Chapter Six
Commercial viability
Introduction
6.1
This chapter will examine the government's commitment to the NBN being a
commercially viable operation. Relevant issues include the level of demand that
is required and its relationship to service pricing.
6.2
Pursuant to this, the predicted estimated costings for the NBN will be
outlined, together with the basis on which those costings were made. Claims that
productivity increases will result from the NBN will also be examined, as will
the contentious issue of conducting a cost benefit analysis for this massive
spending of tax payers' funds.
The foundation promises
6.3
Shortly after being elected in November 2007, the Rudd Government made a
commitment to the nation that it would:
...provide funding of up to $4.7 billion, and consider the
necessary regulatory changes, to facilitate the roll-out of a new open access,
high-speed, fibre-based broadband network, providing downlink speeds of at
least 12 megabits per second to 98 per cent of Australian homes and businesses.[1]
6.4
Following the termination of the RFP fibre-to-the-node (FTTN) process in
April 2009, this commitment suddenly ballooned into the current promise that
the Australian Government would build a fibre-to-the-premise (FTTP) NBN. This
build will be conducted in partnership with the private sector in what is
claimed to be the single largest nation building infrastructure project in
Australia's history.
6.5
The current commitment by the government is that the NBN will:
-
Connect 90 percent of all Australian homes, schools and
workplaces with broadband services with speeds up to 100 megabits per second, 100
times faster than those currently used by many households and businesses;
-
Connect all other premises in Australia with next generation
wireless and satellite technologies that will deliver broadband speeds of 12
megabits per second; and
-
Directly support up to 25,000 local jobs every year, on average,
over the 8 year life of the project.[2]
6.6
Further, the government stated that the NBN was to be 'built and operated
on a commercial basis'[3]
by a company established specifically for this purpose, the company now known
as NBN Co.
6.7
The government has committed that 'every house, school and business in
Australia will get affordable fast broadband.'[4]
However, the cost of this new broadband promise is nearly ten times the
previous commitment, with the government anticipating it will now require an
investment of up to $43 billion over the eight year period that the NBN build
is expected to take.[5]
Cost – benefit analysis
6.8
The expenditure of any substantial amount of public funding needs to be
justified transparently to the Australian taxpayer. This is usually undertaken
in the form of a robust and rigorous cost-benefit analysis, which is generally
a component of the government's business case that is routinely prepared prior
to embarking on a major project.
6.9
When the government embarked upon its nation building infrastructure
project, a new agency called Infrastructure Australia was created to facilitate
the analysis and the prioritisation of proposed major infrastructure projects. In
its first report to government in December 2008, Infrastructure Australia
stated that it had:
...adopted a new national approach to infrastructure decision
making ... [which] uses a robust framework. ...
Infrastructure Australia has rigorously applied this
framework.[6]
6.10
The framework has seven stages through which infrastructure projects
were to be analysed, which are as follows:
-
Goal identification;
-
Problem identification;
-
Problem assessment;
-
Problem analysis;
-
Option generation;
-
Solution assessment; and
-
Solution prioritisation.[7]
6.11
The detailed explanation within Stage 6 of the framework, the 'Solution
assessment', lists the following requirements for action within that stage:
Use of cost-benefit analysis to assess those
options/solutions. ... Accurate and justifiable Cost-Benefit Analysis [CBA]
has been used to appraise options. CBA is comprehensive and includes wider
economic and social impacts.[8]
(bolding added)
6.12
It is clear from this that the government's intention was that all
proposals for infrastructure projects of national significance were to be
validated through the application of this assessment framework, which included
the requirement of an 'accurate and justifiable' cost-benefit analysis that was
to be 'comprehensive' in nature.
6.13
In addition, Infrastructure Australia was required to assess
infrastructure proposals that were to be funded from the Building Australia
Fund (BAF) according to a set of BAF evaluation criteria and principles. Those
criteria can be found on Infrastructure Australia's website, along with an Explanatory
Statement that cites:
Pursuant to s. 52(2) [of the Nation-Building Funds Act
2008], the Infrastructure Minister must not recommend payments from the BAF
unless Infrastructure Australia has advised the Infrastructure Minister that
the payment satisfies the BAF Evaluation Criteria.
Similar arrangements apply under s. 52 to advice from
Infrastructure Australia ... through the Infrastructure Minister, to the Minister
for Broadband, Communications and the Digital Economy...[9]
6.14
The BAF Evaluation Criterion 2 relates to the '[E]xtent to which
proposals are well justified with evidence and data', with the first part of
that criterion stating:
-
Proposals
should demonstrate through a cost-benefit analysis that the proposal represents
good value for money.[10]
6.15
The committee reminds the government that a lack of 'value for money'
was the supporting principle used by the government to terminate the previous
FTTN RFP process.
6.16
The government has made no attempt to justify its decision to push ahead
with this major infrastructure project without undertaking a cost-benefit
analysis; this was also the case with the previous FTTN NBN proposal. When
Minister Conroy was closely questioned at Senate Estimates in October 2008 whether
there would be any cost-benefit analysis of the FTTN proposal, the Minister was
adamant:
This is an election commitment, and we will deliver our
election commitment. ...
We are going to deliver on our election commitment. ... No ifs,
no buts; it will be delivered.[11]
6.17
The Senate Standing Committee on Environment Communications and the Arts
(the ECA committee) sought confirmation that the funding was to come from the BAF,
yet was to be exempt from the BAF Evaluation Criteria, to which the minister
replied:
We could not be clearer. ... This will not be subject to
Building Australia Fund processes. This is a separate election commitment.[12]
6.18
The committee is appalled that, at the time of reporting, almost eight
months after the announcement of the commitment to a massive investment of $43
billion for the FTTP NBN, the government still refuses to comply with its own
legislative requirements that the NBN must undergo a rigorous cost-benefit
analysis.
Stakeholder opinions regarding CBA
requirement
Implementation Study?
6.19
The report has discussed in chapter 3 the broad scope of the
multi-disciplinary Implementation Study being undertaken by the Lead Advisor
into all aspects of the NBN roll-out. It would be logical to include a cost-benefit
analysis within the broad scope of this study. Despite the comprehensive list
of inclusions within that study, (see paragraph 3.17), most conspicuous by its
absence is a cost-benefit analysis of the project.
