Chapter 2 - Issues in the bills
Overview
2.1
The purpose of this report is to identify and address matters
surrounding the provisions of the Clean Energy Amendment Bills 2012.[1]
The Government has flagged that these bills will help to build the framework to
link Australia’s carbon pricing mechanism with international emissions trading
schemes.[2] During the inquiry, four central
provisions emerged as areas worthy of analysis, namely:
- the implications of
linking Australia’s carbon trading scheme with international systems, including
the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS);
- the removal of the floor
price;
- the limits placed on
the use of eligible international carbon units to discharge an emitter’s
liability; and
- the treatment of
natural gas supply and use.
2.2
The Clean Energy Amendment Bills 2012 build on the Government’s Clean
Energy Legislative Package and will provide the framework for entities to
purchase and surrender eligible international carbon units to discharge
liabilities in the flexible price period of Australia’s emissions trading
scheme. This flexible price period will start in 2015 and the amendments in the
bills facilitate a link between the Australian carbon pricing mechanism and the
EU ETS from this time. The provisions also provide the flexibility for
Australia to link with other emissions trading schemes in the future.
2.3
Witnesses generally supported the concept of linking emissions trading
schemes. The committee heard that to the extent Australia wants to be part of a
global carbon market, then the measures in the amendment bills are an important
step towards that. However, some witnesses postulated that linking to the EU
ETS could weaken Australia’s control over scheme design.
2.4
To facilitate the link with the EU ETS, there will no longer be a ‘floor
price’ in Australia’s scheme. The floor price was to be implemented by imposing
a minimum auction reserve price and a charge on the surrender of eligible
international emissions units. Instead, it is proposed that the Minister may
establish a ‘reserve charge amount’ for a specific auction.
2.5
During the inquiry, budget implications and price volatility resulting
from the removal of the price floor were discussed. It was submitted that linking
to a large carbon market like the one supporting the EU ETS would achieve commensurate
price certainty for participants in Australia’s carbon market. The Government’s
carbon price revenue estimates also remain as published in the 2012-13 Budget.
2.6
A designated limit of 12.5 per cent has been set for Kyoto
units. The general limit – which allows for entities to meet
50 per cent of their liability through the purchase and surrender of
international units –remains in place. Both limits will continue until 2020. It
was submitted that the designated limit on Kyoto units will artificially
increase costs for liable entities, undermining the intent of the scheme to
provide least-cost abatement. The committee heard compelling evidence that the
designated limit was necessary to ensure the integrity of Australia’s emissions
trading scheme.
2.7
Provisions are made in the bills that seek to ensure liability for
carbon emissions is realised as high as possible in the natural gas supply
chain and that the principle of universal coverage for all liable entities in
this chain applies. Gas producers were concerned that the bills’ provisions
might have broader, unanticipated implications for the industry. The Department
of Climate Change and Energy Efficiency (DCCEE) assured the committee that the
intent of the provisions was narrow and that ensuing regulations would be
dependent on the outcome of consultation with stakeholders due to occur in the
near future.
Linking carbon markets
Background
2.8
Carbon markets are a prime vehicle to meet carbon pollution reduction
targets. There exist a number of carbon markets around the world. Individually,
these markets work in a localised way to reduce pollution, but linked, they can
create a global market place that fosters least-cost abatement and contributes
to an international solution to climate change.
2.9
Linking the Australian emissions trading scheme has been a policy
priority of the Government’s for some time. Since 2007, it has variously said:
As an Australian scheme begins to take shape, the Australian
Government will begin discussions with other nations which are developing or
contemplating complementary emissions trading regimes, and which share
Australia’s broad approach to climate change … The Australian scheme will be designed
to maximise the prospect of linkages with other schemes, and with policy-based
arrangements such as offsets, where offshore emissions reducing activities
could be counted by Australian firms in determining their net emissions.[3]
As a supporter of the development of a global system,
Australia has a direct interest in promoting links between comparable schemes.
