GOVERNMENT SENATORS' REPORT
FIRST STAGE OF SELECT COMMITTEE ON A NEW TAX SYSTEM Government
Senators do not necessarily agree with the emphasis placed on some of the information
contained in the body of the Select Committee's report. We therefore have provided
additional evidence contained in this separate report to support our conclusions.
- INTRODUCTION
This Select Committee on A New Tax
System has terms of reference to inquire into the Government's tax reform plans
as set out in the policy document Tax Reform: not a new tax a new tax system
(ANTS). This report covers the first stage of the Senate Inquiry, which
has examined the views of economic modellers, and whether their evidence supports
the case for tax reform. As set out in this report, their economic evidence supports
the Government's position of tax reform providing benefits for Australia. 2.
The Government's tax reform policy ANTS is a comprehensive policy
approach to tax reform which brings together reductions in personal income
taxes totalling $13 billion a year better links between the tax system
and the social welfare to remove poverty traps and increase incentives to work
increased pensions and government allowances the introduction of
a broad-based goods and services tax (GST) to replace wholesale sales tax and
9 other indirect taxes; and a more sustainable approach to Commonwealth-State
financial relations. In establishing the need for tax reform, the Government
identified the problems of Australia's current tax system and set them out in
detail in the Treasurer's 1998 publication `The Australian Taxation System
In Need of Reform' and in ANTS. Without reform, the Commonwealth
will become increasingly reliant on income tax directly levied on individuals
and companies and the tax revenue of the States will become even more inadequate
and more inefficient. The existing taxation system is broken.
The existing taxation system is unfair - average wage earners will be paying
43 cents for every additional dollar in 1999 and 47 cents in the dollar soon
after 2000 - high marginal tax rates punish incentive and encourage minimisation
- the wholesale sales tax system is illogical, out of date and costs jobs
by taxing exports and investment The existing taxation system is complex
- Sales tax is difficult to understand and very costly to administer and
comply with, especially for small business - 7 tax rates 0, 12,
22, 32, 37, 41, 45 lead to absurd classifications - causing business,
the ATO and the Courts to spend large amounts of time and money deciding which
goods fit into the various categories The existing taxation system is
outdated - it was designed and introduced in 1930 and has failed to keep
pace with changes in the economy - now, compared to the 1930s, services
are a larger part of economy so a goods only tax base distorts investment -
complex multiple rates and classifications were introduced as emergency wartime
measure and it was stated at time that this approach would never have been contemplated
in peace time - very few countries still operate a WST Social
security beneficiaries face high effective marginal tax rates, complexity and
unfairness - the current social security system creates poverty traps and
disincentives to work - a family can be worse off by entering the workforce
The sales tax base is shrinking - because WST is a tax on some
goods and no services, it is levied on the shrinking part of the economy because
services have become the increasingly dominant economic activity - WST
revenue has only been maintained through rate increases which accentuates the
division between taxed goods and untaxed services. 3. THE MACROECONOMIC
IMPLICATIONS OF THE GOVERNMENT'S TAX PACKAGE The Government set out
in ANTS why the tax reform package will deliver substantial long-term improvements
in the operation of the economy, to the benefit of all Australians. Improvements
will be reflected in higher economic growth as a result of stronger, more productive,
investment which, together with the lowering of industry costs, will yield better
export outcomes. Such changes will be crucial in relaxing the balance of payments
constraint that has for so long held back Australia's growth performance. The
combination of higher growth and improved work incentives will deliver more jobs
and lower unemployment. Key elements of the package that will drive higher
growth are: - lower effective income tax rates, lifting incentives
to work and save;
- lower, less distorted, industry input costs lifting
export profitability and performance;
- abolition of distorting indirect
taxes;
- a reformed business tax system, lifting capital productivity;
- lower tax compliance costs, freeing highly skilled resources for more
productive
- endeavour; and
- more secure government finances, removing
the need for ad hocery in tax design.