6.20
It was clearly anticipated by several witnesses that a cost-benefit
analysis would be part of the Implementation Study. Mr Sameer Chopra stated at
the public hearing in Canberra that;
It is my understanding that [a cost-benefit analysis] would
probably occur as the NBN implementation study group comes together, but I have
not seen any cost-benefit analysis at this stage.[13]
6.21
The committee asked a telecommunications and media analyst at this
hearing whether it would be 'prudent' to undertake a cost-benefit analysis for
the NBN, to which the response was:
We absolutely do. With an investment of $43 billion,
whichever way you look at it and whichever way you structure it in terms of
debt equity funding, it makes sense to perform a rigorous cost-benefit
analysis.[14]
An assessment framework
6.22
Another witness made the comment that a cost-benefit analysis was just
one of a 'dashboard' of assessment tools available to the government, also
anticipating this to occur within the Implementation Study:
It is one of a range of measures that governments can use to
assess the attractiveness of particular projects. It is obviously important
that projects have a reasonable cost-benefit analysis ... irrespective. Clearly,
there is more detail which will come out through the implementation study about
the costs and benefits of this project and we look forward to seeing them.[15]
6.23
The Productivity Commission held the view that conducting a cost-benefit
analysis was not the only way of assessing the viability of a major project. Mr
Bernard Wonder explained at the Canberra hearing in October:
Desirably, cost-benefit analysis can be used as a tool to
inform decision making. Different cost-benefit assessments will present
different challenges. Sometimes they are more straightforward that other times:
for example, where there is less uncertainty in what the benefits and costs
flows are.
...It is not only cost-benefit analysis, I might add, that will
give you that information – there may be other analyses that are being
conducted ... but a cost-benefit analysis is one framework that you can enter all
of these things into.[16]
6.24
The submission provided by the Productivity Commission went into
considerable detail about using a cost-benefit analysis as a framework,
highlighting the fact that any such analysis is only as good as the data
available to feed into the framework. The submission noted that:
The precise nature of the benefits and cost which should feed
into the analysis will depend on the specific features of the project.[17]
6.25
The Productivity Commission points to the government's Best Practice
Regulation Handbook (2007) which recommends:
...costs and benefits, including money equivalents based on
willingness to pay, should be discounted using a real rate with appropriate
sensitivity analysis.[18]
6.26
A social discount rate of seven per cent is recommended by the handbook,
with sensitivity testing between three and eleven per cent.[19]
The Productivity Commission believes that:
...uncertain future costs and benefits should be estimated in
terms of the risk-weighted averages (expected values) of all possible outcomes
... That is, uncertainty of costs and benefits should be addressed in the
valuation of the costs and benefits rather than used to vary the appropriate
discount rate.[20]
6.27
The issue of the uncertainty of both the costs and particularly the
benefits is very pertinent to the NBN, a fact pointed out by the Productivity
Commission:
The use of expected values of costs and benefits is relevant
to the NBN, as uncertainties of the evolution of technologies and consumer
demand mean no single estimate for each of the future costs or benefits can be
proposed with certainty.[21]
6.28
The submission acknowledges the difficulties around conducting a cost- benefit
analysis for the NBN, highlighting the complexities of 'forming appropriate
estimates of the expected values of costs and benefits.'[22]
Further emphasising this point, the Productivity Commission submitted that:
...cost-benefit analysis is a tool whose results are no better
than the systemic way in which it is used and the quality of data it elicits or
estimates – its value lies principally in it being appropriately used to fairly
assess the relevant costs and benefits of a project.[23]
6.29
The committee acknowledges these difficulties. However, the committee
strongly believes that this should not excuse the government from their
responsibility to assess the 'value for money' of this project by conducting a
cost-benefit analysis.
6.30
The submission provided by the Productivity Commission suggested that
one way to overcome much of this uncertainty is to conduct pilot trials, with
the objective of gathering information that may not otherwise be revealed. Consequently,
pilots can be 'useful insurance policies'[24]
for the government. Noting that the government has selected Tasmania as the
first phase of the national roll-out, and also that the first priority regions
have been selected for the Regional Backbone Blackspots, the submission
suggests that information from these 'pilots' could provide valuable input into
the framework of a cost-benefit analysis.
6.31
The committee views this as sound advice, but believes the suggested
approach of awaiting results from pilots could see the timeframe for
implementation of the NBN blow out considerably. However, the committee also
recognises that the additional time taken would be a relatively inexpensive
'insurance policy' when measured against the $43 billion investment at risk.
6.32
One organisation that remains highly critical of the government's
refusal to undertake a cost-benefit analysis is the Business Council of
Australia (BCA). The written submission provided by BCA attached their
submission to the government regarding regulatory reform options.
6.33
Although supportive of the NBN proposal, BCA's submission to this
inquiry noted that the government's decision to create the NBN Co was:
...a significant departure from past policy approaches in the
ICT sector and the market-led approach to broadband investment favoured by the
OECD. The proposal is therefore not without some risk and... the BCA contends
that further analysis of the [NBN FTTP] proposal is warranted.[25]
6.34
BCA supported this call for further analysis citing recent advice to
governments by the OECD that 'policy makers must evaluate the costs and
benefits of any government investment in communication infrastructure.'[26]
The submission stated further that:
Consistent with this advice and with international best
practice, the government should provide publicly and in full a cost-benefit
analysis that also sets out the investment case for the planned roll-out ...
Rigorous cost-benefit analysis needs to be an in-built part
of all spending decisions ... The government needs to remain committed to having
Infrastructure Australia audit the likely benefits of major infrastructure
projects and ensuring the transparency of policy advice.[27]
6.35
Attention was drawn to the lack of publicly available information about
the government's policy intentions, which presumably will be entailed in the
Implementation Study. Highlighting the need to fill this information vacuum,
BCA cautioned that until the government's intentions are more fully detailed,
'much potential current and future investment [in broadband take-up] could be
held back.'[28]
6.36
The submission by BCA to the government's discussion paper on regulatory
reform further elaborated on these issues, again emphasising the need for the
Implementation Study to be completed expediently. The submission made a number
of high level recommendations, two of which were directly relevant:
-
The government should make the completion of the NBN
implementation study a high priority and avoid upholding potential investment,
both within and outside the NBN, due to bureaucratic delay or regulatory
uncertainty.
-
A thorough cost-benefit analysis on the NBN proposal should be
made publicly available, to ensure that the approach that has been proposed has
a net benefit for the Australian economy and to underpin confidence in
investment.[29]
6.37
The committee fully supports this call to the government to ensure that
the Implementation Study is completed expediently and that a thorough
cost-benefit analysis is conducted, with the outcomes of both of these to be
available for public scrutiny.
Existing analysis[30]
6.38
At the time of reporting, there had been only one academic attempt to
conduct a structured cost-benefit analysis. This was presented by economists
Professor Henry Ergas and his associate, Professor Alex Robson at a
Productivity Commission roundtable on evidence-based policy.
6.39
The telling conclusion of this detailed analysis was that the overall
costs of the NBN will far outweigh any benefits by between $14-20 billion. This
is a staggering claim that surely must ring alarm bells for the government.
