Chapter 4
Financial Management
4.1
This chapter builds on information contained in chapter 3 to analyse
state and territory financial management. It discusses interest payments,
public sector wages, unfunded superannuation liabilities, and financial
forecasting as key features of financial management across the states. The
chapter then examines the main revenue sources of state government; taxation,
and income from the Commonwealth. Finally, the chapter touches on the financial
relationship between state and local levels of government. However, the first,
and perhaps most significant aspect of financial management in this chapter, is
debt levels and management.
Debt
4.2
Of itself, debt is not symptomatic of a problem for sustainable
budgeting. It is common practice for governments to borrow even when they have
a cash surplus. For example, the Australian Government is committed to issuing
sufficient Treasury Bonds to support the Treasury Bond Futures market, despite
having large cash surpluses to fund spending.[1]
4.3
Infrastructure management, which is dealt with substantively in chapter
6, is a case in point. Borrowing to fund economically responsible
infrastructure spending does not necessarily reflect poor economic management.
In fact, it can help to spread the financial burden of paying for that
infrastructure across those generations that benefit from it. Infrastructure
can expand the nation's productive capacity thereby allowing it to achieve
strong, sustainable growth with low inflation.[2]
However it may be that it is inefficient for governments to borrow to build
infrastructure if the private sector could have built that infrastructure
instead. Governments have been loath to borrow in recent decades. It is
commonly held that incurring debt, for whatever purpose, is deeply unpalatable
to voters in contemporary Australia. Mr Henry Ergas provided the committee
with his analysis of the situation as it affects state and territory
governments:
What is true is that in the late nineties we were coming out of
the situation during the eighties and early nineties where state governments
had in numerous instances managed their fiscal positions extremely poorly.
Because they had managed their fiscal positions extremely poorly, there was an
overhang of debt and widespread concern among the public that further
accumulation of debt or further spending by state governments might well be as
inefficient as some of the spending that had occurred in previous years had
proven to be.
In my view, what happened at that point was that we got both the
wrong prescription and the wrong implementation of the prescription. We got the
wrong prescription in the sense that the conclusion was drawn that what state
governments should do was look like the Commonwealth and essentially have
either a cyclically adjusted budget surplus or aim to run surpluses over the
course of the economic cycle, if not over an even shorter time frame than that.
That is a position that makes sense from the point of view of the Commonwealth,
but in our system of government it is not the right fiscal rule for state
governments, given that those state governments have responsibility for
providing some very long-lived assets.
...
Additionally, we got the wrong implementation of that
prescription, because there were many areas where state governments could have
and should have improved the quality of their outlays, including
infrastructure. The right way to do it would have been to focus on improving
the quality of state government spending–looking at areas such as public
services, where there was doubtless potential to improve efficiency
significantly–making savings to the extent to which they could be made without
compromising service delivery to the public and continuing to fund vital
infrastructure. Instead, what we got, and what emerges quite clearly when you
look at the state government finances over the period, were severe constraints
imposed on funding for the long term and much less severe constraints imposed
on funding that had much more short-term objectives and were much more visible
in the short term. That is understandable; that is the nature of the world in
which governments operate, but it meant that we then entered a period of very
strong economic growth with key players in our system in infrastructure
delivery not having done their bit. That was not the sole factor but it
contributed to the difficulties that we had subsequently.[3]
4.4
Representatives from a number of state opposition parties gave evidence
in relation to debt, often expressing misgivings about its escalation in their
state in recent years.[4]
Views expressed by Dr Bruce Flegg MP, the Queensland Shadow Treasurer were
typical. Dr Flegg said that:
...the issue of government debt is particularly concerning. In the
past two state budgets, we have seen a dramatic escalation of borrowings that
are now forecast to reach over $64 billion by 2011–12. Most of this debt is [GBE]
sector debt, with Queensland’s [GBE] sector having the highest gearing ratio of
any state, at around 70 per cent.
...
...this government has left Queensland’s budget enormously
vulnerable—and I think ‘vulnerable’ is probably the appropriate word to
describe it—particularly as we enter a period of economic uncertainty.[5]
4.5
The level of debt held by states attracted significant comment from
other witnesses. The Australian Industry Group (AiG) commented that:
It is our belief that the borrowing and debt positions of the
Australian states and Territories have been overly conservative for some time.
This has been associated with a significant underinvestment in Australia’s infrastructure.
In recent years...this overly-conservative stance has been wound back and the
states and territories have become more willing to borrow and to make inroads
into the backlog of important projects that has built up over many years.
...
It is difficult to rationalise the excessive focus on reducing
debt. It has little basis in good economic management but seems rather to be
driven by an ideological position.[6]
4.6
Officials from the Treasury submitted that, by historical standards, the
projected level of debt for states in the forward years is relatively low.[7]
4.7
Putting aside the borrowings themselves, the timing of investment in
recent years also bears directly upon the states' management of their finances.
On this point, Mr Henry Ergas observed that:
I believe that what has happened is that the states, which
should have been investing in expanding productive capacity throughout the late
1990s and the early part of this century, stalled that investment. That created
bottlenecks and constraints, and those bottlenecks and constraints added to the
extent of the constraints in the economy as a whole. When those constraints
became both severe and apparent, the states then largely reversed course and at
that point greatly expanded their infrastructure spending—just at a time when
the private sector was also expanding very heavily. If the states had followed
a more steady-as-she-goes course then we would have had less competition for
resources in the period subsequent to 2005. But they did not. As regards the period
from 2005, the problem there is that we have had both this accentuated
competition for resources and, within that, many projects which look like they
are relatively poor quality or where it is very difficult to assess the quality
of those projects. What those projects are doing is displacing private sector
investment, which is being truly market tested. We know that that private
sector investment will in the long run yield real benefits to the community.[8]
4.8
Again, this evidence is expanded on in chapter 6, but the implication is
that state investment was ill-timed. It occurred at a time when the private
sector was also seeking resources for its own projects. It is uncontroversial
to say that this increase in demand boosted the price of the project inputs,
especially skilled labour, and that the final price paid by taxpayers, through
their governments, was higher than it might otherwise have been. Mr Ergas also
warned:
...but even worse to have that stop-go cycle coincide with
overall cyclical movements in the economy, which means that you, as it were,
open the tap to the full just as the economy is going into what looks like a
period of overheating or at least where labour markets and product markets are
very tight. Hence, you accentuate all of the inflationary pressures underway in
the economy. That in my view highlights a serious failure of policy.[9]
4.9
The committee shares the concerns of Mr Ergas that badly planned and
badly managed infrastructure investment, and in the past few years, has put
upward pressure on inflation.
