Chapter 8 Beyond official productivity statistics
Productivity is not a perfect measure for evaluating
policy
8.1
As highlighted in Chapter 2 and by the major
economic departments advising the Australian Government, the official
productivity estimates do not measure the wellbeing or living standards of the
community. This section outlines the issue from a policy perspective and
considers possible ways that the government can respond.
8.2
Productivity should be seen as a means to an
end, rather than an end in itself. The ultimate objective of public policy is
to promote community wellbeing and quality of life.
8.3
It is important to acknowledge that whilst
productivity can contribute to community wellbeing; it is not the sole
determinant. As the Productivity Commission notes, wellbeing has many
dimensions that includes:
n environmental
capital (amenity, biodiversity and air quality);
n social capital
(social attachments, community involvement and safety); and
n per capita income
(consumption and saving, funding of social activities and funding of
institutions, such as law and order).[1]
8.4
Productivity only directly contributes to improvements
in wellbeing by increases in per capita income. This is important because
increases in per capita income allow individuals to achieve a higher material
standard of living and for society, through taxation revenue, to fund a range
of government services and support facilities. The Treasury noted that:
Productivity improvements will also be important in helping
Australia adapt to the challenges of an ageing population and climate change.[2]
8.5
So whilst productivity improvements will play an
important role in ensuring that Australia has the resources to maintain living
standards and community wellbeing in the face of future (financial) challenges,
it is important to note that the ultimate objective of government policy is
community wellbeing and not productivity. The Department of Education,
Employment and Workplace Relations remarked that:
There is an increasing movement of international economic
thinkers pointing us to the importance of a wider measure of capacity as a
measure of the aggregate capacity of an economy and the wellbeing of the
society, rather than simply as a measure of outputs over inputs.[3]
The non-productivity determinants of wellbeing
8.6
When evaluating policies to improve productivity
it is important to understand what impact the policies will have on all factors
that affect community wellbeing.
8.7
Policies that improve productivity can help to
achieve other government objectives and improve community wellbeing. It is
possible that human capital policies to improve the skills of disadvantaged
members of society, such as the unemployed could lead to improvements in
productivity and increased job satisfaction for these individuals.
8.8
However, policies aimed at improving
productivity can hinder the achievement of other government objectives and compromise
community wellbeing.
8.9
It is possible for productivity improvements to
come at the expense of other means of achieving economic growth. As highlighted
by the Treasury and the Productivity Commission (PC) the sources of economic
growth are productivity, participation and population.[4] It is possible that some policies that increase productivity will
lower either workforce participation or population growth. PC researchers found
that France’s productivity improvement, was accompanied by a significant reduction
in labour utilisation, as shown in Figure 8.1.
Figure 8.1 Labour productivity and utilisation in France
Source Dolman,
B, Parham, D, and Zheng, S, Can Australia Match US Productivity Performance?
Productivity Commission Staff Working Paper, March 2007, p. 9.
8.10
Within Australia The Treasury highlighted the
potential conflict between improving productivity and workforce participation:
Some people who are not currently in the labour force, if you
brought them into the labour force, may be less productive than the current
average worker. So, if you took a strict measure, you could say they may reduce
labour productivity through reducing the average. That might be a nice
technical point but it would be a pretty silly conclusion. Given that there are
a range of disincentives for participation, removing those and improving
overall workforce participation outcomes clearly enhances wellbeing overall.[5]
8.11
Productivity objectives can also conflict with
other government objectives, such as minimising the risk borne by individuals.
It is possible that government policies aimed at increasing productivity could
actually increase the risk borne by individuals. Dr Ken Henry, analysing the
impact of structural reforms, noted that:
To put this (retrospectively) into our
wellbeing framework, structural reforms have often involved increasing risk to
some parts of the community in order to benefit Australian society in some
aggregate sense.[6]
8.12
One specific policy example that impacts on
productivity and the risk borne by individuals is occupational health and
safety (OH&S) laws. To a certain extent, OH&S laws designed to protect
the safety of workers can lower productivity, for example, the requirement to
erect scaffolding around a roof on a construction site will increase the safety
of construction workers, but will require more resources to complete the
construction activity.
8.13
The PC, in its submission, identified reforms to
State OH&S laws that prevent workers from bearing more risk as a potential
policy area to improve productivity:
For example, innovation in occupational health and safety
practices based on workers assuming responsibility for risks they are best
placed to manage, is prevented by regulation in some jurisdictions.[7]
8.14
As the PC notes, this policy that could promote
productivity is based on workers bearing the cost of extra risk. From a
Government perspective it is important to evaluate whether the gains in productivity
will outweigh the costs to workers from bearing greater risk.
8.15
Policies aimed at promoting productivity may
also impact on the government’s objectives in relation to the distribution of
income and wealth. PC researchers outlined how the policies on working hours
and minimum wages in some European countries had:
…excluded the low skilled from the work
force…. These same policy and institutional factors also affected productivity
outcomes. They shifted labour demand towards the relatively skilled… and
shifted factor demands toward capital and away from labour.[8]
8.16
This highlights the fact
that policies to promote productivity may reduce the incomes of the
disadvantaged in society with a negative impact on the distribution of income
and wealth.