6.40
Professor Ergas and Professor Robson are both previously from Concept
Economics. Their analysis compares the likely costs of connecting those within
the 90 percent footprint of the FTTP network with the counterfactual cost
of upgrading the existing HFC and copper assets. The latter scenario is similar
to the government's previous FTTN proposal, but with higher speeds of 30-40
Mbps and enabling wireless broadband in regional areas of up to 30 Mbps. The
economists estimate that the cost to build the FTTP NBN would be around three times
the cost of the counterfactual.
6.41
The analysis of the benefits was based on the likely increase in the
consumer's willingness to pay for the increased speed offered by the NBN FTTP.
This willingness to pay is then mapped over a 20 year period (life span assumed
for the FTTP), allowing for increases in income and the development of future
applications that could drive demand. Professor Ergas explained the analysis as
follows:
Our cost-benefit analysis is based on the bottom-up approach,
...the way that works is that we assume a rate of growth in the willingness to
pay and then we assume that the willingness to pay for higher speeds increases
more rapidly than the willingness to pay for lower speeds. ...
We then value the benefits in that way. That is an absolutely
conventional way of doing this sort of exercise for new goods. We then use that
valuation to compare it to the schedule of costs and that then gives you the
comparison between the costs and benefits...[31]
6.42
The paper suggested that the NBN would take longer than eight years to
build and that consequently any flow-on benefits would be delayed. Also
questioned was the government's claim that eHealth applications development
will surge.
6.43
The authors were critical of a number of assumptions made by the
government that were fundamental to the development of the current NBN policy.
One criticism was the government's claim that the NBN would result in an
increase in productivity after 10 years of 1.1 per cent. The authors stated
their belief that this was incorrectly based on the change in productivity
resulting from there being no broadband available, whereas most Australian
consumers already have some form of broadband.
6.44
There is also an admission within the paper that the option of delaying
the project was not costed. However, the authors are quoted as suggesting that:
This option is likely to have high value, particularly if it
is accompanied by regulatory reform that addresses the current disincentives to
invest.[32]
6.45
The authors conclude that if the costs of the NBN outweigh the benefits
by more than $17 billion, the project should not proceed. As Professor Ergas
stated at the Canberra hearing:
What it shows to my mind is that you need to do this kind of
analysis because otherwise it is impossible to take rational decisions.[33]
6.46
Since the publication of this paper, there have been some criticisms of
the overall outcome arrived at by the authors, their assumptions and the fact
that they advocate a counterfactual that is similar to the now terminated FTTN
proposal.
6.47
The committee believes that this criticism only serves to emphasise the
need for the government to take the lead, undertaking a robust cost-benefit
analysis that makes use of all the information that only the government has
available to it through the ongoing Implementation Study.
Government position
6.48
The committee sought advice from the Department of Broadband,
Communications and the Digital Economy (the Department) on whether a
cost-benefit analysis was planned for the NBN. The Department reiterated the Minister's
claim that the implementation of the NBN 'is the government's commitment' and
continued that:
There will certainly be an independent, multidisciplinary set
of commercial, technical and legal advice.[34]
6.49
However, this apparently will not include a cost-benefit analysis.
6.50
The Department of Finance and Deregulation (DoFD) played a significant
role in determining that the FTTP proposal should proceed. When questioned
about how DoFD determined the costing estimates for the proposal for the FTTP
network, it was explained that:
Our costing exercise was entirely related to the cost of
building or acquiring a network. It was not a business study or a cost-benefit
study or a business case analysis. ...
In terms of advice on cost and benefit, certainly we have
given advice to the minister in relation to those matters on NBN Co., but a
full cost benefit analysis was not done as part of the period leading up to the
[April 2009] announcements by the government.[35]
6.51
Officers from the Treasury were also questioned in relation to the
costing exercise, and in particular whether Treasury would normally be asked to
conduct a cost-benefit analysis of a major project proposal as part of its advice
to government. Treasury responded:
We would not. ...a formal cost-benefit analysis has not been
undertaken.[36]
6.52
However, Mr Murray did attempt to explain this response in the ensuing
discussion. Although there may be some benefits that would be readily
identified, such as increased capital stock, and clear economic benefits from
increases in productivity, he said other benefits would be less obvious,
including those resulting from improved competition and greater network
coverage:
...there are likely to be significant spin-off benefits of
this. ... Those spin-off benefits are very difficult to quantify.[37]
6.53
The committee was troubled to hear Finance Minister the Hon Lindsay
Tanner seem to concede that a cost-benefit analysis would be too hard, due to
the high level of uncertainties that exist:
...cost-benefit analyses are only as good as the assumptions
you feed into them and it is hard to make assumptions about applications and
services that will only be imagined and marketised in a high-speed [NBN]
environment.[38]
6.54
Again, the committee remains highly critical of the dismissive attitude
taken by the government that such uncertainties justify tossing a cost-benefit
analysis into the 'Too Hard' basket.
Minority lack of concern
6.55
Conversely there were a number of key stakeholders who stated that they
were not overly concerned that there would be no cost-benefit analysis of the
NBN project. Some pointed to historical examples of large national
infrastructure projects that would most likely not have gone ahead if approval
was dependent on a rigorous cost-benefit analysis. For example, Mr Maha
Krishnapillai from Optus explained:
...if Sir John Monash in Victoria in 1920s and 1930s had to do
a full economic cost-benefit analysis in terms of rolling electricity out to
regional Victoria it would have failed and would not have gone ahead on the
basis of why would you rollout electricity to replace a whole lot of candles
and gas lights.[39]
6.56
At the Communications Day Congress in Melbourne during October, the
issue was the topic of a panel discussion that 'revealed pronounced industry
ambivalence on the subject'.[40]
Mr Greg Muller Managing Director of Bullseye was quoted as saying that the
delay caused by insisting on a cost-benefit analysis:
...could be more harmful that the project itself – leaving
Australia exposed to increased competition from other countries proceeding with
their own fibre builds. ...
If we're going to be sustainable as an economy and as a
society into the future, we need access and we need speed ...[which] are
fundamental needs for our society as part of our growth ... failing to implement
[the NBN] is only going to constrain us and constrain our business in much
bigger ways than $43 billion.[41]
6.57
There was a consensus in that panel that, due to the high level of
unknowns, particularly regarding future innovative applications that may be a
consequence of the NBN, concern for the cost-benefit analysis was possibly
over-stated. Examples of present and future applications and uses for the NBN
are featured in chapter seven.
6.58
The committee acknowledges that there will be innovations that evolve in
an NBN environment. However, the committee strongly disagrees with the reliance
on policies based on a 'build it and they will come' mentality, which the
committee believes is a poor substitute for a rigorous and publicly disclosed
cost-benefit analysis.
Commercial viability
6.59
As noted in the introduction to this chapter, the government has
committed to ensuring that the NBN Co operates as a 'commercially viable'
Government Business Enterprise (GBE). This will be a necessary pre-requisite
for the government to be able fulfil its subsequent commitment to sell down its
share in the NBN Co five years after the network is fully operational. However,
in stating this desired outcome, the government has yet to define how it will
measure the 'commercial viability' of the NBN Co, which adds to the list of
uncertainties upon which this proposal is based.
