating to the Open Learning Agency.

 

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee recommend that the Senate reject the provisions in the Bill which provide for the de-regulation of fees for the Open Learning Agency. Students eligible for the Open Learning Deferred Payment Option should be able to defer the full amount of their fees.

 

Research funding

The Opposition and Democrat members of the Committee support the increases to research structure, collaborative research and the Australian postgraduate awards, but object to overall cuts in research . They note, however, the concern of NTEU that the increases in collaborative grants have been backloaded with most of the money being left until the final year of payment. In its post budget statement, the AVCC urged the government to distribute the $90M in three annual instalments of $30M. This measure would allay concerns in the sector that the final year of payment may be subject to further rEducations.

 

Footnotes

[1] Second Reading speech, House Hansard, p.5022.

[2] Senate Employment, Education and Training Legislation Committee, Additional Information Relating to Examination of Budget Expenditure for 1996-97: Volume 1 (October 1996), pp.22-23.

[3] This figure is based on the increase of $134 million for Programme 2.2 Target Research and Scientific Development and the rEducation of $1.956 for Programme 2.1 Higher Education System.

[4] Additional Information relating to Examination of Budget Expenditure for 1996-97: Volume 1 (October 1996), p.23.

[5] Mr Phillips, Senate Estimates, Senate Employment, Education and Training Legislation Committee, Monday 16 September, 1996, p.68.

[6] Higher Education Funding Act 1988 provides for amounts which shall not exceed the figures specified in section 17 of the act.

[7] NTEU, Submission No.5, p.23.

[8] Transcript of Evidence, p.130 (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[9] NTEU, Submission No.5, p.24.

[10] AEU, Submission No.24, p.47.

[11] NTEU, Submission No. 5, p.24.

[12] Bruce Chapman, 'Understanding the 1996/97 Budget Changes in the Funding of Australian Higher Education', October 1996, p.7.

[13] Australian Dental Association, Submission No.1, p.2.

[14] The World Bank, Higher Education: The Lessons of Experience, 1994, ps.6, 7.

[15] Ibid.

[16] Transcript of Evidence, p.131 (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[17] Transcript of Evidence, p.132 (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[18] Second Reading Speech, House Hansard, p.5022.

[19] University of Queensland, Submission No.12, pp.80-81.

[20] Based on figures used by Professor Chapman, Transcript of Evidence, pp.132-3, (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[21] Transcript of Evidence, pp.132-3, emphasis added (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[22] NUS, Submission No.6, p.13.

[23] Report of the Committee on Higher Education Funding, April 1988, p.3, sourced to Department of Education, Student Assistance for the Disadvantaged: Practice and Prospect, Student Assistance Policy Series, AGPS, 1986.

[24] NTEU, Submission No.5, p.24.

[25] Department of Training and Education, NSW, Submission No.19, p.27.

[26] NTEU, Submission No.5, p.25.

[27] Transcript of Evidence, p.261 (Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone).

[28] Senator Robert Hill, Interview on Radio Triple J, 28 February 1996.

[29] CAPA, Submission No.16, p.98.

[30] Ibid, p.98

[31] Transcript of Evidence, p.248 (Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone).

[32] Ibid, p.259.

[33] Advice from DEETYA, 19 November 1996.

[34] Transcript of Evidence, p.259 (Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone).

[35] Ibid, p.247.

[36] Report of the Committee on Higher Education Funding, April 1988, p.vi.

[37] Senate Estimates, Senate Employment, Education and Training Legislation Committee, Monday 16 September, 1996, Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone, pp.71-72.

[38] Transcript of Evidence, p.119 (Mr Burmester, DEETYA).

[39] Transcript of Evidence, p.103 (NTEU).

[40] The University of Queensland, Submission No.12, p.80.

[41] NUS, Submission No.6, p.52.

[42] University of Southern Queensland, Submission No.9, p.69.

[43] The Australian National University, Submission No.13, p.86.

[44] Transcript of Evidence, p.105 (Dr Allport, NTEU).

[45] Second Reading speech, House Hansard, p.5023.

[46] Transcript of Evidence, pp.135, (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[47] Report of the Committee on Higher Education Funding, April 1988, p.v.

[48] Advice from DEETYA, Question on Notice 4.3, 28 October, 1996.

[49] Advice from DEETYA, Question on Notice 6, 28 October, 1996.

[50] Mr Phillips, DEETYA, Senate Estimates, Senate Employment, Education and Training Legislation Committee, Monday 16 September, 1996, p.71.

[51] ANU, Submission No.13, p.85.

[52] NUS, Submission No.6, p.54.

[53] D. S. Anderson and A. E. Veroorn, Access to Privilege (NU Press, Canberra, 1983, p.146) provides data showing that the proportion of full-time students whose fathers were from trades/manual occupations, since the abolition of tertiary fees rose from 17% to 22% between 1974 and 1984.

[54] Transcript of Evidence, p.247 (Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone).

[55] Second Reading speech, House Hansard, p.5022.

[56] Mr Phillips, Senate Estimates, Senate Employment, Education and Training Legislation Committee, 16 September, p.70

[57] Ibid.

[58] Transcript of Evidence, pp.132, (Professor Bruce Chapman).

[59] Charles Sturt University, Submission No.10, p.73.

[60] Transcript of Evidence, p.263 (Senator the Hon Amanda Vanstone).

[61] DEETYA response to question on notice No.4.2 (28 October 1996).

[62] Ms Sudha Shenroy, Lecturer in Economic History, University of Newcastle, Submission No.20.

[63] ANU, Submission No.13, p.85.

[64] The Higher Education Legislation Amendment Bill 1996, Schedule of Amendments, Item 20.

[65] NTEU, Submission No.5, p.34.

[66] Ibid.