Any Australian domestic trading scheme should be designed to enhance the scope
for links, both formal and informal, with as many different systems as
possible.[4]
The Government acknowledges the overwhelming support of
stakeholders for linking and recognises the benefits of linking in providing
low-cost compliance options for liable entities and in supporting an efficient
global response to climate change.[5]
Australia’s carbon price will be linked to carbon markets
around the world from the start of the flexible price period. This will allow
reductions in carbon pollution to be pursued globally at the lowest cost.[6]
... it is common sense to support international linking
because it assists in providing emissions reduction at least cost and it
contributes to knitting together different national and regional schemes. It
develops a common carbon price across economies, a common incentive to cut
emissions, and fairly shares the burden of doing so.[7]
2.10
The amendment bills provide the legislative framework for linking
Australia’s emissions trading scheme to other schemes, including in the first
instance the EU ETS. The Explanatory Memorandum to the bills states:
The amendments are designed to enable the Government to make
and implement arrangements to link with a variety of schemes, and are therefore
designed to provide appropriate flexibility for the Government in implementing
these technical arrangements.[8]
2.11
The EU ETS is a mandatory emissions trading scheme covering at least
30 countries in Europe. It has operated since 2005 and by 2011, it had
delivered emissions reductions of 17.5 per cent below 1990 levels in the EU.[9]
The carbon market supporting the EU ETS is also the largest in the world. In
2011, trade in European carbon units represented at least three quarters of all
trade in global carbon units, in both volume and value terms.[10]
Analysis
2.12
The concept of linking emissions trading schemes was generally supported
by submitters and witnesses who appeared before the committee. The committee
heard that to the extent Australia wants to be part of a global carbon market,
then the measures in the amendment bills are an important step towards that.[11]
The committee also heard that broadly, the amendments were a positive thing
that would better deliver the policy intent of the Clean Energy Act 2011.[12]
2.13
Evidence presented to the committee indicated there are multiple
benefits to linking. These include expanding the scope of abatement
opportunities available to Australian liable entities and providing them with
access to well‑established markets to assist with hedging risk.[13]
2.14
Linking Australia’s emissions trading scheme to the EU ETS as the
amendment bills facilitate will also simplify compliance for entities liable in
both Australia and Europe. These entities will be able to use fungible carbon
units – either European allowances or Australian carbon units – to acquit their
liability under either scheme.[14]
2.15
The Australian Financial Markets Association submitted that:
Linking of the Clean Energy Scheme with sound international
schemes has been consistently requested by AFMA as a mechanism to increase
market depth, achieve least cost abatement and reduce overall risks for participants.[15]
2.16
Likewise, the Clean Energy Council stated that it:
... supports the linking of Australia’s carbon pricing scheme
with international emissions trading systems. International linking allows
Australian businesses to access emissions reductions opportunities at least
cost. With international linking, the carbon price in Australia will
essentially be set by international supply and demand for abatement.[16]
2.17
Beyond the broader economic and commercial benefits, witnesses before
the committee suggested that linking carbon markets also generates momentum
towards a global carbon market to reduce carbon pollution. The IETA stated:
We think that Australia's concrete steps towards creating a
real link between two different carbon markets on different sides of the planet
encourages those other countries to see that their own domestic efforts to
create carbon markets can have a further step where they can link to other
countries. It is not just theory; it is becoming practice.[17]
2.18
While support for the general concept of linking was widespread, the
committee is aware that views vary on this and that some believe that linking
Australia’s scheme to the EU ETS may not be as beneficial.[18]
2.19
The committee heard the view that jurisdictions, including Europe, will
design their emissions trading schemes specific to their national
circumstances, and changes in foreign schemes to which we are linked may not be
consistent with our national interest. The Australian Coal Association stated:
... the EU will design a scheme to meet its purposes and
Australia will have no say really in that design ... there is a significant
risk that what is in the best interests of the European Union is not in the
best interests of Australia.[19]
2.20
The Cement Industry Federation also said:
... it appears that Australia has very little say over any
major scheme changes that are contemplated by the European Union ... Australia
should not be willing to hand over ‘sovereignty’ on scheme design unless the
scheme becomes a truly international scheme.[20]
2.21
Witnesses discussed with the committee that linking by its very nature
subjects participants to a degree of loss of sovereignty. Just as global
markets for other commodities are influenced by exogenous factors which
participants must manage, so too will global carbon markets. Baker &
McKenzie stated:
The truth of the matter is that ... these are global markets.