An applicable definition
6.60
One definition of commercial viability was provided in a report to the
New Zealand Government as it sought to restructure its energy sector in 1998.
The report cited several criteria for determining whether the newly separated
entities would be commercially viable. The New Zealand scenario has parallels
to the situation currently facing the Australian telecommunications industry. The
criteria to determine that the entities were commercially viable included that the
entity was:
-
able to survive (operate without going into liquidation or
requiring financial support from its shareholders) under all reasonably
foreseeable market and operating circumstances; and
-
projected in most reasonably foreseeable market and operating
conditions, including all probable market outcomes, to provide enough positive
free cash flow and net profit after tax to enable it to:
-
compete
effectively in the wholesale [telecommunications] market;
-
have
funds to reinvest in the [telecommunications] sector;
-
provide
acceptable returns to its shareholders; and
-
borrow
from the private sector on comparative terms.[42]
6.61
The sensitivity to unfavourable variations in demand and different
pricing strategies was also taken into consideration.[43]
6.62
Due to the strong similarities of the New Zealand restructuring scenario
to the establishment of the NBN Co, the remainder of this chapter will use
this definition as a useful benchmark for further examination of the
'commercial viability' of the NBN Co.
Timeframe?
6.63
The committee draws attention to another critical parameter that has not
been defined, being the timeframe within which the NBN Co must attain commercial
viability. Although there has been no definite period of time over which the
NBN Co would be expected to prove commercial viability, there was a hint by the
Executive Chair of the NBN Co when he commented that:
I would certainly not exclude the possibility of providing a
return on the investment over the longer term.[44]
6.64
Of course, this still leaves Australia guessing exactly what is meant by
'over the longer term.'
The cost
6.65
According the above definition of commercial viability, the NBN Co will
need to earn a return sufficient to cover the cost of the build before it can
generate 'positive free cash flow and net profit after tax' and be able to
provide 'acceptable returns to shareholders.'
6.66
The government has said that up to $43 billion dollars would be invested
to build a fully operational, wholesale only, national network. The project
will be undertaken as a joint investment, with government hoping to attract
significant investment from the private sector. This poses the question: what
will be the actual cost to tax payers?
Government response
6.67
The government has been questioned closely about the $43 billion
investment and what portion of that is to be the responsibility of the
Australian taxpayer.
6.68
At Budget Estimates in May 2009, the Minister gave a detailed opening
statement in which he noted that '...the total funding of the network will be no
more than $43 billion.' The minister further explained that:
With respect to the total cost I should make clear that
advice to government identified a cost range of $38 billion to $43 billion ...
no-one has seriously suggested that these figures are an underestimate. I note
that even the analyst Ian Martin stated in a recent report that the
government's proposed NBN company could roll out a passive optical network
based on FTTP ... to 90 per cent of households for less than $20
billion to $25 billion. Indeed we expect the actual cost to be significantly
lower than $43 billion for a number of reasons, including the substantial
contingency intentionally built into the estimate.[45]
Lower estimates
6.69
The Minister's admission that the NBN could cost almost half the stated
$43 billion was supported in evidence to the committee some months later.
Mr Arthur Price, CEO of Axia NetMedia Corporation, outlined his cost estimates
to the committee, stating that the greatest proportion of the cost to build the
NBN would be in connecting individual premises to fibre. This would:
...have much more of a resources logistical challenge. We think
the fibre-to-the-premises component of this is about two-thirds to
three-quarters of the [total] capital.[46]
6.70
Mr Price believed that the way that this was managed in the network built
by Axia in both France and in Alberta, Canada, was to complete the build in two
stages. The regional backhaul (Axia's 'community interconnect grid') was deployed
first and communities connected once they had backhaul provided to their
closest regional centre.[47]
Mr Price believed that the NBN in Australia would not cost $43 billion,
stating that:
The fibre-to-the-premise part would be in the range of $20
billion. The community interconnect grid [regional backhaul] – the rest – is in
the range of let us say $5 billion to $7 billion.[48]
6.71
Mr Price later reiterated that the build should cost 'around $27 billion
and less than $30 billion.'[49]
$43 billion under the microscope
6.72
The committee questioned officers from the Department of the Treasury
when they appeared at the Canberra public hearing during October 2009. Mr Richard
Murray reiterated that it was not the government's intention that it would need
to provide the entire $43 billion; rather, 49 per cent of that would come from
the private sector over the eight-year building period. Mr Murray continued
that:
The assumption has been made that the other 51 per cent
[provided by the government] would have around a 50-50 debt-equity ratio. ...
That leaves you with an equity funding by the government of about $11 billion.
Not all of that is going to be spent over the forward estimates, but we have in
the budget numbers enough to cover the government's equity investment over the
next four years.[50]
6.73
However, when the government was pressed to confirm it would only need
to come up with that 51 per cent, the minister admitted that:
We said we would be the 100 per cent if necessary.[51]
6.74
The amount of $11 billion was then further clarified in response to
another question on notice:
The figures ... indicate that the Government borrowing to fund
its equity contribution to the National Broadband Network might be of the order
of $8.6 billion (comprising an $11 billion equity contribution less the $2.4
billion from the Building Australia Fund), not all of which would be required
over the forward estimates. An addition of $8.6 billion to the borrowing
program, spread over (say) four years, would represent an increase of only
$2.15 billion per annum. An adjustment of this magnitude would be very
manageable.[52]
6.75
The government has committed to providing an initial investment of
$4.7 billion, which includes:
$4.45 billion for an equity injection for the company that
will build and operate the network and an investment in the early rollout of
the fibre-based network in Tasmania.[53]
6.76
This $4.7 billion comprises $2.4 billion from the Building Australia
Fund; the remaining $2.3 billion is to be provided through the future issuance
of Aussie Infrastructure Bonds. Further discussion about the issuing of bonds
can be found in chapter five.
Wholesale only entity
6.77
Even if the overall cost of the NBN is less than $43 billion, the major
limiting factor to commercial viability is that NBN Co will only provide
wholesale services to access seekers. Basically, NBN Co can only sell access to
the fibre, and that will generally be to telecommunications retailers, at least
in the formative years. It is common knowledge that the major commercial value
is in the retail service arena, in which the NBN Co cannot participate.
6.78
If the NBN Co is to be commercially viable, it follows that the prices
it charges for access to the wholesale services must ensure that the NBN Co can
meet the minimum criteria listed in paragraph 6.60 above. Critical among those
criteria is the ability to provide sufficient positive cash flow to enable
reinvestment in the sector and also provide acceptable returns to its
shareholders.