The Committee heard evidence
from the Treasury, the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research
(including evidence concerning distributional effects which is covered later in
this report) and from Mr Geoff Carmody of Access Economics. The Committee also
commissioned its own research from Professor Peter Dixon of the Centre of Policy
Studies at Monash University and Mr Chris Murphy of Econtech. In general
terms, all the economic evidence provided to the Committee supported the Government's
view that the tax package will provide substantial benefits to the economy. Witnesses
provided their assessments of the macroeconomic impacts on measures such as economic
welfare gains, GDP growth, CPI effects and employment based on a combination of
economic theory, models and judgements. The breadth of ANTS, and
the inclusion of measures affecting indirect taxation, direct taxation, government
benefits and the fiscal balance, makes the task of modelling the package extremely
difficult. Before commenting on the results of the private sector modelling it
is instructive to examine the Treasury approach to estimating the macroeconomic
effects of ANTS in the development of the package. In the evidence of Dr
Henry We were interested in the qualitative picture primarily: that is,
is it likely that this particular package will lead to a higher level of gross
domestic product over time than we would otherwise have? Is it likely that this
package would lead to higher employment levels over time than what we would otherwise
have? Those are qualitative questions, and for those questions we were comfortable
with developing a qualitative answer. Our secondary interest was in the
question of what might be the impact on revenue of these sorts of behavioural
effects: that is, if we are comfortable with the idea that gross domestic product
will be higher, what might be the impact on income tax revenue and on GST revenue
of that higher level of gross domestic product? [1]
We reviewed the modelling work that had been done and the sorts of estimates
that people were producing for increases in gross domestic product. We reviewed
all of that quite closely. We then had a discussion about what might be the most
plausible range of estimates, and then we fixed on a number very much at the conservative
end of that plausible range of estimates. [2] The
Treasury approach to assessing the impact of the Government's tax package accords
with the views of Professor Dixon who, in evidence to the Committee on several
occasions, indicated that emphasis should be placed on material underlying modelling
outcomes and not necessarily the outcomes themselves. The Chair paraphrased
Professor Dixon in the following terms
he said "Pay less
attention to the numbers; pay more attention to the arguments as to how we arrived
at these figures. [3] Gross
domestic product All modellers found that the Government's tax package
would increase Australia's output or GDP. Professor Dixon was at the bottom
end of the range with his long term estimate of a 0.2% increase. The Committee
was informed, however by Econtech, who reviewed the MONASH outcomes, that assumptions
in MONASH about the composition of GDP and capital stock "
makes
the Monash estimate of a GDP gain of 0.2 per cent misleadingly low when assessing
the gain in living standards from ANTS using GDP
". [4]
Econtech's estimate of a 1.8% increase in GDP sits closely with the Melbourne
Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research who expect GDP to increase by
1.7% as a result of the tax package. Access Economics forecast a higher
benefit to GDP, stating their view that the tax package will lead to a 2.5% increase
in national output. While the Treasury did not provide a point estimate
to the Committee, they indicated in evidence that cumulative GDP growth of 0.5%
by 2002-03 was implicit in the tables contained in ANTS which set out the fiscal
impacts of the package. This is consistent with the long term outcomes mentioned
above. Export performance All modellers estimated a beneficial
impact on exports. Professor Dixon again provides the lower bound for estimates
of export growth, predicting an increase of 1.0%. The Melbourne Institute of Applied
Economic and Social Research then comes in at a 2% increase. Econtech estimates
a 6% increase. The benefits to exports arise from the removal of taxes
on business inputs and because exports are GST-free. That is, the tax package
lowers the cost of export production. Given that there is a small appreciation
of the exchange rate, these positive export outcomes demonstrate the benefits
to exporters of reducing the cost structure of Australian industry. The
reason for the difference between Monash and Econtech is that Monash have lower
export demand elasticities and a smaller increase in export supply arising from
Monash's smaller capital stock and hence production potential. Consumer
price index In the case of the CPI, Professor Dixon assumed a 2.19%
CPI impact for the purposes of modelling, ie he used an assumption as an input
to his modelling rather than the model producing an estimate for the CPI impact.
As a result, the MONASH model provides no assessment of the inflationary impact.
The increase in the cost of living associated with the introduction of
the tax reform package is estimated by the Treasury to be 1.9 per cent in
2001-02. As set out in ANTS, however, It needs to be noted,
that the 1.9 per cent CPI increase excludes the impact of the tax package
on tobacco prices. This reflects the Government's view that the impact of the
GST on tobacco prices should not, for public health reasons, be offset by income
tax cuts and/or increases in social security payments. The 1.9 per cent CPI takes
account of the new First Home Owners' Scheme's offsetting the impact of the GST
on new house prices. [5] In evidence given to
the Committee, Treasury confirmed that ANTS had referred to a (first year)
2000-01 CPI impact of around 2.5%. Further, the Treasury indicated to the Committee
that the CPI impact in 2002-03 was estimated at 1.8%. The Melbourne Institute
indicated in evidence that their estimate of the CPI impact was
2.44%
after three or four years, and then it will move down further
In the longer
run the price will come down towards the 1.9 per cent. [6]
The Econtech estimate of long term CPI impact is 0.9%. This lower estimate
arises because Econtech incorporates second round saving effects from financing
costs and businesses changing their input mix to take advantage of larger savings.
The debate about whether the CPI impact is an appropriate methodology for
measuring the price impacts of the Government's tax package is raised later in
the report. Economic welfare Economic welfare is a measure
to estimate living standards. In modelling the Government's tax package Professor
Dixon initially estimated a figure of negative $30 million. In his paper of 25
January Professor Dixon described this as
the long run resource
allocation gains flowing from the proposed tax changes will be negligible
[7] In the review of Professor Dixon's
work, Econtech found that the formula used by Monash to calculate the welfare
gain was an approximation only and would likely lead to an under-estimate. Because
of this approximation error, Mr Murphy stated in his review of the Monash work
that
all results for the welfare gain contained in the Monash Report
are under-estimates
From last-minute advice from Monash the understatement
error appears to be about $100 million to $150 million on a Monash Model basis.
[8] It was established in evidence that Econtech's
MM303 model is clearly superior to the Monash model in measuring welfare gains.
Its estimate of the welfare gain as a result of the tax package is $607 million.
Mr Murphy indicated that this result is conservative because "
MM303
allows for only four out of six sources of efficiency gain from ANTS
"
and "
it is
difficult to model the efficiency gains from
abolishing business stamp duties and bank account taxes
" [9].
Employment Monash and Econtech use long term computable general
equilibrium models which assume that employment is held constant in the long run.