4.10
To address the issue of 'whether the combined spending envelope of both
Commonwealth and the States can be delivered in prevailing economic conditions
without putting at risk the Government's inflation targets',[10]
there does need to be some overall mechanism to ensure that governments'
borrowings and spendings do not negate the Federal Government's economic goals.
4.11
Mr Swan in his Press release, mentions the Australian Loan Council. The
committee considers that it may be appropriate to re-energise the Australian
Loan Council.
Overview of the Australian Loan
Council
4.12
The Loan Council's origins lie in the 1920s when the Commonwealth and
States competed for funds on capital markets. Whilst the Commonwealth wanted to
refinance war debt, the States were interested to fund infrastructure programs.
To resolve this and other disputes, the May 1923 Premiers' Conference agreed to
form a voluntary Loan Council responsible to coordinate the timing of debt
issues and deal with other matters including interest rates on issues of
securities.[11]
4.13
The Loan Council formally came into being in 1927 and the ratified
Financial Agreement was incorporated into the Financial Agreement Act
1928 (the Act). Amongst other things, the Act provided for:
- the Loan Council to regulate borrowing by the Commonwealth and
States;
- the Commonwealth to borrow on the States' behalf;
- limits on the States' borrowing powers;
- the Commonwealth and the States to contribute to the National
Debt Sinking Fund to redeem debt; and
- the Commonwealth to provide grants to the States to help them
meet interest payments and Sinking Fund contributions.[12]
4.14
In the 1950s, a major change to the role of the Loan Council took place
given that the Commonwealth increasingly viewed it as an instrument of macroeconomic
policy. The Commonwealth Treasurer advocated a reduction of Council-approved
borrowing to ease strong inflationary pressures. The Commonwealth's influence
over the Loan Council was strengthened given that the Commonwealth undertook to
provide funds to the States if the States were unable to raise, through the
issue of securities, any borrowing that the Loan Council had approved. In
effect, 'the Commonwealth agreed to underwrite State borrowing'.[13]
4.15
Mr Geoffrey Anderson appearing before the committee in a private
capacity made note of the role of the Loan Council in the 1970s and 1980s:
The deregulation of world financial markets in the mid-1970s to
the 1980s and the pressure on state governments to borrow money to fund an
early infrastructure boom, coupled with the rapid deregulation of the
Australian financial system following the floating of the dollar in 1983, put
great strain on the agreements which had governed the level of borrowing by
both the Commonwealth on behalf of the states, through the Loan Council, and
borrowing by the states’ own authorities. All this was happening at a time when
the Commonwealth was attempting to significantly reduce the overall public
sector borrowing requirement. I should add there is an interesting academic
debate about whether that was a good idea but the fact is that at that time
there was enormous pressure from the Hawke and Keating governments to reduce
government borrowing.
It is fair to say that most of those arrangements were failing,
particularly the so-called global limits where the states agreed to limit their
borrowings to a global limit. States were borrowing and conducting transactions
which effectively amounted to borrowing outside of the Loan Council. Slowly, by
the mid-1990s those agreements had been replaced by a system in which the
states were responsible for their total borrowing within financial markets,
which was specifically designed to increase the market scrutiny on the fiscal
and debt management of the individual states.[14]
4.16
In response to such trends which undermined the Loan Council's
effectiveness, new arrangements were adopted for monitoring and reporting in
the early 1990s. These arrangements provided for each jurisdiction to nominate
a Loan Council Allocation, based on its net borrowing as indicated by its
deficit/surplus.[15]
Of the agreement, Mr Anderson explains:
The 1992 meeting of the Loan Council also agreed to amend the
Financial Agreement to permit the states to issue securities in their own name
in both domestic and overseas markets and to remove the requirement that
borrowings needed to be approved under the provisions of that agreement.
Taken together, these changes completed the process which had
been underway for more than a decade, of moving the control of government
borrowing back into the market, and this establishing a new relationship
between the public sector and the markets. As the Commonwealth budget papers
described the process: “The changes in Loan Council arrangements broadly
reflect the evolving nature of financial markets and their interaction with the
public sector. The new arrangements are designed to enhance the role of
financial market scrutiny as a discipline on the public sector and, in doing
so, build on the changes instituted in the 1980s to enable the individual
states to assume responsibility for managing their own borrowings and to be
accountable to financial markets for their actions”.[16]
4.17
The impact of these changes was that borrowing by the individual States
was now much more subject to financial market scrutiny, a mechanism designed to
impose the financial discipline upon them which previously had been the
province of the Loan Council.[17]
4.18
As of 1 July 1995, the Loan Council operated under the Financial
Agreement between the Commonwealth, States and Territories which is
incorporated as a schedule to the Financial Agreement Act 1994. The
Financial Agreement incorporates changes agreed in 1992 which:
- remove the requirement for Commonwealth and State borrowings to
be approved under the Agreement;
- remove the Commonwealth's explicit power to borrow on the States'
behalf;
- abolishes the restriction on State's borrowing through the issue
of securities in their own name; and
- includes the Australian Capital Territory and Northern Territory
as members.[18]
4.19
Mr Anderson explains the ramifications of these changes:
As a consequence the borrowing arrangements of the Federation
had become as “deregulated” as the nation’s financial system had during the
1980s, with the States active players in domestic and global financial markets.
But while borrowing arrangements were deregulated they were not “unregulated”.
Rather than being governed by constitutional provision, legislative scheme or
political agreement they were now being regulated by the financial markets and
in particular by an agent of the markets in the form of international credit
ratings agencies.[19]
The contemporary role of the
Australian Loan Council
4.20
The Loan Council which is formally a Commonwealth-State Ministerial
council comprising Commonwealth, state and territory treasurers meets once a
year to consider the nominations having regard to each jurisdiction's fiscal
position.