6.79
To assess the ability to generate positive cash flow, a basic
requirement would be a sound understanding of the cost of building a fully
operational NBN. Due to the current lack of information regarding the technical
build and consequently the overall cost of the NBN, prices that have been
suggested to date by analysts and telecommunications companies can only be regarded
as speculation. Again, details within the Implementation Study will hopefully
enable more precise calculations.
The relationship between demand and
pricing
Is there demand for high-speed
broadband?
6.80
The demand for broadband services across Australia is increasing,
according to the June 2009 statistics from the Australian Bureau of Statistics
(ABS) on Internet Activity. Comparisons to June 2008 data show a continuing
upward trend in broadband connections and a corresponding decrease in dial-up
connections.[54]
6.81
An interesting figure is that there still remain over one million
dial-up subscribers out of a total of 8.4 million internet subscribers.[55]
Almost 13 per cent of Australian internet subscribers are currently not connected
to broadband services. This is a significant statistic that the government must
consider as a possible limitation to achieving commercial viability of the new
network.
6.82
Subscription to Digital Subscriber Line (DSL) continued to comprise the greatest
proportion of non-dial-up connections; however this figure fell from 63 per cent
in December 2008 to 57 per cent in June 2009.[56]
6.83
What is most notable is the staggering ongoing growth in wireless
broadband connections, which now represent around 47 per cent of the DSL
subscription. In June 2009, there were just over two million wireless
subscribers, with over 1.9 million of these being mobile subscriptions. This
equates to an increase of over 51 per cent in wireless subscriptions
over the previous six months.[57]
6.84
This figure would no doubt be even higher, as the ABS site states that
the figure of two million does not include internet connections via a mobile
phone device.[58]
Given the ever increasing use of handheld devices by a progressively more mobile
workforce, added to by the popularity of new smart phones, such as the iPhone,
the committee suggests that this figure should be markedly higher.
6.85
Some of these statistics should be examined at more than just face
value. In fact the increasing prevalence of wireless broadband connections
raises serious doubts over the need for fibre to 90 per cent of
Australian premises.
6.86
The ABS statistics also document the increasing appetite among Australians
for higher download speeds, with 57 per cent of internet users now subscribing to
download speeds of 1.5Mbps or greater, up from 51 per cent in December 2008.
However, another telling aspect to the ABS report was that the demand for the
highest speed connections of above 24 Mbps remained steady at
5 per cent over the last six months.
6.87
This indicates that the increase in demand for speed is limited to the
lower end of the speed range, hence questioning the requirement of the
government's move from the RFP proposal speed of 12 Mbps. Mr Kevin Morgan was
one witness that raised this point directly with the committee when he
suggested the government needed to provide affordable broadband, not just to
the individual consumer but to 'society at large.' Mr Morgan pointed out that
the current UK proposal for broadband is for 2 Mbps as a national goal, suggesting
that for Australia:
...it might be more realistic to perhaps go back to the 12
megabits as the baseline. That would be adequate for most applications that any
domestic user would want. ...
So 100 megabits is definitely gold plating and perhaps not
necessary.[59]
6.88
In Canberra the committee heard from Mr Daniel Blair from Southern Cross
Equities, who agreed that there was not the demand for 100 Mbps, in fact he believed
that '[t]here is not that propensity of demand for [even] 12 megabits per
second.'[60]
He later continued that:
In our view there is not a demand for 100 megabits per
second. [But] if you offer someone something for free they will probably take
it up. ...
It is pretty hard to see how you are going to use 100
megabits per second today.[61]
6.89
Mr Blair stated quite firmly that the FTTP network would not be
economically viable, partly due to the lack of demand in two areas:
...we believe there is limited demand from consumers – firstly
for the speeds being proposed and, secondly, a low propensity by consumers to
pay above what they do today.[62]
6.90
On this basis, Mr Blair believed that the NBN would not be attractive to
potential investors, and that in fact, 'I would not be recommending this
investment at this stage.'[63]
A different pricing model?
6.91
Aligned to the discussions of both Mr Blair and Professor Ergas relating
to consumers' 'willingness to pay', a commentator from Nokia, Mr Bob James, came
to the following conclusion:
History shows us that people and businesses ... looking back
over the last ten years ... have paid the same amount or less year after year in
most countries yet received faster speeds. ...
Many households in urban areas have the option of paying for
higher speed today, but choose their plans based on needing more gigabytes per
month rather than more megabits per second.[64]
6.92
What Mr James infers is that families are looking for subscription plans
that meet their higher download data capacity requirements, rather than just
seeking higher speed capacities for those downloads.
6.93
Referring to the current price modelling based on speed, Mr James
commented that:
Charging for speed made sense when fast connections to
business premises were constructed at one time and at great expense. ... It made
sense when something rare had to be rationed. But does it make sense when the
government is spending considerable amounts of money to make fast broadband
universally available at affordable prices?[65]
6.94
Mr James suggests that the NBN Co could charge for usage, rather than
for speed, for example applying a monthly fixed fee per premises, plus a charge
per gigabyte of usage. Mr James continued:
This utility style pricing ...is a good way of pricing by value
for high fixed cost infrastructure – rather like water and electricity. It also
aligns the ... long term interests of the end user, the retailer and the network
owner.[66]
6.95
This line of thought picks up the thread of conversations the committee
has had with Mr Arthur Price. In evidence before the committee, Mr Price has
consistently advocated Axia's principle that the network owner does not compete
with their customer. If network is thus established as a wholesale-only
operation, then it is Axia's contention that structural separation will occur
by default.
6.96
The network owner (in Australia's case, the NBN Co) will then be
focussed on attracting access seekers in order to be commercially viable,
rather than actively competing with them and restricting their access. If the
fibre network is of the highest quality, access seekers will be attracted to
it. They in turn will seek to attract consumers through differentiation of
their retail services.
6.97
Mr James' pricing model would dovetail neatly into this scenario, aligning
the needs of the NBN Co, its access seekers and the Australian consumers. This
has potential as an optional operating model for the NBN Co.
6.98
Mr Price said that wholesale next generation networks, such as
Australia's proposed NBN, would need to alter their operations and focus on
long term benefits. This is due to the fact that fibre networks have high up-front
capital costs. However, Mr Price reminded the committee that FTTP has low
recurring maintenance costs and activities. Consequently, the wholesale owner
will:
...depend on the evolution of new, compelling services for end
users and a change in the way end users buy. Those are transformational things.
They depend on the evolution of a vibrant, competitive retail services sector
that provides easy-to-adopt, high value services.[67]
6.99
Mr Price then outlined a scenario that he believed would deliver a
commercially viable wholesale-only open access network. However, the notable
difference between Axia's model and that of the government is Mr Price's suggestion
that the starting point is 'a level of financial support', to be provided by
the government. Generally 'in the range of a third of the capital,'[68]
this financial start-up would be considered a government grant that will not be
expected to earn a return.