Therefore they do not forecast long term employment outcomes. In the case
of the Monash model, it is set up to follow the transitional path of variables
including employment. In the central case modeled by Professor Dixon, "
employment
will be stimulated in the short-run by about 30 000 jobs
" [10]
In research undertaken by the Melbourne Institute, they indicated that
modelling results on the basis of no change in pre-tax real wages, the tax changes
could increase the number of jobs by 50 000 [11]. Access
Economics, in their AEM Model Forecast Report of December 1998 indicate that as
a result of the tax package there is an additional 190 000 jobs created in the
long term, consistent with their view of increased GDP as a result of the tax
package. The Committee also requested some work on the employment effects
if it was assumed that workers bargained for wages ignoring the greater disposable
income they have as a result of the tax cuts. In the Government's view,
there is no case for such increases as wage earners will be more than fully compensated
for consumption price increases by income tax cuts and increases in government
benefits their real take home pay will actually rise. In a continuing low
inflation environment and given the enhanced credibility of monetary policy flowing
from the Reserve Bank's independence, the Government considers it will be able
to continue a policy framework that will accommodate some or all (depending on
the circumstances at the time) of the small one-off increase in consumer prices
but not to permit further flow through. Against this background, and the
improved cost structures inherent in the package, the introduction of a GST is
unlikely to lead to an increase in inflationary expectations and on-going inflation.
This assessment is supported by international experience. Econtech
in its report of 14 February 1999 said "The chances of ANTS producing
a wages blowout are remote. This assessment takes into account the generally favourable
experience of other countries in introducing this type of tax reform, and that
Australia has the advantage of having available a Budget surplus that is used
to boost income tax cuts to over-compensate workers for the CPI effect of ANTS."
[12] Fiscal effects The
tax reform package has been designed to be consistent with the Government's medium-term
fiscal strategy. The package will be implemented progressively from 1999-00
and will reduce the size of the Commonwealth surplus projected for that year and
subsequent years. The package has a significant fiscal cost (somewhat less than
one per cent of GDP annually) but will bring substantial benefits to the operation
of the economy and to the sustainability of both Commonwealth and State government
finances. Reflecting the considerable improvements in Government fiscal policy
in recent years, the tax package can be accommodated while retaining sizeable
Budget surpluses as required by the fiscal strategy. The budgetary position
of the States will, over time, be enhanced considerably by the package. After
a transitional period in which the Commonwealth has committed that the States
will be no worse off in budgetary terms, the States will be in a much stronger
position, reflecting that GST revenue will grow at an appreciably stronger rate
than the Commonwealth grants and State taxes that it is replacing. The Treasury
predictions show that State Governments should benefit by $370 million in 2003/4
and by $1.25 billion in 2004/5. A fundamental objective of this package
is to halt the erosion of indirect tax revenue base. The tax mix in the
Australian economy has been moving over the past decade towards a higher share
of direct taxation and a lower share of indirect taxation. For example, in 1987-88,
indirect tax represented 6.9per cent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) compared
with 5.6 per cent in 1997-98. The direct taxation of individuals and
companies increased from 16.9 per cent of GDP to 17.5 per cent
over the same period. As revenue from indirect taxes has declined, more
of the burden has had to be carried by taxes on income; principally by wage and
salary earners. The share of indirect tax as a proportion of total revenue to
the Commonwealth Budget has fallen from 26.3 per cent in 1987-88 to
22.8 per cent in 1997-98, while the share of income tax revenue has
risen from 64.0 per cent to 71.9 per cent over the same period.
Without comprehensive tax reform, the tax mix will continue to shift automatically
towards a greater reliance on direct taxation. Those who can afford expert advice
or who (because of the size of their income) have more options open to them to
minimise their direct tax will continue to have an advantage over those Australians
who cannot afford such advice or do not have tax minimisation options available
to them. In short, under the current tax system, ordinary Australian wage
and salary earners will carry an ever greater share of the tax burden. It
is interesting to examine the comments of the then Treasurer on the 1993-94 Budget
measures to increase wholesale sales tax rates. In his Budget Speech, he said
that `(t)hey will halt the erosion of Commonwealth indirect tax revenue thus preventing
Australia's tax system becoming lopsided
Failure to act on the indirect tax
side would create pressures for more weight on income tax, a weight which would
fall most heavily on middle-income earners'. The revenue erosion is once
more evident, with the indirect tax to GDP ratio presently about one-and-a-half
percentage points lower than its level of a decade ago. This tax reform package
makes up less than half of that lost ground. But it does so in a way that differs
markedly from the 1993-94 Budget strategy. The GST will ensure that the erosion
of indirect tax revenue is halted permanently. The Government notes
the report of the Democrats with respect to the current tax system being broken.
