CHAPTER 3

28th Report of the Senate Select Committee on Superannuation
Choice of Fund
Table of Contents

CHAPTER 3

THE PRINCIPLE OF FUND CHOICE

Introduction

3.1 The Committee encountered a range of views about the principle of choice, ranging from strong support to a more critical appraisal. Some witnesses took no firm view either way on the policy, preferring instead to accept the Government's decision to proceed with its policy, and to restrict their comments to the implementation details.

3.2 The Government places considerable emphasis on the benefits it considers increased competition will bring to superannuation. A group of witnesses, while not necessarily opposing the choice of fund principle, disputed whether choice of fund would deliver economic benefits to employees.

3.3 Evidence was received questioning whether the choice of fund policy provides true choice for employees. Some witnesses also questioned whether the choice of fund policy is supported by an underlying demand for change or is a product of representations from groups who hope to derive a commercial advantage from its introduction.

 

Support for the choice principle

3.4 William M. Mercer Pty Ltd, Australia's largest firm of superannuation consultants, welcomed the Government's draft choice of fund legislation as a `positive contribution to the development of the Australian superannuation industry'. Mercers told the Committee that:

It is clear that the Government has listened to concerns expressed by employers and the superannuation industry and has made a number of welcome changes. [1]

3.5 The Committee also encountered support for the Government's view from a range of other witnesses. For example, Mr Tony Aveling, Acting Chief Executive, Australian Bankers Association said that:

3.6 Mr Aveling advised the Committee that the industry has a number of features that suggest there is scope for considerable competitive gains. He said that there are a considerable number of small funds - only 4 per cent of active funds having assets in excess of $1 million. In his view, this offers scope for substantial economies of scale in funds management and administration. He illustrated his point by quoting how the administration cost per member in defined benefit and corporate funds drops by a factor of 10 as the number of members increases from 15 to 10,000. He concluded:

3.7 A number of witnesses also considered that giving people choice would increase general community interest and understanding of retirement saving. For example, Mr Stephen Child, Senior Manager, Technical Services, Commonwealth Bank, told the Committee that choice offered individuals the opportunity to optimise their superannuation to their individual needs and circumstances. He thought that without choice, people would have no motive to take any interest:

3.8 The Investment and Financial Services Association (IFSA) considered that the introduction of choice could have beneficial effects beyond compulsory minimum SG contributions and lead to greater voluntary contributions `once people have a greater understanding of how much they really need to put away to save for an adequate level of retirement income.' [5]

3.9 Mr David Connolly, Director, Superannuation and Government Relations, Phillips Fox and former member of the House of Representatives, saw introducing choice as a logical second step after introducing compulsory saving for retirement through the SG system. He told the Committee that:

3.10 The Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia also lent its support to the choice concept. ASFA's Federal President, Ms Rosemary Vilgan, told the Committee that on balance, ASFA had come out in favor of choice for a number of reasons. These reasons were similar to those advanced by other witnesses. ASFA also were of the view that people currently in inappropriate funds should be given the opportunity to move:

Alternative views

3.11 Alternative views on choice of fund fall into three broad categories:

Will competition reduce costs?

3.12 The Government places considerable emphasis on the benefits it considers increased competition will bring to superannuation. The Assistant Treasurer, Senator the Hon. Rod Kemp, reaffirmed this principle in evidence during the Canberra public hearing:

3.13 A number of witnesses, while not necessarily opposing the choice of fund principle, disputed whether choice of fund would deliver economic benefits to employees.

3.14 Towers Perrin, a prominent firm of consulting actuaries, were amongst the several witnesses who questioned the economic benefits of increased competition in choice of fund. Mr Ken Lockery, Principal, considered that choice of fund was fully supportable on democratic principles alone:

3.15 However, Mr Lockery sounded a note of caution about the anticipated benefits of competition. He argued that the majority of employees in large employer based or industry funds would not receive any benefit and might instead suffer a net economic loss. He said that this was because the Government had not recognised the intense competition that already exists:

3.16 Mr Lockery was of the view that costs would increase because of factors such as greater marketing costs, administrative costs and costs of people switching funds. He thought that particularly in the case of people who were in a default fund, `their net benefits will be a little lower'. However, this had to be weighed up against the advantages:

3.17 Towers Perrin recommended that `clear, objective benchmarks' be established to monitor the success or otherwise of the policy. They contended that such measurement should be established before the Government put the policy in place:

3.18 The Australian Institute of Superannuation Trustees were also among the groups who disagreed with the Government's proposition that costs and fees would fall under choice. Mr Geoffrey Cook, the Institute's President was emphatic:

3.19 Mr Cook attributed the likely increases in costs to a number of factors. These include marketing, which he thought would increase `very materially'; administrative costs associated with the transfer of members; and legal costs. `All of these add up to more and more dollars which are going to be paid by our members out there.' [13]

3.20 It is clear that low overhead funds will have to increase expenditure on product promotion if they are to survive in a fiercely competitive post choice environment. Some indication of the competitive environment they may face is provided by current finance sector expenditure on advertising.

3.21 Ms Helen Hewitt, fund Secretary, C+BUS, provided the Committee with information about current expenditure on advertising in the finance sector. She noted that in 1997, this sector spent $390 million on advertising, $216 million of which was on television advertising. She said that `One big life office spends $1.5 million a month promoting superannuation to the community.' [14]

3.22 Ms Hewitt speculated on what this might mean for C+BUS and attempted to quantify the extra costs that might result from choice induced competition:

3.23 Ms Hewitt concluded by casting doubt over whether competition would in fact produce better retirement benefits for fund members:

Government view on benefits of competition and effects on fund costs

3.24 The Committee sought information about the apparently conflicting views it received during the Sydney and Melbourne public hearings concerning the likely effects of competition on funds costs. The Government's stated position is that it believes increased competition will drive down costs and fees and result in better benefits for fund members. However, several witnesses disputed whether this, in fact, would be the case.

3.25 Mr Keith Chapman, Acting Deputy Commissioner - Superannuation, Insurance and Superannuation Commission (ISC), told the Committee that, overall,

3.26 However, Mr Chapman acknowledged that `individual funds may incur cost'.

3.27 The Committee sought information as to whether the ISC could provide any information about the overseas experience of expenditure on advertising and marketing costs when choice is introduced. Mr John Larkin, Assistant Commissioner, Policy, ISC, told the Committee that:

3.28 Mr Larkin advised that there was some evidence of how competition could drive down costs. He told the Committee that the ISC had:

3.29 He said that this flows through to cheaper fees and charges for the end user, the consumer. `I think these developments will gather pace as choice of fund is taken up.' [20]

Does the proposal deliver true choice for employees?

3.30 A number of contributors to the inquiry questioned whether the government's choice model will provide adequate choice for employees. For example, the Australian Consumers Association, a supporter of the choice principle, contended that the Government's model will not allow choice for many employees:

3.31 The submission acknowledged that there are `reasonable arguments' for minimising administrative loads on employers that may result from fund choice. However the Association considered that the Government has not achieved an appropriate balance:

3.32 The Association proposed an alternative model, under which the employer would take responsibility for the default fund, coupled with open ended choice for those employees who wanted it. [23] Essentially, the Association's model amounts to choice driven by employee demand.

3.33 The ACTU also disputed whether the Government's model provides employees with adequate levels of choice. Ms Linda Rubenstein, Senior Industrial Officer, Australian Council of Trade Unions, contended that the choice proposal in its current form actually offered employees minimal choice. She said that:

3.34 In common with other witnesses from the Trade Union movement, Ms Rubenstein contended that the power relationship between employers and employees is such that the employers wishes are likely to prevail leaving the employee with little real choice:

Government position

3.35 The Committee sought information from the Assistant Treasurer about the extent to which the Government's proposal delivers choice to employees. The Minister noted that at the moment, there is no choice for many employees:

3.36 The Minister advised that the Government aimed to give employees choice, but had to balance this against employers' interests:

3.37 There are arguments both for and against the Government's choice model and alternative options. While some may see totally unlimited choice as a more reasonable option, this also has shortcomings. Unlimited choice may impose excessive administrative burdens on employers. While unlimited choice may be attractive for some well informed employees, it does open up the possibility of poor decision making on the part of employees who are not able to make an informed choice.