If OPEC makes a decision on oil, the oil price changes. What you are seeing is
that, in a global marketplace, you have to manage the carbon price.[21]
2.22
Bloomberg New Energy Finance also pointed out that the market that
operates under the auspices of the United Nations and which generates Kyoto
units already involves an inherent loss of sovereignty for Australia:
Any time a link is forged between an Australian carbon market
and any other market—whether it is the international offset market, the
European market or the New Zealand market—there will be an element of
policy-taking from Australia. In the CER [a form of Kyoto unit] market—where,
in the current legislation, we are linked to the value of 50 per cent of
companies' liabilities, potentially—that market price is determined by a
melting pot of demand and supply across the entire world, driven by the UN
policy negotiations and subject to a significantly larger number of forces than
the EU ETS price.[22]
2.23
Bloomberg further argued that treaty negotiations with Europe in the
context of the two-way link between Australia’s scheme and the EU ETS provides
the opportunity for Australia to mitigate any potential loss of sovereignty:
So while it is very true that there is a risk of Australia
having to accept policy decisions from other markets, I think this is actually
a lower-risk move, because at least Australia can have a bilateral discussion
with the EU and negotiate its position up-front rather than essentially
accepting what comes out of a UNFCCC slightly messy international negotiation.[23]
Conclusion
2.24
The committee considers that linking the Australian emissions trading
scheme to other emissions trading schemes, including to the EU ETS, will
provide clear benefits to Australian entities. The combined EU ETS and
Australian emissions trading schemes will allow the inter-continental pursuit
of low cost abatement and is an important step to achieving a global carbon
market and, ultimately, a global solution to climate change. The committee
supports the provisions in the bills that facilitate linking.
2.25
The committee notes views that linking schemes could involve a loss of
autonomy over the design of Australia’s emissions trading system. However, it
is also the committee’s view that in the process of formally linking with
international emissions trading schemes, the Government will be able to
participate in treaty negotiations to ensure Australia’s interests are promoted.
Removal of the floor price
Background
2.26
The price floor in Australia’s emissions trading scheme represented a
minimum carbon price which was to be implemented through a minimum auction
reserve price and a charge on the surrender of eligible international emissions
units.[24] While enabling
legislation existed to implement these features, the Government had not made
regulations pursuant to this legislation, pending consultation with
stakeholders.
2.27
The price floor was intended to provide a degree of carbon price
certainty, but it is also not the only way to achieve this. Access to large and
liquid carbon markets, like the EU ETS, can provide commensurate carbon price
certainty.[25]
2.28
To remove the surrender
charge on eligible international emissions units, the current amendments will
repeal section 124 of the Clean Energy Act 2011, which introduced the
surrender charge, and the entire Clean Energy (International Unit Surrender
Charge) Act 2011. Under current law, if an eligible international emissions
unit is surrendered in the 2015–16, 2016–17 or 2017–18 financial years, a
charge would be imposed. However under the amended law, no charge will be
imposed on the surrender of eligible international emissions units.[26]
2.29
Reference to a minimum auction reserve price will also no longer be provided
in subsection 111(5) of the Clean Energy Act 2011. Under current law,
provision is made for minimum auction reserve charges of $15 for 2015–16, $16
for 2016–17 and $17.05 for 2017–18. There will be no minimum auction reserve
charge automatically applied under the amended law.[27]
2.30
The Minister may establish a ‘reserve charge amount’ for a specific
auction in a legislative instrument. According to the Explanatory Memorandum:
The ‘auction reserve charge amount’ is a mechanism aimed at
enhancing the price discovery of the auction. A reserve charge amount can serve
to counteract bid shading (that is, bidding an amount which is less than the
amount that the participant believes that the unit is worth) or collusion by
auction participants by minimising the potential gains from such behaviour.[28]
Analysis
2.31
There has been both support for, and argument against, the removal of
the floor price in evidence presented to the committee.
2.32
In its submission to DCCEE, the Business Council of Australia indicated
its support for the removal of the floor price:
The BCA supports the removal of the floor price and a
surrender charge. Both these elements of the legislation distorted the market
that is intended by the legislation and will bring additional costs to the
economy and consumers at a time when all efforts should be directed at
maintaining a strong and growing economy.[29]
2.33
Similarly in its submission, COZero approved of the removal of the floor
price and linking as a way to promote least cost abatement in Australia and to
reduce uncertainty for liable parties:
Prior to the amendment of the legislation, COZero’s market
experience showed that the floor price and proposed surrender charge for
international units would significantly diminish the demand for these permits.