6.100
However, in this scenario Mr Price claims that the grant would also be a
one-off cost to government: '[T]his financial support is not ongoing.' In
addition, if regional backhaul was provided through that one-off government
grant, he believes there would be no further need for the additional government
ongoing funding to ensure ubiquitous regional telecommunication coverage:
...take into account substantial funding ...to regional and rural
Australia and they crystallise that into one time span and get rid of it – let
me use an example – they would have a payout of having a $2 billion one-time
grant... [that] would deal forever with the regional and rural dislocation. That
would not be a grant, that would be a saving against ongoing programs.[69]
6.101
Using the scenario above, Mr Price believed that wholesale access prices
for each premises in Australia could be between $40 and $60 per month.[70]
Mr Price also discussed in detail the key success factor for a wholesale
network to be commercially viable, stating that:
For wholesale fibre-to-the-premises investments to be viable
the key criterion is to ensure market penetration covers the cost of capital
for the implementation of the fibre-to-the-premises and associated
infrastructure.[71]
6.102
Using the access prices of $40 to $60 per month, Mr Price thought it
would be possible for a customer to have a voice-plus-ISP price starting at
about $50 per month for a lower end 25 Mbps service, ranging to $80 to $100 for
100 Mbps. This compares favourably to what Mr Price believed was the current average
cost for a Telstra customer of $100 per month. At those pricing levels, the NBN
Co could drive demand for its network, attract access seekers and hence achieve
the level of market penetration that would ensure commercial viability. Mr
Price stated that the ideal penetration level was around 70 per cent, and until
that is achieved there would be shortfalls for the company.[72]
Other pricing guesstimates
6.103
As mentioned previously, without the Implementation Study, the industry
can only speculate on what could be the pricing levels of the wholesale access.
6.104
At the Telecoms World conference in Sydney during September 2009, a
telecommunications analyst, Mr Mark McDonnell, estimated that wholesale access
prices would cost more than double the cost suggested by Mr Price.
6.105
Mr McDonnell also pointed to what he believed was a lack of demand for
high speed broadband, stating:
...no-one has yet provided any real evidence relating to unmet
demand for 100Mbps broadband delivery for the household.[73]
6.106
This statement seems to be verified by the ABS statistics cited above
that showed there was no growth in the demand over the last six months for
services above 24 Mbps.
6.107
Using his own set of assumptions, Mr McDonnell calculated the cost of
wholesale prices would be $113 per month if the NBN achieved 100 per cent
penetration, ramping up to $905 per month if the network achieved only 12 per
cent penetration.[74]
6.108
Mr McDonnell continues that:
It isn't hard to imagine what would happen to consumer demand
under these prices.[75]
6.109
The committee notes that the penetration of the recently completed tasCOLT
pilot achieved was only around 25 per cent.[76]
6.110
Mr Blair also provided some estimates of probable pricing, likewise
based on a series of assumptions (necessary due to the lack of accurate
information), including a take-up assumption of 50 per cent after 10 years of
operation. Under his modelling, Mr Blair proffered that:
...to maintain a 10 per cent return would require that the
wholesale price be somewhere around the $110 mark. If you are a retailer ...
[t]oday's margin levels suggest [a retail price] around the $200-$220 mark. It
is conceivable that perhaps it could be $150, but that would be on very thin
margins ...[77]
6.111
A more optimistic estimate of the cost of wholesale access was made in
late October by an Optus analyst, placing the cost at between $40 and $70 per
month depending on the level of service selected by the customer. Not
surprisingly, this lower-end price was quickly highlighted by Minister Conroy.[78]
6.112
The committee draws attention to the government's commitment that it
will provide every house, school and business 'access to affordable
fast broadband.' (emphasis added). Wholesale access prices must be structured
to ensure that no Australian business, household or school is excluded from the
potential benefits offered by the NBN through a lack of service affordability.
The value of existing assets
6.113
With the view that market penetration rates of around 60 to 70 per cent
will be required for the NBN Co to be commercially viable, the obvious question
is how can that be achieved by a new network when the current incumbent, Telstra,
will also be striving to retain at least 60 per cent of the market.
6.114
The obvious solution would be to utilise as much of Telstra's existing
infrastructure – its underground conduits, pits and pipes – as possible. The
value placed on Telstra's assets, and consequently the bargaining power it
could wield, was also subject to much industry speculation. At least that was
the case until 26 October 2009, when the government inadvertently
tabled a report by the ACCC that revealed Telstra's true worth to the
Australian public.
6.115
Discussion in the industry has centred on the probability that Telstra
could negotiate with the government to 'vend in' its assets, including the
transfer of its customer base. This would resolve the dilemma of NBN Co in
struggling to attract customers to the new network, with the bonus of achieving
the immediate high market penetration and hence faster attainment of commercial
viability. It could also be (very optimistically) seen by some as a 'win' for
Telstra, considering the well known fact that much of their copper customer
access network is ageing and consequently heavily maintenance-intensive.
6.116
Conversely, Telstra could have chosen not to negotiate with the
government at all. Instead, with the knowledge that it would take the
government least eight years before the NBN was built and fully operational,
Telstra could easily have made a concerted effort to upgrade its own
infrastructure during that period. They would subsequently be able to retain and
possibly increase their customer base through their upgraded offerings, leaving
the new NBN virtually stranded, underutilised and definitely not commercially
viable.
6.117
That option has been severed with the government's tabling in
September 2009 of the Telecommunications Legislation Amendment
(Competition and Consumer Safeguards) Bill 2009. This bill seeks to amend the
several pieces of existing legislation, with the overall effect of enforcing
the structural separation of Telstra's wholesale and retail business units,
thus removing the incentive to optimise its market power. This legislation is discussed
in detail in chapter seven.
6.118
Negotiations between Telstra and the government were ongoing at the time
of reporting. No-one will ever know the full impact that the mistaken
revelation of Telstra's asset value has made on Telstra's negotiations with the
government. However, for commercial viability, the NBN Co needs more than
just Telstra's infrastructure; it requires Telstra's customers who are using
that infrastructure. This customer base is most certainly as valuable as the infrastructure
itself.
Legislation to allow price setting
6.119
One of the outcomes sought by the Telecommunications Legislation
Amendment (Competition and Consumer Safeguards) Bill 2009 is to amend the
powers of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) in making
access determinations. As noted in the Explanatory Memorandum to the Bill:
A key reform made by this Bill to Part XIC [of the Trade
Practices Act 1974] is the removal of the ACCC's role in arbitrating access
disputes between access providers and access seekers, and the introduction of a
power for the ACCC to set up front the terms and conditions of access to
declared services to apply to all access providers and all access seekers.[79]
6.120
This provision seeks to end the ability of Telstra to 'game' the regime,
streamlining the pricing process and providing pricing certainty to access
seekers and their customers. It is a move that will no doubt be welcomed by the
majority of access seekers who have experienced both the investment uncertainty
and the costly and time-consuming litigation processes that have plagued the
industry for the last decade.