4.21
Of the current status of the Loan Council, Mr Anderson stated:
In recent years, the pressure to renew infrastructure and
provide new infrastructure for economic development has seen the pressure for
zero debt or near zero debt to modify. Increasingly, the rating agencies have
been at pains to point out that they do not necessarily follow an approach of
no debt whatsoever. I think we saw that in New South Wales and Victoria last
year, when both states announced major capital programs and the rating agencies
came out broadly in support of that capital expenditure. They made the point in
both cases that their overall financial position could support greater
borrowings. Of course, the Loan Council has not totally vacated the field:
states have to agree among themselves at the Loan Council for their allocation
of the amount they are going to borrow, which is a methodology that now takes
account of transactions that are not strictly debt but nevertheless have
implications for the amount of risk states take on. In short, they look at the
overall financial requirements of the states rather than their formal
borrowing.[20]
4.22
The role of the Loan Council is now primarily that of monitoring and
approving the loan programs of the Commonwealth and the States. Since the new
financial agreement in 1995 between Federal and State governments, the Loan
Council's borrowing constraints have essentially been voluntary. Indeed, it has
been 15 years since the Loan Council has amended any borrowing proposals of the
States.[21]
4.23
Nevertheless, the current Loan Council arrangements are still used as a
tool of macroeconomic policy. The overall level of conventional borrowings and
other financing arrangements proposed by the Commonwealth and the States is
still assessed for consistency with Commonwealth macroeconomic objectives.
4.24
In relation to a possible alarm trigger mechanism in relation to state
debt levels, Mr Derek Bazen, an Analyst at the Department of the Treasury
informed the committee:
...whilst the role of the Australian Loan Council has changed, the
Australian Loan Council do still meet following the Ministerial Council on
Federal Financial Relations, and they consider the aggregate borrowing
requirements of all Australian governments. I would anticipate that, should
there be borrowings at levels that are ringing those sorts of alarms, that
would be the forum at which those issues would be raised and dealt with.[22]
4.25
Given the scope for the Australian Loan Council to provide a greater
oversight of state borrowing, the committee makes a recommendation
(Recommendation 10) in chapter 8 to investigate mechanisms to enhance and
strengthen the powers of the Australian Loan Council to scrutinise excessive
growth in state debt.
Interest
4.26
The costs of borrowing have escalated along with the level of state debt
in recent years. An estimate of state interest payments as a percentage of Gross
State Product (GSP)/GDP for the General Government Sector, the Public
Non-financial Corporations sector and the Non-financial Public sector, each
show an upward trend of the level of state borrowing over the forward estimates
as states fund their infrastructure programs. However, these payments remain a
small percentage of the states' GSP.[23]
A year on year breakdown for the period 2000–01 to 2010–11, compiled from state
data, is presented in Tables 4.1, 4.2 and 4.3 below.
Table 4.1—General government sector borrowing as a
percentage of GSP/GDP, 2000–01 to 2010–11
Source:
Commonwealth Treasury, Supplementary Submission, p. 5.
4.27
The level of borrowing for the state PNFC sector is perhaps more
relevant, because this sector owns nearly all of the stock of state public debt
(see Table 4.2 below).
Table 4.2—Public non-financial corporations borrowing as
a percentage of GSP/GDP, 2000–01 to 2010–11
Source:
Commonwealth Treasury, Supplementary Submission, p. 6.
4.28
Combining the borrowings of these two sectors of government yields the
Non‑financial Public Sector figures, which represent the overall presented
in Table 4.3.
Table 4.3—Non-financial public sector borrowing as a
percentage of GSP/GDP, 2000–01 to 2010–11
Source:
Commonwealth Treasury, Supplementary Submission, p. 7.
Public sector wages
4.29
The committee notes the disparity between the Commonwealth and state
governments on public sector wages. For example during the June quater 2007 the
Commonwealth spent $3.8 billion compared to $17.8 billion in spending by the
states.[24]
4.30
During the course of its hearings, the committee heard significant
evidence on the growth in state government spending on their public service. Mr
Henry Ergas submitted that the 'poor performance' of state and territory
governments in part reflected a failure to contain public sector wage costs.[25]
During the period September 1997 to March 2008, increases in the Labour
Price Index (LPI)[26]
for the public sector in many states and territories substantially exceeded
those for the private sector. Over the same period, the LPI for the
Commonwealth public sector closely tracked that of the private sector as a
whole. Most noteworthy among the states was New South Wales where government
wage growth exceeded that in the private sector by over 14 percentage points.
Table 4.4 sets out the relative levels of wages growth between public and
private sectors over time.
Table 4.4—Growth in Labour Price Index, September 1997 to
March 2008
Jurisdiction |
Public Sector
(per cent increase) |
Private Sector
(per cent increase) |
NSW |
56.8 |
42.3 |
Victoria |
43.1 |
43.0 |
Queensland |
49.7 |
43.3 |
SA |
52.0 |
43.0 |
WA |
44.1 |
49.4 |
Tasmania |
47.3 |
39.7 |
ACT |
49.4 |
42.6 |
NT |
43.9 |
40.4 |
Commonwealth |
45.6 |
43.3 |
Source: Mr Henry Ergas, Submission
42, p. 6. Drawn from ABS, decomposing data published in ABS Cat 6345.0
Labour Price Index.