The Government agrees with the Democrats and without repeating the quotes and
their analysis of budget figures, it agrees that a strong case has been made for
reform. 4. DISTRIBUTIONAL ISSUES The CameosThe results
of Treasury's distributional analysis are presented as a series of cameos, which
estimate the impact of the tax package on individuals and families in a variety
of situations. The cameos show the effects of income tax cuts and increases
in family benefits and social security payments to be received by various types
of household at a variety of private pre-tax income levels. It is assumed for
these cameos that the tax package does not affect private pre-tax incomes. Disposable
income is affected, however, through the tax cuts and the increased Government
cash payments. The calculations assume that everyone who satisfies the
criteria for a Government cash payment does receive that payment. The calculations
are based on the projected values of family and social security assistance in
July 2000, under pre-tax reform conditions. Then a further calculation was made,
again using those projected values but after the application of the tax reform
package. Effects on Consumer Price IndexThe change in the CPI
represents the increased cost of living produced by the introduction of the tax
package. Treasury estimates that this will be 1.9% in 2001-2. However, the calculation
does not include the effect of the tax package on tobacco. It does include the
effect of the new First Home Owners' Scheme on new house prices. One of
Treasury's assumptions in this area has drawn considerable comment. The calculations
have assumed that all households face the same cost of living adjustment as a
result of the tax package, i.e. the 1.9%. Most other modellers, while recognising
that HES data has flaws, disagree with this approach and prefer to assign different
cost of living measures depending on household income levels. Treasury's objection
to this method is that it relies on using and manipulating data from the ABS'
Household Expenditure Survey in ways which Treasury considers produces unreliable
results this issue is discussed below under the heading the data
debate. The Treasury further noted that the uniform cost adjustment
method simply continued a long established government practice of increasing benefits
based on movements in the population-wide CPI. The Use of Disposable IncomeIn
calculating the cost of living increase, the CPI increase is applied by Treasury
to household disposable income, not to consumption. This technique measures the
change in real disposable income and avoids the problem of differences in saving
ratios between households. It also reveals changes in households' ability to consume
or save as a result of cost of living changes. Treasury argues that avoidance
of the problem of different saving ratios does not produce a significant effect
on the cameo results especially since the population-wide household saving
rate is only around 5%. The Treasury ResultsBased on the Government's
proposed tax package, the Treasury has predicted that prices will rise, on average,
by 1.9% in the second year of implementation of the package. This figure includes
the effect of the new First Home Owners' Scheme on new house prices and excludes
the tobacco prices. [13] Included in the predicted result is allowance
for a 4% increase in pensions and benefits and a promise that over time that increase
will be maintained at 1.5% above the CPI impact. Costs facing Australian
exporters are expected to fall by about 3.5% (i.e. by about $4.5 billion a year).
Import competing firms will also benefit from reduced costs. The entire package
of indirect tax reforms is expected to reduce business costs by 3%. The cost of
private investment goods is expected to fall by around 7%. Rural and regional
Australia will also benefit from a fall in transport costs, due to the reduction
in diesel fuel excise for off-road use from 43c per litre to zero. For large transport
users (including rail) the rate will fall from 43c per litre to 18c per litre.
These reductions are in addition to a refund of around 7c per litre which is available
to all business users of petrol and diesel. Treasury said there should be no price
rise for other consumers. The Data Debate The evidence given
to the Committee revealed a fundamental difference of opinion between the Treasury
and certain commercial/academic modellers on the value of the Household Expenditure
Survey (HES). Two main measures are used in this area: (i) the Australian
Bureau of Statistics' (ABS) HES and (ii) the Consumer Price Index (CPI). The HES
is carried out every five years by the ABS and surveys in detail the expenditures
of some 8400 households across Australia. The difference of opinion between Treasury
and certain other modellers, concerns the value to be given to the HES data and
its reliability in measuring the effects of some aspects of the tax package. In
evidence given to the Committee, Treasury representatives said that they considered
the HES data to be invalid for the purposes of distributional analysis.
In response to a statement from Senator Murray that As soon as
you try to disaggregate it (HES data) and get down to small cameos of household
numbers, your margin of error soars [14],
Treasury representative, Dr Henry, commented: Yes
Even at the aggregate
level, the household expenditure survey is not valid or, at least, let
me put it this way: if the household expenditure survey is valid, then the Australian
national accounts are wildly inaccurate and the CPI is even more wildly inaccurate.
[15] He continued:
the ABS does
not believe the HES. The ABS takes the HES results. It then uses a lot of judgement,
a lot of guesswork, a lot of manipulation in order to manipulate those results
of the HES to produce the official CPI weights.
So, even at the
aggregate level, the ABS is saying that the household expenditure survey does
not provide an accurate representation of household expenditure patterns. [16] Those modellers who use the HES extensively,
however, recognise the flaws in the data set, make adjustments to allow for those
flaws and then use it because it has no equivalent available in this country.
There was no evidence provided however that conclusively demonstrated that one
approach or set of assumptions was better than the other. Another major
concern with the use of HES data is dissaggregation. Treasury have also consistently
argued that disaggregating the population-wide CPI among different households
is not desirable:Certain features of the HES invalidate its being used
in this way. This is because of the adjustments made by the ABS in order
to calculate weights for the CPI these adjustments assure a better CPI but, without
them, the HES data contain biases. For example, adjustments are made for known
cases of under reporting (eg tobacco and alcohol) and some expenditure estimates
(eg some consumer durable items) are subject to high sampling errors and are adjusted
using other data on expenditure levels. [17]
The HES is conducted over a full year to take account of seasonal variations
in expenditure. Treasury believe that: It is not appropriate to draw statistical
inferences from individual household records in the survey. It is only through
the aggregation process that seasonal and other irregular variations in expenditure
patterns are ironed out. [18] The broader issue of different cost of
living measures for different household groups has been examined in detail by
the ABS. They concluded, in the publication Feasibility of Constructing Price
Indexes for Special Population Groups (Catalogue No. 6445.0) that there was
almost no difference in the overall price increase each household group
faced over a period of eleven years despite prices rising by 120 per cent
over that period. For these reasons, governments have consistently adopted
the practice of providing compensation for price increases by adjusting benefits
by the movement in the population-wide CPI. As mentioned earlier, and in
the ANTS document, the Government has calculated the increase in the cost of living
by applying the increase in the population-wide CPI to household disposable income,
rather than to household consumption. This approach has been criticised by some
witnesses for not calculating the saving ratios among households when determining
changes in cost of living. The Government believes that their approach, as stated
in the ANTS document:
is consistent with the approach of many researchers
who take the view that current consumption (in a particular week, month, or even
year) provides a less reliable measure than disposable income of a household's
ability to consume. And it is a household's ability to consume that is really
of interest, since that is what is affected by cost of living changes. [19]
The Government also believes that there is a more pragmatic
reason why cameo calculations are based on disposable income, rather than consumption:
While there is a National Accounts measure of average household saving,
there are no reliable data on the saving rates of different types of households.