6.121
However, even if the legislation is passed and the ACCC is granted the
power to set prices, the committee highlights that there is still no clear
basis on which the ACCC can decide prices. The committee again urges that the
Implementation Study must be publicly provided to ensure that the previous
industry uncertainty around pricing options is not perpetuated by government delays.
Pricing principles
6.122
The Productivity Commission (the Commission) provided a submission to
this inquiry that drew from recent reviews it had conducted, noting that the
Commission had not undertaken any recent reviews into broadband itself.
Regardless of this, the submission provided some very useful principles that
govern a number of aspects around the deployment of the NBN, including pricing
principles.
6.123
An insight provided by the Commission is that governments should not
regulate prices 'unless it is clearly necessary to avoid larger efficiency
losses from the successful exercise of market power.' Although this implies
that price regulation in the current telecommunications environment is
warranted, the submission then states that:
Price regulation should not be employed to meet social
objectives.[80]
6.124
This places some cloud over the continuation of price regulation once
the NBN is fully operational, due to the high level of social benefit. Although
social benefits of the NBN are difficult to quantify or monetise for the
purpose of a cost-benefit analysis, they are certainly an assumed consequence
by the government and major stakeholders.
6.125
The Commission also cautioned that 'price setting is an imprecise
exercise' and that '[A]ll of the methods available to regulators for setting an
"efficient" price have shortcomings.'[81]
6.126
Having noted that price-setting is an 'imprecise exercise', the
Commission warned that there are negative effects of setting prices either too
high or too low:
Prejudicing future investment in important infrastructure
services through setting prices too low is likely to be much more economically
damaging than allowing service providers some prospect of retaining a modicum
of monopoly rent.
-
Excessively low access pricing produces adverse effects
gradually, but its long-run welfare implications can be significant. If access
prices remain too low, no firm (including the incumbent) will make core network
investments as it cannot expect a reasonable return on capital.
-
Excessively high access prices discourage service-based
competition and lead to excessively high retail prices, less product variety
and the potential for inefficient duplication of facilities.[82]
6.127
The Commission recommended that prices should be set so that they are:
...at least sufficient to cover efficient long-run costs,
including a return commensurate with the commercial and regulatory risks
involved.[83]
Competitive neutrality
6.128
The Commission's submission also discussed the issue of competitive
neutrality, noting that the full operational and governance arrangements are
still uncertain. The Commission states that compliance with the policy of
competitive neutrality would ensure that any company operating as a government
business would not have a competitive advantage. The submission quotes from the
Commonwealth Competitive Neutrality Policy Statement (1996), which warned
that:
Where competitive neutrality arrangements are not in place,
resource allocation distortions occur because prices charged by significant government
businesses need not fully reflect resource costs. Consequently this can distort
decisions on production and consumption ... [and] also distort investment and
other decisions of private sector companies.[84]
6.129
This has clear implications for the NBN Co and also for the ACCC in
setting up front costs for access to the NBN Co, which will be a major GBE. The
Commission cautioned that:
...prices set by any government-owned business should fully
reflect resource costs and, in doing so, achieve a commercial rate of return on
the business' capital.[85]
6.130
This note of caution is not only relevant, but also highlights yet again
the fact that the costs of building the NBN are an essential component in the
price setting process for the wholesale-only network. Without knowledge of the
anticipated cost outlay, the prices cannot be set to 'reflect resource costs'
and consequently no-one can determine whether the NBN Co will ever be a
commercially viable entity.
Discard the commercial viability
requirement?
6.131
There have been a number of stakeholders who have questioned the
government's insistence that the NBN Co must be a commercially viable GBE. The
founding CEO of Internode is among those who believe that the government is
mistaken in trying to achieve this outcome. Mr Simon Hackett aligns the
creation of a dedicated national broadband network with the building of
Australia's national road system. He notes that the last 50 years of economic
growth and prosperity was facilitated by the national roadwork, and suggests
that the next 50 years' growth will be equally dependent on building a
dedicated national broadband network.
6.132
Consequently, Mr Hackett states that:
...the new network, like the national road network, should be
initially built as a 100% government funded network, not as a public-private
partnership, to avoid a tug-of-war between competing drivers that could
literally pull the network apart.[86]
6.133
Mr Hackett explained this further:
The natural agenda of a commercial investor ... conflicts
fundamentally with the long term, nationally available, wholesale-only aspects
of the NBN policy.
...this just serves to highlight that the commercial investment
model is the wrong model to apply to a network of this nature![87]
6.134
Professor Joshua Gans was also of the view that the government should
not force the NBN Co to be a commercially viable entity. Professor Gans pointed
out that the NBN will be a critical infrastructure project for Australia, and
stated that:
There is a lot of discussion regarding the new broadband
network and whether it can earn a commercial return. As an economist, I regard
that as a largely irrelevant consideration for what is essentially a government
infrastructure policy.[88]
6.135
Professor Gans believed that the government must place greater
consideration on the long term benefits of the NBN, adding the interesting
viewpoint that:
...part of the future proofing is being not just
technologically future proofed but economically future proofed as well. ... I see
it not as broadband policy but infrastructure policy and that is how we have to
think about it.[89]
The promise of pricing equivalence
6.136
Adding to the pricing confusion is the commitment by the government not
only to provide affordable broadband across the nation, but also to ensure that
everyone in Australia pays the same price for their broadband services. This is
in response to thus-far unanswered and long-standing criticisms that regional
and remote Australians are forced to pay far higher prices for a service than
their metropolitan-living compatriots.
Cross-subsidisation
6.137
In order for wholesale access prices to be equivalent right across the
Australian landmass, and over the three different delivery modes, it is
apparent that access prices for the less-profitable regional, rural and remote
communities will need to be supported by cross-subsidies from the more
commercially viable urban centres.
6.138
Minister Conroy has been quoted as confirming that the NBN will offer
uniform wholesale pricing across fibre, wireless and satellite:
This is unashamedly and explicitly a cross-subsidy to deliver
equivalent service to all Australians.
My ambition is that there will be the same wholesale price
for every household for the same speed across satellite, wireless and
fibre-to-the-node [premises].
We are saying up front this will be a cross-subsidy, one
wholesale price averaged across the country.[90]
6.139
The minister further clarified this several weeks later at Senate
Estimates, however also inserted a caveat:
What I said in Tamworth was that across the fibre network for
90 per cent there would be one price for a product – for example one meg. What
I clearly said was that was our ambition, depending on the implementation
report ... for across the three platforms of wireless, satellite and fibre for
there to be consistent pricing, subject to the implementation study...[91]
6.140
The minister was even more tentative as he further clarified:
What I have talked about is products and, depending on the
implementation study, some products may – and I stress 'may' – be able to be
priced across all three platforms.[92]
6.141
Yet again, the Implementation Study is creating uncertainty even around
the basic assumption of equivalent pricing, which subsequently must impact on
the promised 'affordability' aspect of the NBN.