4.31
The committee acknowledges the warning it received from Dr Tony Richards,
representing the Reserve Bank of Australia, in relation to the LPI:
I note that the wages price index is just one measure of wages
growth in the economy and it is not as broad as some other measures. The
broader measures which are more likely to capture bonuses et cetera are more
likely to be paid in the private sector. It may be that the wage price index is
not a perfect measure of the entire payments for labour in the public and private
sectors.[27]
4.32
Nonetheless, the committee accepts that the LPI is indicative of
relative trends of the labour price movements between sectors. Mr Ergas added
detail to his explanation when he spoke of the factors feeding the growth:
It is always very difficult to say, but when you look at it
there are a few components. One is that the composition of employment in state
governments changed. That change in the composition of employment, with a
reduction in the number of essentially unskilled and a relative growth in more
skilled types of employment contributed to a growth in labour costs. At the
same time, there was some shift within the public sector in the types of
positions or areas and occupations which were growing, and that too made a
contribution. But, finally, in a number of cases there did appear to be wage
growth which was, when compared to the private sector, relatively generous.[28]
4.33
Mr Ergas also expressed doubt about whether the increases in public
sector wages have been sufficiently underpinned by increased productivity:
The difficulty also is that, in the private sector, there has
been a closer link between increases in labour costs—or, rather, increases in
remuneration—and increases in productivity. Of course, part of the problem in
the public sector is that it is very difficult to measure productivity, so we
do not know how close that relationship has been. But, if we look at outputs,
we do not see outputs or outcomes increasing particularly rapidly. That is
certainly not dispositive of the question but suggests that there may be real
issues there about whether those increases have been justified by increases in
the productivity with which services are being provided.[29]
4.34
It would seem that substantially increased hospital waiting lists,
worsening school performance are instances where increased wages costs have not
increased productivity. The Australian Institute of Health and Welfare reported
that last year, just 70 per cent of public hospital visits and just 65 per
cent of urgent visits were seen on time.[30]
Yet in several states and territories there are more health bureaucrats than
hospital beds.[31]
4.35
According to the Ministerial Council on Employment, Education and
Youth Affairs, between 2002 and 2005 (the four most recent years in which
statistics are available), the percentage of Year 5 children who received
benchmark results in reading and writing had declined overall and declined in
the majority of States and Territories.[32]
4.36
Yet in 2006–07, whilst the Australian Government increased funding by
11 per cent, the State and Territory Governments increased funding to
schools by just 5 per cent – less than half of what was provided by the
Commonwealth.[33]
4.37
Evidence from Dr Steve Thomas MLA, Shadow Treasurer for Western
Australia, added weight to Mr Ergas' doubts:
...of the additional public servants that are now employed, only a
small proportion of those are frontline public servants and there is a
significant rise of backroom Public Service operators. It is interesting that,
when you see an economy booming, it is a bit like Murphy’s Law: the amount of work
for social workers effectively expands to fill the number of social workers you
have got, and the same applies in relation to the general government sector. If
the money is there, the departments are spending it and there is significant
wastage in relation to additional public servants.
If you look at the advertising budgets, for example, they are
rising constantly. If you look at the number of people sitting in offices that
are providing policy direction, for example, they are expanding daily, and the
number of public servants who are fulfilling roles that are not front-line public
servants is increasing. There has been an increase in police, an increase in
nurses and an increase in teachers, and they are all very welcome, but at the
same time there has been a fourfold increase on top of that of everybody else...[34]
4.38
Shadow Finance Minister for New South Wales, Mr Mike Baird MP told the
committee of the situation in his home state:
In relation to some of the [public sector] expense rises we have
seen—and the total expenses have gone from $36 billion to $45 billion—the
employee expenses have gone up at the highest rate, from $18 billion to almost
$23 billion. The important point there is that those rises have grown at a
much faster rate than the private sector.[35]
4.39
The situation was mirrored in Victoria, where Mr Kim Wells MP, Victorian
Shadow Treasurer submitted that:
The number of public servants has grown significantly from what
it was in 1999. The Victorian Public Service wages bill is now $12.2 billion.
It is my understanding that, from 1999 to 2008, the Victorian Public Service
has increased by between 64 000 and 65 000. We accept that there has been an
increase of police of 1400 and an increase of teachers and nurses of between
5000 and 6000, and we understand that there has been an increase in public
health allied workers. But I am unsure of the allocation of employment in other
sectors of the Victorian Public Service.[36]
4.40
In an attachment to his submission, Dr Flegg observed that labour costs
taken together with other public service operating expenses in Queensland
painted an even more dramatic picture. Total expenses grew by 10 per cent in
2004–05; 13 per cent in 2005–06; and 12 per cent in 2006–07. This spending
represented an increase on forecast estimates of 3.4 per cent, 5 per cent and 4
per cent respectively over the same years.[37]
4.41
Mr Mike Blake, the Auditor-General of Tasmania, made an obvious point
but one worth noting:
I highlighted that the numbers of FTE [full-time equivalent employees]
are growing and the salary costs are growing. I think there are good reasons
why the money is being spent primarily in the education and health sectors and
that has been well documented in this state. All I am trying to highlight is
that, if that trend continues and your expenditure growth is higher than your
revenue growth, at some point you hit a negative situation.[38]
4.42
According to ABS data on Wage and Salary Earners in the Public Sector in
Australia 2007:
- Between 1996 and 2007 the number of public sector employees in
the Australian government deceased by 121 700. Over the same time public sector
employees at state level increased by 210 700.
- Between 1996 and 2007 the amount spent by the Commonwealth Government
on wages increased by 12 per cent. At the same time the state government wages
bill increased by 95 per cent.[39]
Unfunded superannuation
4.43
It is partly through the exclusion of superannuation liabilities from
their calculations that some state governments are able to claim they hold no
'net debt' (ND), or even enjoy 'negative net debt'. As explained in chapter 3,
ND often does not include liabilities which could be subject to significant actuarial
recalculation.
4.44
Nonetheless, not all jurisdictions report single ND figures, making
comparisons between states less straightforward. For example, the Australian Capital Territory
(ACT) provides two ND calculations—one including superannuation, the other without.
The reason for different reporting in the ACT is the establishment of a
Superannuation Provision Account in which assets are placed for the purposes of
meeting future superannuation liabilities. These funds cannot be used for any
other purpose. Other jurisdictions report either a 'superannuation liability'
or an 'unfunded superannuation liability'. The details on how assets and
liabilities are held for the purposes of superannuation, compared to general
operations, are widely dispersed across budget papers. There is little detail
on what is counted or not counted for these definitions.
4.45
The Parliamentary Library compiled Table 4.5 to give the committee a
broad picture of superannuation liabilities across the jurisdictions, using
figures from the state budget paper balance sheet.