Subsequently, it is our stance that the removal of the price floor and 12.5%
import cap (very close to European levels) will promote demand for these units
and allow for affordable abatement.[30]
2.34
The Australian Financial Markets Association also supported the removal
of the floor price, arguing that it would improve the design of the Australian
carbon market, reduce costs and simplify administration.[31]
2.35
On the other hand, the Climate Institute argued its preference for an
extended floor price ‘because of the predictability it provides investors and
the economic efficiencies it could deliver’. The Climate Institute noted three
benefits from a gradually rising floor price:
- It helps deter
investment in highly emission intensive technologies that would become stranded
under the stronger policies needed in the future.
- It reduces downside
financial risk premiums associated with low carbon investments thereby reducing
the costs of investments.
- It encourages
investment in low emissions technologies through more predictable price signals.
This brings down their costs through ‘learning by doing’ and economies of
scale.[32]
2.36
The Climate Institute noted that ‘without a carbon price or strong
limits on the import of international offset credits from developing countries,
Australian carbon prices would likely fall to single digits in 2015’. This would allow an Australian company to
‘buy a credit from a country like China for a renewable energy project that they
had built for less than $5 per tonne’. The result of this would be that
Australia would be locked into ‘the polluting technology of the past’ and would
not be prepared for ‘the emerging and inevitable low-carbon economy’.[33]
2.37
The Climate Institute did concede, however, the viability of ‘linking
with the world’s biggest carbon market with a limit on international permits’,
provided ‘it is combined with strong policies for domestic clean energy and
energy efficiency’.[34]
2.38
In evidence before the committee, DCCEE noted that the floor price was
only ever intended as an interim measure, for the first three years of the
flexible price period, while domestic markets develop.[35]
DCCEE also noted that the link to the EU ETS operated as an alternative to the
floor price in providing price stability by granting access to a mature carbon
market:
They have well-established futures markets. They provide an
alternative way in which domestic liable parties can actually lock in the
future liabilities under the scheme ... The link to the European scheme is a
different way of providing long-term price security, because you can already,
today, bank on the price which is trading in futures markets within the
European Union.[36]
2.39
The evidence received by the committee at its public hearing indicated
widespread support for the removal of the floor price.[37]
Conclusion
2.40
The committee considers that removing the floor price and repealing the
legislative mechanisms which would have given effect to it will make linking
the Australian emissions trading scheme with the EU ETS administratively
simpler, facilitating the overall policy outcome. The link to the EU ETS and
access to associated derivative markets should offer the Australian carbon
market commensurate carbon price stability in absence of the floor price.
Surrender limits on Kyoto units
Background
2.41
A key part of the linking arrangement with the EU ETS and to which the
amendment bills give effect is the introduction of a surrender limit on Kyoto
units (referred in the bills as a ‘designated limit’) of 12.5 per cent of an
entity’s annual liability. The limit will be in place until 2020, after which
regulations may change the percentage. The amendment bills provide a new power
at section 123A of the Clean Energy Act 2011 to enact this limit.
2.42
The designated limit on Kyoto units is in addition to an existing
‘general limit’ on other international units. The general limit for
international units is set at 50 per cent of an entity’s annual liability.
2.43
DCCEE advised the committee that the surrender limit on Kyoto units was
part of the negotiated deal struck with the European Commission to link
emissions trading schemes.[38]
2.44
The amendment bills provide the Government with the regulation-making
power to introduce additional designated limits on eligible international units
in future. The Explanatory Memorandum says:
The setting of designated limits through regulations reflects
the requirement for flexibility in both setting and changing limits over time,
reflecting the maturation of Australia’s emissions trading arrangements, the
enhancement of existing links with overseas emissions trading schemes and the
development of new links and international emissions trading systems.[39]
2.45
To provide sufficient notice to liable entities of new limits,
designated limits will come into effect one to three financial years after the
regulation is registered.[40] In general, three years
notice must be given before a new designated limit is introduced or an existing
limit is changed. However, to give effect to an international arrangement, at
least one year’s notice must be given before a designated limit associated with
the arrangement is introduced.
Analysis
2.46
The Explanatory Memorandum to the bills states that the purpose of
limiting units is to safeguard the environmental integrity of Australia’s
pollution reduction efforts. The designated limit on Kyoto units will also
assist with the convergence of the price of European units and Australian
carbon units.[41]
2.47
However several submitters and witnesses were concerned about the limit,
arguing that because it will restrict access to comparatively cheap Kyoto
units, it is inconsistent with the broader objective of linking to achieve
pollution reduction at least-cost.