For example, the HES, which has sometimes been used for such purposes, does not
contain reliable data of this sort a point that the ABS emphasises with
each survey release.
Those who would prefer to see cost of living
calculations based on current consumption will presumably want to argue that,
to the extent households spend less than their total income (ie save), the cost
of living increases reported here will be overstated and, hence, the cash gains
are understated. They will also take the view that, to the extent households spend
more than their income (ie dissave), the cost of living increases will be understated.
Making such adjustments, however, would have an imperceptible effect on the cameos
especially as the population-wide household saving rate is about 5 per cent.
[20] Adequacy of Compensation Under
the Government's tax reform package people will be overly compensated for the
inflationary impact of the introduction of the GST. Personal income tax cuts totaling
over $13 billion per year will be introduced from July 2000. Family assistance
will be increased by more than $2 billion a year under the new tax system. Tax
relief for families is introduced and incentives for low and middle income families
are improved in two ways: families can earn more income before family
payments start to be reduced; and the phase out of payments occurs at
a slower rate. The Government has ensured that all Australians will be
able to share in the benefits of tax reform. In particular, families, pensioners
and other recipients of income support payments will benefit from increases in
their payments. The Government will increase all pensions and other income
support payments (such as the Age Pension) by four per cent which more than offsets
the general price rise associated with the GST. The Government will also pay bonuses
to eligible senior Australians to help maintain the value of their savings. As
the ANTS document states: These increased rates of assistance raise the
maximum level of all income support payments by more than the impact of tax reform
on prices (as measured by the CPI), overcompensating recipients for the cost of
living effects of the changes to indirect taxation arrangements. The Government
will ensure that income support payments are 1.5 per cent higher than
they would have been had the normal automatic indexation arrangements applied.
[21] There has been a variety of micro-modelling
performed on the adequacy of the compensation provided in ANTS. These include:
Treasury's PRISMOD simulation which was used in ANTS, HES based distributional
analysis, and the Melbourne Institute modelling. As already discussed,
the PRISMOD simulation showed that all groups would be better off under the new
tax system, with the average family $40-50 per week better off. The HES
data also showed that each household group would be better off, with the cost
of living increase varied between 1.3 per cent and 2.5 percent. The Melbourne
Institute modelling is best described in the ACOSS submission as: (attempting)
to take account of variations in household spending and saving patterns by using
data from the ABS Household Expenditure Survey (HES) which is adjusted in various
ways to improve reliability. Their model also produces a different (and higher)
set of estimates of the effects of the consumption tax changes on housing and
tobacco prices and on the CPI overall. Their estimate of the average CPI increase
is 2.44% compared with Treasury's estimate of 1.9%. [22]
ACOSS asked the Melbourne Institute to model the price effects for households
whose primary income source is government income support payments, described by
ACOSS as households with the lowest incomes. Four assumptions were
then modelled, using the Treasury inflation figure of 1.9% as the most optimistic
assumption, and then getting progressively more pessimistic (See ACOSS submission
p.9.). The results of this modelling showed that even under the most pessimistic
assumption used by the Melbourne Institute, every group modelled was better off
under the tax package. 5. FOOD AND THE GSTThere has been some
discussion about the results of the economic modelling commissioned by the Committee
indicating that the macroeconomic impacts are very similar for the Government's
existing tax package compared to a package which exempts food from a GST and has
compensating reductions in income tax cuts.This result is hardly surprising given
that the budgetary impact and therefore the fiscal stimulus delivered by both
the packages is unchanged. The macro-modelling results therefore provide no support
for the position that food should be GST-free.On the equity side, not one of the
micro-models presented has been able to show that any individual group will be
worse off under the tax reform package, regardless of the inflation assumptions
used. This evidence clearly shows, not only the need for tax reform, but
the overall adequacy of the Government's compensation package. For reasons of
equity, efficiency and simplicity, the Coalition Senators are strongly against
exempting food, or other necessities of life, from the tax package.
Further, many of the witnesses who made submissions to the committee targeted
the issue of exempting food directly, raising major concerns about any proposal
to exempt food. A general summary of most of the concerns raised was provided
by Mr Fergus Ryan, Chairman, Business Coalition for Tax Reform. In summary,
excluding food would add significant compliance costs, particularly for small
business; tend towards creating a culture of non-compliance and activity that
seeks tax avoidance; increase the administrative costs and the time spent by tax
administrators and the courts in deciding what is and what is not food for the
purpose of tax; and reduce the general competitive advantage of a single rate,
broad based indirect tax.