Table 4.5—Superannuation liabilities of the states and
territories, 2007–08 to 2011–12
|
|
2007-08 |
2008-09 |
2009-10 |
2010-11 |
2011-12 |
|
Notes |
|
|
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
|
|
NSW |
17
126 |
17
389 |
19
921 |
20
016 |
20
024 |
|
a,
c |
QLD |
20
849 |
21
874 |
22
816 |
23
674 |
24
442 |
|
a |
ACT |
3
248 |
3
723 |
3
997 |
4
278 |
4
563 |
|
a |
NT |
2
303 |
2
371 |
2
430 |
2
479 |
2
519 |
|
a |
SA |
|
6
910 |
6
992 |
7
062 |
7
120 |
7
164 |
|
b,
d |
TAS |
3
675 |
3
886 |
3
994 |
4
094 |
4
185 |
|
a |
VIC |
12
939 |
13
067 |
13
101 |
13
156 |
13
159 |
|
a,
e |
WA |
5
366 |
5
170 |
5
088 |
4
972 |
4
860 |
|
b |
Total |
72
417 |
74
473 |
78
408 |
79
790 |
80
915 |
|
|
Source: state and territory budget papers 2008–09.[40]
4.46
When these liabilities are incorporated into state ND figures,[41]
the 'before and after' comparison can be dramatic, as demonstrated in Table 4.6.
Table 4.6—Comparison of Net Debt incorporating
superannuation liabilities and published Net Debt, 2007–08 to 2011–12
|
Net debt incorporating superannuation |
|
Net debt as published |
|
2007-08 |
2008-09 |
2009-10 |
2010-11 |
2011-12 |
|
2007-08 |
2008-09 |
2009-10 |
2010-11 |
2011-12 |
|
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
|
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
$m |
NSW |
22 104 |
23 580 |
26 843 |
27 483 |
27 833 |
|
4 978 |
6 191 |
6 922 |
7 467 |
7 809 |
QLD |
- 3 522 |
- 53 |
4 145 |
8 113 |
11 216 |
|
- 24 371 |
- 21 927 |
- 18 671 |
- 15 561 |
- 13 226 |
ACT |
304 |
488 |
475 |
322 |
141 |
|
- 2 945 |
- 3 235 |
- 3 522 |
- 3 956 |
- 4 421 |
NT |
3 385 |
3 417 |
3 426 |
3 409 |
3 367 |
|
1 082 |
1 045 |
996 |
929 |
848 |
SA |
6 992 |
7 602 |
8 216 |
8 797 |
9 146 |
|
82 |
610 |
1 154 |
1 677 |
1 982 |
TAS |
3 219 |
2 763 |
2 731 |
2 697 |
2 520 |
|
- 456 |
- 1 123 |
- 1 263 |
- 1 397 |
- 1 665 |
VIC |
15 210 |
16 806 |
18 458 |
20 060 |
22 623 |
|
2 271 |
3 739 |
5 357 |
6 904 |
9 465 |
WA |
2 486 |
2 509 |
1 994 |
1 721 |
2 906 |
|
- 2 968 |
- 2 749 |
- 3 182 |
- 3 339 |
- 2 042 |
Total |
50 178 |
57 112 |
66 288 |
72 602 |
79 752 |
|
- 22 328 |
- 17 448 |
- 12 208 |
- 7 275 |
- 1 251 |
Source: state and territory
budget papers 2008–09.[42]
4.47
Plotted as an aggregate of all states and territories, the ND liability
with and without superannuation is portrayed in Figure 4.6.
Figure 4.1—Comparison of published Net Debt and Net Debt
incorporating superannuation liabilities, 2007–08 to 2011–12
Source: state and territory
budget papers 2008–09.
4.48
Figure 4.1 demonstrates that, in 2008–09, for example, the ND position
of minus $17.4 billion (a surplus) reverses to a net debt position of
$57.1 billion, a difference of $74.5 billion.
4.49
To take the Northern Territory example, while General Government Sector
ND at 30 June 2008 is published at $1.082 billion, the committee heard that an
extra $2.3 billion is owed in the form of superannuation liabilities.[43]
In the 2002–03 Northern Territory Budget Paper No II, superannuation liability
was projected to grow to $1.45 billion by 2005–06. The final results for 2005–06
disclosed a figure of $1.8 billion, and in 2007–08, $2.3 billion.[44]
4.50
The Tasmanian Auditor-General told the committee that the superannuation
liability in Tasmania was $3.6 billion, and that the state's reported ND did
not include the liability.[45]
4.51
In New South Wales, Mr Baird alleged that the government had
inaccurately minimised the state's superannuation liability, explaining that:
[mis-forecasting] significantly depresses the unfunded super
obligations of the state going forward, which then creates the position that
you do not need to contribute as much from an ongoing state budget. They
changed the ageing population assumptions, against national trends, and the
impact of that was almost $3 billion in the estimate period. In terms of the
forward estimate, their estimation of unfunded super obligations was $12
billion; using the old accounting standards it was $17 billion. So there is a
huge requirement, which depresses it. It is a good example of the need for
transparency.[46]
4.52
Dr Flegg reported on a similar situation in Queensland:
We have seen in Queensland what would, if it were in the private
sector, be called creative accounting. For years, certainly since the last
downturn following the GST, we have seen the state government bring some
$22 billion worth of superannuation assets, positioned on the balance
sheet, and the investment returns from that, which have been up to a maximum of
21 per cent, going straight to the bottom line as though they were tax
receipts. That money is not available for any general government purpose; it
belongs to the superannuants in the public sector. To my mind, that is
misleading accounting. But now markets have changed, returns are negative. They
are certainly below the long-term average and, in the recent past, have
actually been negative. So they have introduced a different system.[47]
4.53
It is interesting to note that the South Australian Government is
reported in the Adelaide Advertiser of 1 September 2008 as having to fund an additional $120 million for superannuation costs as a result of the
international financial crisis.[48]
Forecasting
4.54
In addition to evidence of 'creative accounting', the committee heard
evidence of a growing tendency by a number of state and territory governments
to under-estimate revenue in their forward estimates. Mr Terry Mills MLA,
Leader of the Opposition in the Northern Territory, submitted that:
...[T]he Territory has repeatedly and substantially underestimated
its revenue outcomes. In Budget Paper II for the year 2004–05 the projected
income for the year 2007–08 was $2.77 billion, compared with the $3.49 billion
of the 2007–08 mid-year report.[49]
4.55
The New South Wales Shadow Treasurer submitted that in his state:
Two continuing trends in the mis-forecasts are the windfall tax
revenues and the continuing blowouts in expenses above budget targets. The
2006–07 expenses increase target of 5.7 per cent blew out to 5.9 per cent and
the 2007–08 target of 3.6 per cent has already blown out to 6.8 per cent.[50]
4.56
The Property Council of Australia submitted that, of the 56 state and
territory budgets handed down since the introduction of the GST, subsequent
property tax revenues were underestimated 91 per cent of the time.[51]
4.57
The committee was told of a number of instances of wages and other
spending being mis-forecast. In 2005, employee expenses in the Northern
Territory exceeded estimates by $120 million, or 12 per cent.[52]
4.58
While the committee can understand the desire to exercise caution in
forecasting, the consistency and extent of under-forecasting revenue appears
excessive. The committee makes the point that deliberately engaging in this
practice misleads the public in exactly the same way as under-forecasting a
deficit or debt result. Insofar as this detracts from the public having an
accurate picture of the financial position of their state, it is equally as
serious. The committee makes a recommendation (Recommendation 2) about
improving state financial forecasting in chapter 8.