2.48
During the hearing APPEA asked:
If we are about reducing emissions and meeting the targets
that we have domestically and as part of our international obligations at
lowest cost, why introduce constraints that frustrate that goal?[42]
2.49
Similarly the Cement Industry Federation submitted:
It is not clear that Australia has gained any specific
advantage by agreeing to put sub thresholds in place. By definition, the sub
threshold does not encourage access to lowest cost abatement.[43]
2.50
Conversely, some submitters supported the surrender limit on Kyoto
units, recognising that it would still allow access to relatively cheap units.
COZero stated:
... it is our stance that the removal of the price floor and
12.5% import cap (very close to European levels) will promote demand for these
units and allow affordable abatement.[44]
2.51
The committee also heard that Kyoto units would unlikely effectively
realise the transition to a low‑carbon economy that the Clean Energy
Act 2011 sought to achieve. In particular, the supply of Kyoto units is not
capped which contributes to a low price for them, currently around
$2.50 per unit. Bloomberg argued:
... I think that we need to be careful of buying carbon for
the sake of buying carbon. While the carbon price mechanism is a least-cost
mechanism, having the cheapest carbon—that is, a $2 carbon price—is not going
to achieve the objectives that it has been put in place to achieve. Look at the
power sector and the coal-gas fuel‑switching price. Just turning off coal
and turning on gas as an abatement measure is at least $30 today and, depending
on the gas prices as we move to more LNG exports, is probably moving up towards
$60 and beyond. That is just for the power sector. So, if we are serious about
reducing emissions inside Australia, we need a higher carbon price than $2.50.
That will increase costs for carbon-intensive businesses, but that is the
nature of reducing emissions: it does cost something.[45]
2.52
Due to a lack of global legal agreement around the future form of the
United Nation’s mechanisms which govern Kyoto units, Baker & McKenzie
further pointed out that there is currently no certainty around the prospects
for Kyoto units beyond this year:
CERs are produced under the international rules of the Kyoto
Protocol. There is absolutely no guarantee at this point in time that you are
going to be able to use those post-2012. There needs to be a negotiation under
the Kyoto Protocol about facilitating the extension of Kyoto and how those
units are used ... I think people have forgotten that that is not yet a done
deal—the use of those international permits.[46]
2.53
Similarly, the committee also heard that much greater business certainty
is provided by allowing Australian liable entities to use European units to
acquit their pollution liabilities. Unlike the market for Kyoto units, the
European market is much larger, more established and presents more of a going
concern.[47] These features are important
as it provides a better basis on which to make investment decisions around
long-lived, low carbon technologies.
2.54
The committee further heard that the limit would still allow for
significant access to Kyoto units in the Australian scheme. While estimates
vary, around 230 million Kyoto units could be used in the Australian scheme
between now and 2020.[48]
Conclusion
2.55
The committee acknowledges the concerns expressed in relation to the
limit placed on the use of Kyoto units in Australia’s scheme.
2.56
The limit was a condition of the linking arrangement agreed between the
Government and the European Commission. For the link to the EU ETS to work
effectively and for this to help foster a transition to a low‑carbon
economy in Australia, consistent with the broader objectives of the Clean
Energy Act 2011, some limitation on Kyoto units is necessary. The committee
supports the provisions in the bills which facilitate surrender limits on eligible
international units.
Natural Gas
Background
2.57
The amendments relating to the treatment of natural gas aim to ensure
that liability for carbon pollution is realised as high as possible in the
natural gas supply chain and that the principle of universal coverage for all
liable entities applies.[49] The Explanatory
Memorandum notes that:
Currently, there is the potential for certain commercial
arrangements to lead to situations which may not be captured by the current
provisions of the CE Act concerning emissions embodied in natural gas.