would reduce the amount of GST paid by
the wealthiest 20 per cent of households by double the reduction for poorest 20
per cent of households. In other words, for every dollar of benefit received by
the poorest 20 per cent of households, granting a GST-free status for food would
deliver a benefit of $7.60 to the rest of the population. [23] The myth of an Economic Efficiency gain
from exempting foodThe Senate inquiry has not received any evidence which
supports the proposition that there is an economic welfare benefit from exempting
food from the GST. In fact the evidence has quite the contrary. Professor
Dixon in his report to the Senate inquiry stated that: In the
long run, exempting food has a negligible, but negative impact on economic welfare
under either labour market assumption. [24]
He also provided this further caveat to his findings: Our food-exempt
simulations bring two issues to mind. The first concerns the costs of implementation,
compliance, administration and rent-seeking. These costs are likely to be increased
if the GST is implemented with substantial exemptions, but in all of our simulations
they have been ignored. These ignored costs should be set against any benefits
that we show in our simulations for the tax package, especially in assessing the
benefits of exempting food. [25] The Econtech research also showed that
a slight erosion to economic welfare would result if food was made GST-free. Professor
Neil Warren, in his December 1998 paper, explained how the perceived benefits
to low income earners, and any suggestion of a benefit to economic welfare, may
not be achieved: There is also another issue why concessional rates for
food need to be avoided. This is concern about whether the full benefits of the
concession are actually passed onto the consumer. It there are two sectors and
one is taxed and the other untaxed, consumers will substitute the untaxed good
for the taxed good. As they do this, the price of the untaxed good will rise as
a result of increased demand and the price of the taxed good will fall so that
not all of the tax burden on the tax good will be passed through to the consumers
of that product. As a result, the supposedly untaxed good effectively is taxed
because of the increased demand for this good and the pricing response by producers.
[26] Given that the evidence shows that exempting
food from the GST has negative impact on general economic welfare, and that there
is no evidence that it would provide any specific welfare gains to those on low
incomes, there is a strong economic efficiency argument for leaving food in the
GST net. The revenue implications of exempting Food Significant
concerns have been raised by many witnesses about the magnitude of revenue required
to remove food from the GST net. The equity issues surrounding the inclusion
of food in the GST net cannot be fully assessed without an understanding of the
magnitude of revenue involved. Given the definitional problems surrounding what
should constitute taxable food, most witnesses decided to define food widely
excluding restaurants and takeaways. Treasury estimated [27]
that the amount of revenue forgone if food (other than food sold in restaurants
and takeaway food establishments) were to be zero-rated would be $4465
million in 2000-01, blowing out to $5820 million in 2003-2004. This evidence
is consistent with Professor Warren estimate in his December paper: If
food was zero-rated, this would reduce revenue by over $5 billion [28]
The only witness who defined food narrowly for costing purposes was Prof.
Dixon who defined it as
meat, vegetables, bread all the
staples [29]. Under this narrowest of definitions,
he predicted it would cost $2.7 billion a year, by crudely taking 10% of what
Australians currently spend on those staples. Distributional Impact of
Making Food GST-FreeGiven that most of the proponents for making food
GST-free cite equity arguments, it is important to determine who will receive
the greatest benefit from so doing. Professor Warren points out that rather
than being a progressive equity measure, zero-rating food would benefit the wealthy
to a much greater extent than the poor:
zero-rating food benefits
most in nominal terms, those in the highest income groups. In fact, the top 20%
benefit twice as much in terms of dollars and cents from zero-rating food, as
does the bottom 20% [30] Ms Angela Ryan agreed with Prof. Warren's
assessment: If you are looking at the dollar amounts of GST that you are
going to lose if you take out something like food, it is the high income earners
that will do best out of that system by a proportion of about two to one if you
compare the top 20 per cent of households with the bottom 20 per cent. [31] At worst the distributional impact of
exempting food is in fact the opposite to the objectives of those who would wish
to do so on progressive equity grounds: It is reasonable to expect that
this action (zero-rating food) would increase the tax burden on non-food goods
and services which would provided the greatest benefit to the low-income groups.
[32] Moreover, at best, the distributional impact
of exempting food from the tax net shows that it is an extremely blunt instrument
for achieving any form of equity outcome. The simple fact is
that this approach to compensating for the effects of taxing food is quite inferior
to directly targeting those groups which are adversely affected. This should be
clear from the magnitude of the benefit to the lower income groups from zero-rating
food. In effect, what zero-rating food has done is to reallocate around $2b from
a 4.9% GST which was initially on food to all other goods which now have imposed
on them a 5.8% GST. [33] And, Angela Ryan concluded,
if you include food in the base, you have got more than enough revenue
collected from the higher income earners to compensate the lower income earners
and have money left over that you can spend on other welfare programs if that
is what you want to do. [34] Conceptual Problems
in Defining FoodA common theme in the evidence before the committee was
that defining what constitutes food for taxation purposes would lead to massive
compliance costs, both to business and the government. Problems in defining
what is food arise because what constitutes food under one classification may
not be taxable under another. Which classification has precedence and therefore
results in the item being taxable or non-taxable needs to be clear. [35]
In describing the difficulty of defining food, Prof. Warren uses the following
examples:
confectionery is "any item of sweetened prepared
food which is normally eaten with the fingers". Clearly, this has a very
wide interpretation and not surprisingly, needs to be elaborated upon at length
to make it operational. As a consequence, statements such as the following in
the UK VAT information on biscuits is typical: Biscuits covered or partly
covered in chocolate or some other product similar in taste and appearance to
chocolate are standard-rated. This includes: - all fully and semi-coated
biscuits including biscuits decorated in a pattern with chocolate or some similar
product;
- chocolate shortbread;
- gingerbread men decorated with
chocolate unless this amounts to no more than a couple of dots for eyes; and
- ice
cream wafers partly covered in chocolate such as "chocolate oysters".