Income from the Commonwealth
4.59
Consistent with the relatively high level of Vertical Fiscal Imbalance
discussed in chapter 2, Treasury submitted that total Commonwealth funding payments
to the states for 2007–08, comprising GST revenue, general revenue assistance
and Special Purpose Payments (SPPs) is expected to be $73.1 billion.[53]
4.60
The states will receive GST revenue of $42.2 billion in 2007–08, an increase
of 6.8 per cent from 2006–07. This is expected to be $3.4 billion more revenue
in 2007–08 than they would have received had the GST not been in place. These
outcomes represent significant tax windfalls for the states over and above what
they were forecast to receive at the introduction of the GST in 2000. Revenue
from the GST comprises about 60 per cent of revenue received by states from the
Commonwealth.[54]
4.61
Commonwealth SPPs totalling $30.3 billion were made in 2007–08, and SPPs
should increase slightly to $30.9 billion in 2008–09. Of these, the
Commonwealth provided $22.6 billion 'to' states and $7.6 billion in payments
'through' the states to local government in 2007–08. In 2008–09, SPPs 'to' the
states are estimated to be $22.8 billion and payments 'through’ the states to
be $8.1 billion.
4.62
Between 1997–98 and 2005–06, the Commonwealth provided $4.9 billion in
National Competition Policy payments to the states for implementing
National Competition Policy and related reforms.
4.63
The annual amounts for each of these Commonwealth funded revenue sources
are detailed in Table 4.7 for the period 2000–01 to 2010–11.
Table 4.7—Total Commonwealth
funding, 2000–01 to 2010–11
Source: Mid-year
economic and fiscal outlook 2007–08 estimates, Commonwealth Treasury, Submission
25, p. 9.
State government taxes
4.64
State government taxation proceeds constitute a significant proportion
of their total revenue. In New South Wales, revenue from taxation in 2008–09 is
forecast to be 38.7 per cent of total revenue,[55]
while the Queensland Government expects to raise 27.6 per cent of its revenue
from tax in the same period.[56]
In states relying more heavily on assistance from the Commonwealth, the figure
is lower; in 2006–07 Tasmania derived 20 per cent of its income through
taxation.[57]
4.65
The sentiment of many submitters to the inquiry regarding state and
territory taxation was summarised by the Real Estate Institute of Australia,
which contended that:
An ongoing lack of financial autonomy results in states and territories
clinging to taxation regimes which are known to be distortionary and
inefficient. While significant progress was made as a result of the implementation
of the intergovernmental agreement underpinning the introduction of the GST, a raft
of relatively inefficient state and territory taxes remain in place, with
little prospect of removal in the absence of alternative revenue sources. These
taxes include stamp duties on property conveyancing, land tax and payroll tax.[58]
4.66
Mr John Nicolaou, representing the West Australian Chamber of Commerce
and Industry, made his organisation's purpose clear:
What we are here to see is a more competitive tax regime. That
is the central message that we have been trying to articulate for some time
now. On a per capita basis, Western Australia is clearly the most uncompetitive
state. In relation to tax as a percentage of the total economy, which Treasury
now use as their benchmark, we do rank middle-of-the road, but that percentage
is increasing, so we are moving up in terms of overall tax burden. The
Commonwealth Grants Commission use a tax effort ratio and we rank as the
highest taxing state.
...