3.38 Unlimited choice, however, removes a number of potential legal problems in respect of liabilities that were of great concern to many small employers. This is because responsibility for selecting a fund shifts from the employer to the employee.

3.39 It can be argued that the four fund option places too much power in the hands of the employer. However, while the employer is able to select the funds offered, this model nonetheless does offer greater choice than that presently available to many employees and can only be regarded as an improvement on the present situation.

Is there a demand for choice from employees?

3.40 Several witnesses, particularly those representing the union movement, questioned whether many employees were in fact actively seeking choice of fund. They also questioned the motives of some choice supporters, suggesting that these groups may in fact be driven by the potential for commercial gain.

3.41 The view expressed by Mr Michael O'Sullivan, National Executive President of the Australian Services Union, are representative of those who question the need for this policy. Mr O'Sullivan suggested that the Government's agenda in this area arises out of hostility towards industry funds and lobbying by the banks and major life offices to gain a share of the superannuation market. He told the Committee that:

3.42 Mr O'Sullivan considered that opening the superannuation market up to these groups would have detrimental effects on his members, leading to poorer retirement benefits:

Application to Public Sector schemes

3.43 The Committee received some "grassroots" evidence of public sector employee discontent with the funds in which they found themselves. Mr Brian Werndly and Mr Darryl Brick, former defence force employees, wrote to the Committee complaining about the defence force fund. Mr Werndly's "employer" contributions are locked into the fund until he reaches retirement age. The value of his benefits is indexed to the CPI. He claimed that this was `grossly unfair', because almost all funds return better than the CPI. [30]

3.44 The Committee does not draw any strong conclusions from these complaints, which are clearly based on a misunderstanding of the nature of unfunded defined benefit schemes. However, these views usefully illustrate the principle that some people, when they are in funds with low earning rates, are conscious that they could do better and might benefit from the possibilities that choice of fund may offer.

3.45 The principle of choice is not being extended to military superannuation schemes. Current members of the PSS and CSS will be offered choice of fund from 1 July 2000. The Government has announced that it intends to close the PSS to new entrants from 1 July 1998 and will offer new Commonwealth employees choice of fund from that date.

3.46 The Committee is currently considering legislation concerning the application of choice to Commonwealth employees and the closure of the PSS.

Employer attitudes to choice of fund

3.47 Generally, smaller employers have expressed concern about quickly coming to grips with legal responsibilities and key features statements.

3.48 Some employers clearly saw the need to learn about and implement choice of fund as an imposition. Two pithy comments made in a submission by Mr Stephen Cole, a patisserie manager, summed up his views:

3.49 Coles Myer, Australia's largest private sector employer, supports the concept for choice of fund. Coles Myer was, however, concerned about a number of issues relating to the implementation of the choice policy. In particular, Coles Myer was concerned about training requirements for staff, changes to payroll systems and whether the company could meet the Government's announced start-up date. [32]

Footnotes

[1] Submission, p. 1

[2] Evidence, p. 3.

[3] Evidence, p. 4.

[4] Evidence, p. 199.

[5] Evidence, Mr John Maroney, p.374.

[6] Evidence, p. 253.

[7] Evidence, p. 238.

[8] Evidence, p. 405.

[9] Evidence, p. 302.

[10] Evidence, p. 308-9.

[11] Submission, p. 11.

[12] Evidence, p. 104.

[13] Evidence, p. 104.

[14] Evidence, p. 180.

[15] Evidence, p. 181.

[16] Evidence, p. 180.

[17] Evidence, p. 434.

[18] Evidence, p. 433.

[19] Evidence, p. 435.

[20] Evidence, p. 435.

[21] Submission, p. 8.

[22] Submission, p. 8.

[23] Submission, p. 8.

[24] Evidence, p. 123.

[25] Evidence, p. 123.

[26] Evidence, p. 419.

[27] Evidence, p. 419.

[28] Evidence, p. 54.

[29] Evidence, p. 54.

[30] Submission no.11, p. 11.

[31] Submission no. 1, p. 1.

[32] Evidence, p. 84-85.