- It does not include:
- chocolate chip biscuits where the
chips are either included in the dough or pressed into the surface before baking;
- bourbon and other biscuits where the chocolate or similar product forms
a sandwich layer between two biscuit halves and is not continued onto the outer
surface;
- jaffa cakes; and
- biscuits in a coating of caramel or
some other product that does not resemble chocolate in taste and appearance.
(Source: Section 2.5, UK Inland Revenue VAT Notice 701/14 Food, which
is reproduced in Attachment C) A review of the criteria used to define
what is and is not food in the VAT legislation applied by various countries results
in several common conceptual problems for those drafting the VAT legislation.
These problem areas can be categorised along the lines detailed in the following
table. [36]
Table 8 Defining Food in Practice under a GST [37] |
Criteria | Taxable
(and therefore not FOOD) | Not Taxable (FOOD) |
Temperature | Above ambient temperature
Frozen yogurt | At ambient temperature Refrigerated
yogurt | Timing of Consumption | Immediate
consumption | Later consumption | Sweetness
| Sugar, chocolate or yogurt covered | No
sweet topping | Use of Fingers | To
be eaten with fingers | Not eaten with fingers |
Saltiness | Salted | Unsalted |
Number | 1 pudding 1-5 buns | 2+
puddings 6 buns (maybe of any type) | Volume
| 1 pudding less than 425ml 1 beverage less than 500ml
Size of the biscuit ( eg Gingerbread biscuit vs Gingerbread house) | 1
pudding greater than 425ml 1 beverage greater than 500ml |
Concentration | Drink with >25% fruit
juice concentration | Fruit juice flavoured drink with less
than 25% juice | Alcoholic content | Drink
with alcohol is taxable if otherwise not taxable | No alcoholic
contents | Prof. Warren concludes: If any one of these
criteria could be applied directly to a particular product, then life for those
administering the GST legislation is probably not that difficult. However, if
a product could be applied to more than one of the above classifications so that
under one criteria it is taxable and another not taxable, then very real problems
will arise. In this case, the product needs to be uniquely classified - hence
the need to endlessly clarify the status of new food products as they are developed
and enter the market place or as producers find avenues for making their product
non-taxable. [38] If we take the issue of temperature
in isolation, it could have definitional ramifications felt in almost every supermarket,
convenience or corner store, as Joycelyn Morton of the ASCPAs pointed out:
you might have a situation where you have bottles of coke on the shelf which are
warm, and there would be no GST on them, but if they were in the fridge and they
were cold, they might be deemed to be takeaway and therefore subject to GST. Similarly,
in a large supermarket, if they have the large chicken rotisserie, is that takeaway
chicken or is that to consume at home?
So you would get all these definitional
problems. Every time you try to make that distinction you will be causing people
an enormous amount of distress from an administrative point of view. [39] Administrative and Compliance Costs
of a GST One of the areas which has not been directly modelled by any
of the witnesses before the Senate Committee is the effect on compliance costs
of excluding food from the tax net. However, evidence has been overwhelmingly
supportive of the proposition that exempting food will lead to more rather than
less compliance costs. Prof. Warren states in his December paper that: Clearly,
zero-rating or even concessionally treating food has major implications for both
the administrative cost of the GST (for the Australian Tax Office) and for the
compliance cost of businesses. Together, administrative and compliance costs constitute
the operating costs of the tax system. [40] Compliance
costs of the current tax reform package are considered to be easily manageable,
and, as Kenneth Claughton of the ASCPAs points out, in the long term beneficial.
I have a full-time practice at the moment, giving advice, advising
clients how to comply with their sales tax obligations. That practice will almost
disappear under a GST. [41] However, the same
can not be said if food were to be exempted:
as long as any GST
is kept simple and therefore easy to administer (which in practice means a very
broad tax base and a single tax rate), most businesses can use cheap computers
and accounting software packages to keep track of their tax liabilities. This
may also have the advantage of improving the information flow to managers, an
issue that is often cited as a cause of small business failure and a benefit flowing
from the introduction of a GST. If food is zero rated in Australia, then
there will be many small businesses who sell food products who will be administering
a GST only to claim back GST refunds, thus contributing nothing to GST revenue
nor receiving any cash flow advantage. Quite simply, if a multiple (positive)
rate GST is introduced, then the burden of compliance could be substantial for
small taxpayers (as is noted for the UK below). [42]
Ms Ryan from the ACPAs described excluding food from GST as an administrative
nightmare. She went on to say:
it would be a bonanza for lawyers
and, I can say, for Accountants. In lots of ways we are not talking our own book
here. If we want to have huge accounting GST practices all around Australia, please
exempt food. [43] The added complexity in compliance from
exempting food also leads to higher levels of avoidance, according to the ASCPA
I think it was quite justified that we saw comments from the Labour Party
leaders during the campaign that the UK had a real problem with avoidance and
evasion. I would contend that the main reason for that the UK has a number of
very wide ranging exemptions in their VAT, including food and children's clothing.