Payroll tax is not a big business issue and it is a furphy to
suggest that it is. It is a small business issue and it is having an impact at
the margin on small businesses that are struggling to meet increased costs.[59]
4.67
The Property Council submission argued that states and territories have
relied too heavily on property taxes in recent history. In calling for the
elimination of stamp duty on commercial conveyances and indirect property
taxes, the Property Council informed the committee that, since the introduction
of the GST, $11.6 billion has been collected through property taxes over and
above the amount anticipated. Land tax and conveyancing duty revenue are
growing at more than double the average rate of all other state taxes combined.[60]
The Property Council calculated that land taxes make up 37 per cent of all
state and territory taxation revenue.[61]
4.68
Nor were industry groups the only witnesses to draw attention to these
concerns. Victorian Shadow Treasurer, Mr Kim Wells MP had this to say:
I am very concerned about the reliance of the state budget on
property taxes. I think the reliance on land tax and stamp duty was in the high
teens in the late nineties; now the percentage is in the very high 30s. With
increased interest rates, petrol prices, the CPI moving and pressure from
overseas markets, my concern is that, if the property market is hit and there
is a slight downturn, there is going to be a significant impact on the Victorian
budget because of its heavy reliance on property taxes.[62]
4.69
The warnings of Mr Wells about over-reliance on stamp duty in the property
boom were prescient. The Adelaide Advertiser of 1 September 2008 reports a reduction in that state government's revenue of $30 million because of a downturn
in the property market.[63]
4.70
The negative impact of state taxes such as conveyance duties was not
lost on the committee. A report on state taxation reform by Mr Robert Carling
found that stamp duty on property conveyance:
...distorts choices between buying and renting and between moving
house and staying put or renovating. It tends to lock householders into
sub-optimal housing and militates against resource mobility. Marginal
deadweight costs have increased over the years as a rising proportion of
transactions have become subject to the upper levels of the progressive scales.[64]
4.71
Another primary focus for criticism was payroll tax, the abolition of
which a number of witnesses called for.[65]
Mr Behrens, State Manager of Commerce Queensland, explored the common
objections to the tax:
Payroll tax is the absolute standout, and the interesting thing
is that, from our own surveys, it is identified by the entire business
community as the tax that they would like to see removed. It is interesting
because 95 per cent of Queensland businesses do not pay payroll tax, yet they
are citing payroll tax as a major concern. We were very curious as to why, so
we explored it and we came up with three reasons. The first one is that,
ultimately, they are a small business and they aspire to grow, so eventually
they may pay payroll tax. The second one is that they do receive some of the
indirect windfall or benefit of the tax cut in that big business does do
business with smaller sized enterprises, who receive some indirect benefit. The
third one is a principle—that ultimately it is a tax on economic growth and it
is a tax on employment. So they have this principle that it should be removed.[66]
4.72
Other witnesses called for payroll tax rates and thresholds in their state
to be modified, primarily for reasons of inter-state competition. Mr Kim Wells
MP, Shadow Treasurer in Victoria, remarked that:
To the government’s credit, they have cut payroll tax from five
per cent to 4.95 per cent, so it is under the five per cent range—and it has
not been that way for some time. But the problem is that the threshold of
$550,000 has not changed. So, as small businesses pay their employees pay
increases, more and more small businesses will be caught up in the payroll tax
net... more small businesses are paying payroll tax. A small business in this
state is a business that has 20 or less. So 20 or less means that obviously
more and more small businesses are paying payroll tax. The issue is that we
welcome the cut of the rate, but the threshold has not been adjusted, and that
is where they are getting more. In fact, despite the cut, with payroll tax they
will collect an extra $200 million from businesses in Victoria.[67]
4.73
Mr Mike Baird MP echoed this call:
We did see a reduction in payroll tax in the last state budget.
We went from six per cent down to 5.75 per cent, and the closest state is Victoria
at 4.95 per cent. So we are still a long way from parity in relation to payroll
tax. Again, I think that is something you need to look at federally. There
needs to be harmonisation. A company operating across Australia will see huge
differences in relation to payroll tax rates and thresholds. It is the most
inefficient system we have spoken about.[68]
State income tax
4.74
At various stages during the inquiry, particularly in discussions about
Vertical Fiscal Imbalance, the prospect of states levying their own income tax
was raised. Realistically, this would likely require the Commonwealth to 'make
room' for the states by lowering personal income tax rates. In 1978, the Fraser
Government legislated to allow the states to impose an income tax surcharge in
order for the states to broaden their own-source tax base. The initiative
failed partly because the Commonwealth did not cut tax rates to make room for surcharges.[69]
4.75
As discussed in chapter 2, Vertical Fiscal Imbalance reflects the larger
stream of revenue flowing to the Commonwealth relative to the states. The
committee's interest in states levying their own income tax lies with the
prospect of reducing the imbalance and alleviating some of its effect.
4.76
One advantage of states levying a surcharge would be that the cost of
administration would not increase greatly if the base rate was unchanged and
identical across the states, and the Commonwealth administered and collected
the tax. Another possible advantage is that competition among the states would
be likely to put downwards pressure on surcharge rates.
4.77
A state surcharge could, however, face considerable barriers because it
would entail a fundamental change to Commonwealth-state financial arrangements.
That would require the agreement of all jurisdictions which may not be
forthcoming. Indeed, the Deputy Leader of the Opposition in South Australia, Ms
Vicky Chapman, remarked that any government seeking to introduce income tax
might be said to have a 'death wish'.[70]
On the other hand, Dr Steve Thomas, Shadow Treasurer in Western Australia
expressed a personal view that, while it would likely be impossible to manage,
it would be a good idea.[71]
4.78
The Institute of Public Affairs, called for the complete abandonment of
income tax collection by the Australian Government to enable the states to levy
their own. The IPA argued that:
In addition to exiting the provision of social services, health
and education the Commonwealth should give up all its personal income tax
powers. This would enable the states and territories to levy their own personal
income taxes. This would also allow the states and territories to give up the
inefficient transactions taxes that they currently levy. The Commonwealth
should continue to levy the corporate income tax and GST and other excise taxes
that it currently levies and should continue to allocate funds (in excess of
its own requirements) to the states and territories. Using the 2007-08 Budget
papers as a guide this implies that the Commonwealth would give up almost half
(excluding the GST) of the revenue it currently raises. In contrast by exiting
its redistributive functions the commonwealth would reduce its own expenditure
by almost two-thirds. In other words there may still be a large role for the
Commonwealth in allocating funding to the states and territories.[72]
4.79
Professor Sinclair Davidson, Economist with the Institute of Public
Affairs, elaborated on the IPA's submission at the Melbourne hearing:
Our argument is that we should push down some level of taxation.
Within Australia, if we think back to the Australian Constitution and what it
is designed to do, it is effectively designed to create a common market within
the six former colonies and the territories, which basically means that the
Commonwealth or the federal government should be looking after common market
activities. It should be looking after corporates, which it does, and therefore
our argument is that the Commonwealth should retain the corporate income tax
power. But individuals are located within states and therefore the states
should have the personal income tax power.[73]
4.80
While the committee was not in a position to explore in detail the
possibilities of states introducing an income tax levy, the concept has some
obvious appeal. Put simply, it has the potential to significantly reduce or
bring an end to the funding 'blame game' between states and the Commonwealth.
Were states to receive income tax revenue in the same way they receive GST
revenue, they would be forced to manage their own budgets without recourse to
criticising a 'donor' Commonwealth.