Committee conclusion
8.17
The committee has found that productivity
measures alone are not a good measure for evaluating public policy because
productivity is not the sole determinant of community wellbeing and that
policies aimed at improving productivity can have positive or negative impacts
on the non‑productivity determinants of community wellbeing.
8.18
The committee also notes that economic growth is
not only stimulated by productivity growth; it may increase when productivity
growth declines if income growth is strong, yet the growth is at a slower rate
than the growth in inputs. The aim of public policy is to improve living
standards, and productivity growth is one way of achieving this.
The need for a policy evaluation framework
8.19
One possible response to evaluating policies
aimed at improving productivity is to consider these policies in a cost benefit
analysis framework. The evaluation criteria used within cost benefit analysis
is the net social benefit to the community, thus providing a policy criterion consistent
with improving community wellbeing. The Department of Finance and Deregulation
Cost Benefit Analysis handbook states that:
Cost-benefit analysis is a procedure for comparing
alternative courses of action by reference to the net social benefits that they
produce for the community as a whole.[9]
8.20
The cost benefit approach has been adopted by
Infrastructure Australia for assessing all infrastructure proposals[10], which is
particularly relevant because infrastructure projects have the potential to
impact on productivity, as well as having other impacts. The Australian
Government also mandates cost benefit analysis for regulatory proposals.[11]
8.21
The Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry
(ACCI) supported the use of cost benefit analysis:
Thus it is important that infrastructure investment decisions
are made after thorough cost benefit analyses to examine the economic,
environmental and social consequences, with the information available in public
domain.[12]
8.22
ACCI also highlighted the importance of cost benefit
analysis for assessing regulatory proposals[13] and the Master Builders of Australia also supported the use of cost
benefit analysis.[14]
Committee conclusion
8.23
The potential for policies
aimed at improving productivity to have a positive or negative impact on other
government objectives highlights the need for a policy evaluation framework
that will consider all of the impacts of a policy aimed at improving productivity.
8.24
In addition, the criteria to
evaluate policies must be based on community wellbeing, and using productivity
as the sole policy evaluation criteria is limited because it is only one
determinant of community wellbeing.
8.25
One option for the Government
is to mandate cost benefit analysis for all policies aimed at improving
productivity. This would be consistent with the Government’s approach to
assessing infrastructure and regulatory proposals.
8.26
The committee believes
extending the use of cost benefit analysis to public policy aimed at
productivity improvements would ensure the optimum mix of productivity and
wellbeing enhancing measures are employed.
Recommendation 6 |
8.27
|
The Australian Government mandates cost benefit analysis for
all policies aimed at improving aggregate productivity growth. |
Government service provision
8.28
The official productivity estimates do not cover
all industries within the economy and it is important in considering
Australia’s future productivity challenge that attention be given to those
industries for which productivity is not officially measured. As noted by the PC:
While estimates of output and hours worked
are published for the whole economy, productivity is only well-measured in that
part of the economy the ABS calls the ‘market sector’ - this is all the
economy except health, education, defence, government administration, property
and business services and personal and other services.[15]
8.29
Whilst many government services are not captured
in the official productivity statistics, the quality and efficiency of these
services can have a substantial impact on productivity. The impacts can be
twofold;
n government
services as an input into the production processes of businesses covered in the
market sector; and
n the
efficiency of government service provision itself as a form of productivity
improvement.
8.30
Dr Ken Henry outlined the consequences of not
measuring productivity for government services or measuring it only based on
reference to inputs:
An immediate consequence of [using inputs to
measure these services] is that productivity change for government-provided
services is ignored, because outputs are taken to move at the same rhythm as
inputs. It follows that if there is positive productivity growth in the public
sector, our measures under-estimate growth.[16]
8.31
An indication of the size of government service
provision is provided in the Report on Government Services 2010, which
includes: education; policing; courts; corrective services; emergency, health
and community services, and housing. These government services are valued at
approximately $132 billion or 13 per cent of GDP.[17]
8.32
An alternative measure of the size and
contribution of government services is provided by the employees employed in
the public service. The Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) estimates that
1.8 million people were employed in the public sector as of June 2009, or
approximately 17 per cent of the employed Australian workforce.[18] At the average
wage for these staff, this equates to a total employee cost of $108 billion
each year for public service provision.[19]
8.33
Based on the annual wages
cost of government service provision, a two per cent improvement in labour
productivity for government services could deliver a benefit of $2.2 billion to
the Australian community.[20]
8.34
Government service provision can also play an
important role in promoting productivity as an input into the production
processes of other businesses. The PC argued:
There is an imperative for the range of human services to be
delivered more efficiently as well as more effectively. Services in the areas
of education, health, childcare and aged care are all important to Australia's
future productivity and the wellbeing of the community generally. Businesses are also subject to the processes involved in Government
service provision that can impact on their productivity. [21]
8.35
Governments also impose regulations on business
that incur a compliance cost that reduces their productivity. The PC has
reported evidence that the compliance cost of regulations could be as high as 1.5
per cent of GDP.[22] The Government has identified regulation
as a potential source of productivity improvement.[23]
8.36
With government service provision consisting of
such a large proportion of economic output and of employed workers, there is
scope for productivity improvements in this sector to have a substantial
impact. The Treasury stated:
Improving productivity in the public sector and improving
public sector efficiency may or may not show up in measured productivity, but
it would clearly be an area where relatively little work has been done. I think
that will be an important area of work, one way or another, into the future.[24]
Committee conclusion
8.37
The official market sector productivity
estimates do not include government services, yet the quality and efficiency of
government services can have a significant impact on aggregate productivity
growth.