Regulations may set out the circumstances in which liability applies to a
supplier or end user in specific circumstances, enabling the Government to
maintain competitive neutrality across the industry by supporting the complete
coverage of natural gas under the carbon pricing mechanism. The specific provisions
would be consistent with the current natural gas provisions in that liability
would arise where the use of the natural gas results in greenhouse gas
emissions.[50]
2.58
The Explanatory Memorandum also notes that these provisions would not
come into effect unless and until the necessary regulations are made, and that
the Government would consult on the development of these regulations prior to
their implementation.[51]
Analysis
2.59
In its submission to DCCEE, AGL rejected the proposed amendments
relating to natural gas. AGL stated:
These changes to the already complex gas supplier provisions
of the Clean Energy Act 2011 (the Act) will introduce significant new
obligations for natural gas suppliers, including the development of new
systems, processes and capabilities, and as they are currently drafted, may
prove impossible to comply with.[52]
2.60
AGL considered that the existing coverage of natural gas supply under
the carbon pricing mechanism is very near complete, and that the amendments are
not required at this time.[53]
2.61
APPEA also raised concerns about how the amendments relating to the
treatment of natural gas would operate and called for their removal from the
bills.[54] In evidence before the committee,
APPEA argued that the proposed amendments were ‘a very complicated part of the
scheme’, and that they had ‘some reasonably significant commercial implications
for gas suppliers in terms of negotiating their commercial arrangements with
their customers and with others in the gas supply chain’. APPEA urged further
consultations before these provisions were dealt with by Parliament.[55]
2.62
In response, DCCEE emphasised that it was important to understand the
context and overarching principles of the proposed amendments :
The underpinning principle for natural gas liability is that
it should be at the point highest upstream that it can be, and that has been
what has driven the question of the point of liability in natural gas from the
outset—that was a recommendation from the Shergold review and there have been
some iterations in the way in which that has been applied. The carbon pollution
reduction scheme had a particular approach and, after that approach no longer
proceeded, the issue was revisited and the approach that was set out in the Clean
Energy Act 2011 was adopted. What that does is reinforce the principle of
liability as high as possible in the supply chain but then provide flexibility
about where that point of liability might be moved to reflect the commercial
arrangements in the gas sector.[56]
2.63
DCCEE also noted that the proposed amendments were designed to ensure
the original intent of the legislation was not subverted:
These provisions are there to address what we consider to be
a potential gap in liability that may emerge around specific arrangements that
exist in the gas supply chain. The overarching objective here is to ensure that
emissions embodies in natural gas are all covered, regardless of where their
point of liability might be. The objective of the legislation and these
amendments is to ensure that that gap cannot be opened and that arrangements
can be made through regulations in a flexible way in consultation with industry
to ensure that the point of liability is put at the appropriate point
reflecting the commercial arrangements which exist in the industry and which may
evolve over time. Those commercial arrangements in this sector, partly
reflecting the dynamism and growth in the sector over recent years, change
fairly rapidly, so the objective with these amendments is to provide that
liability to put the point of liability at the appropriate point and to do so
in a way that does not allow potential gaps in liability to emerge in this
area.[57]
2.64
DCCEE highlighted that the proposed amendments are targeted to the
particular issue in question and narrow in scope.[58]
DCCEE also emphasised that without the regulations, nothing in the amendments
would be given effect and that there would be extensive consultation in
conjunction with drafting of the regulations. DCCEE noted that these
‘amendments are really largely providing for a regulation-making power to make
sure that people operating in this industry understand that emissions embodying
gas will be covered one way or the other’. This would provide ‘a degree of
certainty to the industry about the rules of the game’.[59]
2.65
DCCEE outlined the proposed consultation process, stating that:
There will be a paper setting out the options around the
precise regulations that are proposed. The indication has been, really, that
that should be done probably by the end of October. Then by the end of the year
the department would release draft regulations for consideration by the
industry. Those regulations would be made by March of next year, giving people
a lead period before 1 July 2013 to understand the implications of any
compliance changes that may arise.[60]
2.66
APPEA acknowledged that the intention of the proposed amendments was
limited in nature and that the rationale behind them was not controversial.[61]
It also acknowledged the Government’s stated intention to consult with industry
over the regulations.[62]
Conclusion
2.67
The committee is satisfied that the provisions in the bills dealing with
the treatment of natural gas supply and use are necessary to give effect to the
policy intent of the original legislation.
2.68
Moreover, the committee is satisfied that the proposed method of
implementing these changes, by providing a framework in legislation which will
then be detailed in regulation, is consistent with current legislative
practice, and will allow sufficient consultation to address the concerns of
industry. The committee therefore supports these provisions of the bills.
2.69
The committee also notes and supports the Government’s stated intention
to carry out detailed consultation over the provisions of the regulations.
Recommendation 1 |
2.70 |
The House pass the Clean Energy Amendment (International
Emissions Trading and Other Measures) Bill 2012 and associated bills as
proposed. |
Julie Owens MP
Chair
9 October 2012