4.81
The committee recommends that the Commonwealth Government seriously
consider all aspects of the states accessing income taxation powers at
Recommendation 7.
4.82
Even taken alone, the prospect of reforming the tension between the
Commonwealth and states over funding suggests to the committee that the concept
of state income tax deserves further exploration.
4.83
Another possible advantage is the prospect of encouraging competition
between the states for residents, through the establishment of the most
efficient taxation regime. Far from being mere 'pie in the sky', Professor Davidson
reminded the committee of the situation in Switzerland:
There may actually be some population movement around that, and that
is normally the argument—that there would be a race to the bottom. Yet if we
look at the Swiss, who have a confederation, and their cantons, some of the
richer cantons actually have higher levels of taxation than others and the rich
are not stampeding out of the doors. People actually trade off tax against what
they are getting.[74]
Local government
4.84
The Australian Local Government Association (ALGA) made a number of
points to the committee. Principal among these was that services provided, and
infrastructure owned and operated, by local government is critical to the
efficient operation of the Australian economy, as well as to meeting the social
and other needs of citizens.[75]
This is particularly the case where other levels of government have withdrawn
services from isolated and rural shires.[76]
4.85
To this end, the adequate and efficient funding of local government is
critical. The committee was reminded by the ALGA of the effect cost shifting
between jurisdictions has on local government bottom lines, and on that level
of government's ability to provide services to ratepayers.[77]
4.86
The ALGA was confident that a new agreement between local government and
state planning ministers would help avoid cost shifting in the future.[78]
The committee is pleased to hear that progress is being made to reduce cost
shifting, an inherently inefficient practice that helps nobody in the longer
term. This is referred to in Recommendation 6 which appears in chapter 8.
4.87
The Commonwealth Grants Commission have indicated that states have
recently stepped up the practice of shifting costs onto local councils. One
example is the reduction in funding for libraries, forcing councils to assume
extra responsibility, rather than having those services withdrawn from their
communities.[79]
4.88
The House of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics, Finance
and Public Administration noted in its 2003 Rates and Taxes report that:
There is no doubt that local government has, over a number of
years, been on the wrong end of cost shifting largely by State governments. The
Commonwealth Grants Commission has recorded that over the last 25 years the
Federal government has, in real terms, progressively increased its contribution
to local government while State contributions have not grown.[80]
4.89
The committee also heard evidence of a lack of transparency on the part
of state governments in the provision of funding to local councils. This was of
particular interest to the committee, because much of the funding in question
originates from the Commonwealth. The ALGA submitted that:
Currently, the Commonwealth provides generals-purpose funding to
local government via the States [Financial Assistance Grants], which then
administer the funding following recommendations made to the Commonwealth
Minister by Local Government Grants Commissions established in each State...
[Because funding is] paid initially to the states to distribute to councils,
some states have treated these grants as payments to local government from the state
government. This is misleading and in the absence of better accounting
treatment rules and...there is a real risk of double-counting...aggregate fiscal
data for local government provide a misleading picture which overestimates the
states' financial contribution to local government and undermines efforts to
establish a true picture of local governments' financial circumstances.[81]
4.90
Should the ALGA's submission be accurate, and the committee has no
reason to think otherwise, the states are engaging in practices that are at
best sloppy and at worst duplicitous. The committee recommends that the
Government take the opportunity to specifically address the issue of
identification of Commonwealth funding through its planned SPP reform program
at Recommendation 11 in chapter 8.
Conclusion
4.91
During the course of the inquiry, a number of significant financial
management issues were brought to the committee's attention. The committee is
mindful of evidence received from a variety of witnesses that debt, incurred
for the enhancement of productive capacity, is a sign of responsible economic
management. While the committee is heartened by the evidence from some
submitters that debt levels in states and territories are relatively
manageable, it notes that witnesses generally made their assessment based on a
comparison with historic levels.
4.92
Recent revelation by the former NSW Treasurer in his resignation media
conference mirror the alarm of many of the witnesses. In a revealing parting
shot at the State's parlous fiscal position, the Hon Michael Costa said that
Stamp Duty had fallen $180 million in the first 2 months of this financial
year, the Health Budget had blown out by $300 million this year with a $5
billion capital funding shortfall over the next 5 years causing Standard and
Poor's to warn that there was a 1 in 3 chance of NSW loosing its AAA rating
which would in turn raise borrowing costs by over $500 million over the
forward estimates.[82]
4.93
Memories of the irresponsibly high levels of debt incurred by some
states in recent decades should serve as a warning to those seeking to minimise
concern at the rising levels of debt revealed in this report.
4.94
Increases in public sector wage expenditure appear, in some
jurisdictions, to be excessive. The proportion of budget expenditure going to
fund the public sector is significant, meaning that even modest wage increases
can have dramatic affects on the budget bottom line. As well as the obvious
impact wage rises have on inflation, the committee notes the considerable
danger posed by continuing blowouts to states' fiscal health.
4.95
States employ various means of accounting for their superannuation
liabilities. Not all of these are transparent, and the committee encourages the
respective governments to take an honest and transparent approach with their
constituents on what, in some cases, are very large superannuation liabilities
to be met in coming years. The committee takes a similar view on the issue of
inaccurate forecasting. Recommendations contained in chapter 8 seek to address
these matters, as well as those concerning the states' fiscal relationship with
local government, through the adoption by each state of a charter of budget
honesty.
4.96
The committee's overall perspective, in a time of increasing state GST
receipts, combined with increasing non-GST revenue, increasing debt, and
excessive wages growth, was perhaps summarised best by Mr Ergas, who observed
that:
These trends suggest significant scope for improved efficiency in
financial management at the state and territory level. The concern is not
simply with the deterioration in the fiscal position, though this is
significant in terms of macroeconomic policy, given the pro-cyclical nature of
the current deterioration. Rather, further concern arises to the extent that
this deterioration is symptomatic of basic failures of governance at the state
and territory level, also reflected in their poor management of infrastructure
investment.[83]
4.97
It is to infrastructure, often operated through Government Business
Enterprises, that the committee now turns.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page