8.38
The public sector represents 17 per cent of the
workforce and produces output the equivalent of 13 per cent of GDP. Therefore,
in its own right the public sector is an important source of national
productivity growth, although this impact will not be captured directly in the
official productivity estimates.
8.39
Additionally, government services are an input
into the production processes of businesses and the quality of these services
can affect the productivity of these businesses, which will be captured in the
official productivity estimates.
Recommendation 7 |
8.40 |
Given the size and importance of government service
provision in its own right and as an input into the production processes of
other businesses it is important that any national productivity agenda
includes public sector service provision. |
The exclusion of the voluntary sector
8.41
Productivity measurement is based on economic
principles and as a result only covers industries that sell products or
services in a marketplace.
8.42
The economic output measure used for productivity
estimates exclude voluntary or community work in which there is no product or
service sold in a marketplace and for which the provider of the service does
not receive wages in return for their efforts. The Treasury stated:
A broad limitation with productivity measures flows from the
use of GDP in their calculation....GDP only counts market transactions which
excludes a wide range of activities.[25]
8.43
The ABS estimates that approximately 5.2 million
people did voluntary work during 2006.[26] In terms of the economic value of voluntary work, the ABS estimates
that the value of voluntary work for 1999-00 was $8.9 billion or 4.7 per
cent of GDP.[27] This estimate is derived by valuing voluntary work assuming that it
was undertaken in the formal economy in which workers were paid for their work.
8.44
In addition to the formal voluntary work
undertaken within a not‑for‑profit organisation, there is informal
voluntary work such as the unpaid caring work of an aged relative or a young
child that is not included in the ABS measures of voluntary work. The ABS estimated
in 2003 that there were 2.6 million carers and that 20 per cent of those were
primary carers.[28] The ABS found that primary carers had a lower workforce
participation rate of 39 per cent compared to 68 per cent for non carers.[29]
8.45
In response to a question about unpaid work in
the economy, particularly that done by women, Mr Brunker of the PC stated:
This is a very important issue and, as you are aware, there
are some efforts being made to shed some light on it, for example, through the
ABS’s wellbeing measures that they conduct. Just looking at those sorts of
publications, you can see why it does not get into the productivity numbers—it
is so very difficult to measure…The way we aggregate things together is that we
tend to use revealed valuations of these things to aggregate together to form
GDP or the output for productivity. Those sorts of activities are very
difficult to incorporate within productivity numbers.[30]
8.46
However, Mr Brunker went on to argue that productivity estimates:
…try to serve a particular purpose, and the particular
purpose is about efficiency within business organisations. They were never
really designed to give us an understanding of how well the community in
aggregate is going, although they are clearly a very important ingredient to that.[31]
8.47
Bearing this in mind, any growth of the
voluntary sector could have an impact on the size of the formal economy and
measured economic output. If individuals shift out of the formal economy (that
is, work that contributes to measured economic output) to the voluntary sector
in which their output is not measured then the impact will be a fall in
workforce participation and measured economic output.
8.48
The impact on productivity of such a shift in
labour resources over a short time horizon is not necessarily negative, as both
economic output and inputs have fallen. Indeed if the workers who shift are
average contributors to productivity then their shift from the measured economy
to the voluntary sector will have an inconsequential impact on aggregate productivity
growth.
8.49
Although there may be no direct impact on
productivity of such a transfer to the voluntary sector, if a reduction in
economic output reduces government revenue, then this could reduce the
government’s ability to invest in productivity enhancing reforms, which are
outlined in Chapter 7.
8.50
It is also possible for the voluntary sector to
provide a positive impact on productivity, through contributions to the formal
business sector. As an example, Professor Quiggin argued that:
…it is important to look beyond the enterprise sector and
consider the role of non-profit enterprises and ‘amateurs’ in areas such as
open-sources software, new media and Web 2.0 technologies, which are an
important source of new innovation.[32]
Committee conclusion
8.51
Voluntary work makes a valuable contribution to community wellbeing and
if given a nominal economic value would represent a significant proportion of
economic output.
8.52
To a certain extent any change in the amount of voluntary work can have
an impact on economic activity. However, the significant impacts will be on
workforce participation and economic output but the impact on measured productivity
is unlikely to be significant.
Mr Craig Thomson MP
Chair
28 April 2010