Under a system like that, it is a relatively easy step for people to be able to
falsify invoices. Instead of showing it up on your till as adult clothing you
could show it as children's clothing and things like that. This means that the
system is not comprehensive. [44] On the issue of managerial benefits that
would accrue to small firms through GST reporting, Prof. Warren wrote: In
the survey of VAT relating to 1986-87, 30 per cent of the respondents agreed that
record keeping for VAT gave them benefits. The principal benefit was saving money
because respondents did more of their own accounts, giving less work to outside
advisers. Other benefits included better stock control and fewer bad debts. [45]
Further he said: If the administrative and compliance costs of a
GST are to be minimised, the GST structure should be simple, with a minimum of
rates and exemptions. A simple comprehensive structure avoids difficult borderlines
that put up administrative and compliance costs. [46]
To sum up: All the above discussion clearly highlights the significant
downside from an administrative and efficiency perspective, when food is made
GST-Free. Even from an equity perspective, while zero-rating food does assist
the poor, it is a very ineffective method of compensating those adversely affected
by such a tax. [47] 6. CONCLUSIONS The
Government's tax reform plans were comprehensively put before the Australian public
in August 1998 in the policy document Tax Reform: not a new tax a new tax system
(ANTS). Implementation of the Government's policy will see:
Personal income tax cuts totalling $13 billion a year providing a 30 per cent
marginal tax rate for over 80 per cent of taxpayers Increased family
assistance to low and middle income earners Increased pensions and government
benefits $10 billion a year of embedded taxes being removed from business
Costs to exporters falling by $4.5 billion. The Government Senators
reach the following conclusions from this stage of Committee's proceedings: 1.
On the basis of evidence heard by the Committee and on the basis of the economic
modelling commissioned by the Committee, Government Senators conclude that there
is substantial support for the Government's tax reform plans as set out in the
policy document Tax Reform: not a new tax a new tax system (ANTS). Economic
commentators and modellers confirmed that benefits to the economy as a result
of ANTS will come from: A boost to economic welfare GDP
growth Employment growth Export growth Increased investment
Continued fiscal responsibility; and More sustainable Commonwealth-State
financial relations. 2. There was clear support in the evidence from a
wide range of witnesses from the business sector, the unions, farming representatives,
academics and tax practitioners for the Government's view that the current tax
system is broken. It was accepted that the existing indirect tax revenue base
would continue to diminish as the services sector increases its share of the economy.
3. No case was made for making food or other necessities of life GST-free.
While macro-modelling showed similar results for the Government's existing tax
package compared to a package which exempts food from a GST and has compensating
reductions in income tax cuts, the result is hardly surprising given that the
budgetary impact and therefore the fiscal stimulus delivered by both the packages
is unchanged. 4. No evidence was submitted which showed that the Government's
compensation measures were inadequate. The up-front 4 per cent increase in pensions
and other government benefits and the guarantee to ensure that income support
payments are 1.5 per cent higher than they would have been had the normal
automatic indexation arrangements applied, was shown to overcompensate specific
groups of low income earners identified by other distributional modellers. Senator
Alan Ferguson Senator Brian Gibson Senator Bill O'Chee Liberal Party
Liberal Party National Party Footnotes[1]
Evidence, p.20. [2] Evidence, p.21. [3]
Evidence, p.626. [4] ECONTECH, submission to the
Senate Select Committee on A New Tax System, Modelling a New Tax System (ANTS)
Comparing MONASH and MM303, 14 February 1999, p.20. [5]
Tax Reform: not a new tax, a new tax system (ANTS), p.162. [6]
Evidence, p.116. [7] Prof. Peter Dixon and Maureen
Rimmer, The Government's Tax Package: Further Analysis based on the MONASH
Model, Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University, Report prepared
for the Senate Select Committee on a New Tax System, January 25, 1999, p. ii.
[8] ECONTECH, op cit, p.39. [9]
Ibid, p.19. [10] Dixon. op cit, p.ii. [11]
David Johnson and Rosanna Scutella, Long term effects of the governments
tax package, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research,
18 September 1998, p.1-2. [12] ECONTECH, op cit,
p.21. [13] ANTS, p.162. [14]
Evidence, p.37. [15] Evidence, p.37. [16]
Evidence, p.38. [17] ANTS, p.162. [18]
ANTS, p.162. [19] ANTS, p.163. [20]
ANTS, p.163. [21] ANTS, p.56. [22]
ACOSS, Submission to the Senate Select Committee on A New Tax System, Modelling
the effects of the proposed tax reform package on low income households, December
1998, p.7. [23] Mr Fergus Ryan, Chairman, Business
Coalition for Tax Reform, HANSARD, Senate Select Committee for a new tax system,
Wednesday, 3 February, 1999, p. 608 [24] Dixon,
op cit, p. iv. [25] Ibid. p.iv [26]
Neil Warren, Food: staple of life or staple of the GST?, ATAX, Faculty
of Law, University of NSW, 16 December 1998, p.7 [27]
Supplementary question to Treasury on 19 January 1999 from Senator Murray [28]
Warren, op cit. p.7 [29] Evidence, p. 525 [30]
Warren, op cit. p.7 [31] Evidence, p. 567-568
[32] Warren, op cit. p.8 [33]
Ibid, p.8 [34] Evidence, p.568. [35]
Warren, op cit. p.11 [36] Ibid. p.11-12 [37]
Ibid. p.12 [38] Ibid. p.12 [39]
Evidence, p. 570. [40] Warren, op cit. p.13 [41]
Evidence, p. 573. [42] Warren, op cit, p.14 [43]
Evidence, p.572 [44] Evidence, p. 565 [45]
Warren, op cit. p.15 [46] Ibid. p.16 [47]
Ibid. p.17
Top
|