Should the subsidy be individualised?
6.142
The prospect of having uniform wholesale prices right across the national
network is most likely music to the ears of those who have been consistently paying
much higher prices for broadband services.
6.143
However, in relation to the application of subsidies, the committee
again draws attention to the principles laid out by the Productivity Commission
in their submission. Their submission stated that:
...if subsidies for some consumers of particular infrastructure
services are judged to be necessary, then consistent with the approach agreed
by Australian governments, these should be applied through separate
budget-funded CSOs [Community Service Obligations].[93]
6.144
Later in their submission the Commission further expanded on that
statement:
Governments in Australia have accepted the general
proposition that support for low income, or otherwise disadvantaged, consumers
of infrastructure services is better delivered either by addressing the
disadvantaged directly or through transparent and directly funded CSOs, rather
than requiring providers to cross-subsidise certain users through artificial
pricing structures.[94]
6.145
Professor Gans separately offered a solution to ensuring that all
Australians have access the benefits of the NBN. In evidence given in
Melbourne, Professor Gans explained a way to ensure that the social dividends
of the NBN were achieved across all demographics:
I advocate, in particular, [free] basic broadband services ...
just a basic level of internet access ... there is no reason why you cannot make
that freely available. You end up making a return on that since the vast
majority of households will want something more than the free service, but if
you have a free basic internet service...it allows you to really consider putting
government services online. We know that one of the impediments to putting
those services online is ... simply because there is a section of the population
that cannot afford broadband access. Provide a free service and that entire
debate changes.[95]
6.146
Professor Gans believed that the government could also include an
income-tested provision of computer equipment to ensure that all Australians
could access the free service.[96]
The bottom line dividend for the government would be the long-term cost savings
offered by the broader provision of online government services.
6.147
Yet another alternative solution is to follow the model detailed earlier
by Mr Price, from Axia NetMedia. His suggestion was that, if the government
provided seed funding that was used to nationally deploy sufficient regional
backhaul to facilitate all communities to connect to their nearest regional
centre, there would be no need for any future government funding for regional
areas at all. Mr Axia suggested that:
If you do it that way it solves the perpetual cross-subsidy
program process; all our numbers would say that it would only take $2 billion
of grant to deal with that. The government is spending more than $500 million a
year now, so they get a payout on that $2 billion and the long-term spending is
over.[97]
Productivity Claims
6.148
There is general consensus that the provision of ubiquitous broadband at
equitable and affordable prices will result in productivity benefits across the
nation. For example, the Productivity Commission noted in their submission that:
...an important contributor to Australia's improved
productivity performance in the 1990s was a competitively driven acceleration
of ICT use in many industries ... By analogy, an efficient, well regulated and
widely accessible NBN might be expected to facilitate further direct
productivity benefits ...[98]
6.149
The BCA submission supports this view, making the following claim in
their introductory paragraph:
Investment that raises the speed, quality and coverage of
high-speed broadband provision in Australia has the potential to contribute to
innovation, productivity and economic growth in the coming decades.[99]
6.150
However, the committee notes that the difficulty of attempting to
quantify and monetise productivity increases, coupled with the lack of data
both here and overseas, results in some variance in estimates of the NBN's
benefits to productivity. This simply adds to the list of uncertainties
surrounding the implementation of the NBN.
State of the Regions Report 2008-09
6.151
In the State of the Regions Report 2008-09 (SOR), an entire
chapter was dedicated to the impact of broadband on the economic development of
regional Australia. Although it is almost a year since this report was
published, and the government's planned NBN has evolved from the then FTTN to
the current FTTP proposal, the SOR does carry some important, relevant facts
and conclusions from around the nation.
6.152
The chapter on broadband commences with an examination of the ongoing
upward trend in statistics in broadband and internet usage – a trend that has
continued unabated in the last twelve months, as noted earlier in this chapter.
On the basis of the published figures, the SOR makes a clear statement that:
It is in the nation's interest that the development of the National
Broadband Network is facilitated as planned. Further delays will further
undermine Australia's competitive position in relation to the benefits of the
knowledge economy and of online services.[100]
6.153
Further on, the report finds that any delay to the NBN will constrain
the international competitive position of companies, while also delaying the
cost savings that could be achieved through broader application of government
online services. The report also notes that '[P]oor standards of connectivity
constrain innovation', compromising opportunities to develop, for example,
smart network grids that can facilitate the management of greenhouse emissions.[101]
6.154
The report quotes from a Telstra publication, Towards a
high-bandwidth, low carbon future, released in October 2007, which
estimated that telecommunications networks had the capacity to reduce national
emissions by around five per cent, with cost savings in the order of $6.6
billion per year.[102]
With the current debate about carbon trading schemes, the potential value in
carbon credits to Australia will be even more beneficial to the economy today.
6.155
Noting productivity losses quoted in the previous SOR due to inadequate
broadband connectivity, the report stated that 'there is no reason to assume any
improvements in these numbers for 2008'. No doubt the same can be said for
2009:
Last year's SOR identified $3.2 billion and 32,000 jobs lost
to Australian businesses in the previous 12 months due to inadequate broadband
infrastructure and the possibility of an estimated $40 to $50 billion in
savings from e-health/e-medicine and smart networks over 10 years.[103]
6.156
The SOR also speculates that 'the rapid uptake of mobile and wireless
broadband [could be] a symptom of the lack of a high speed national broadband fibre
network.'[104]
A New Zealand perspective
6.157
Late in October 2009 a report was released by three New Zealand authors,
who examined the impact of internet connectivity on business productivity. The
report analysed three broadband scenarios for businesses using the internet:
broadband versus no broadband; slow versus no broadband; and fast versus slow
broadband. In their conclusion, the authors noted that:
Our study is the first, internationally, to estimate the
productivity impacts of connectivity upgrades using firm level data after
controlling for firms' connectivity choices based on their characteristics.[105]
6.158
The introduction of this report highlights the lack of existing
research relating to productivity increases claimed to be attributable to
broadband:
Despite well articulated pleas for upgraded internet access,
reference to rigorous research that quantifies benefits actually accruing from
network upgrades is generally absent in supporting materials. A key reason for
this conspicuous absence is that little rigorous research exists that measures
the productivity impacts of a shift from one type of internet access to
another.[106]
6.159
The overall analysis findings supported the general consensus that
productivity is improved through the uptake of broadband:
We find a ... productivity effect of broadband relative to no
broadband of approximately 10% across all firms. The estimates indicate a
marginally stronger impact on firm productivity ... in rural (low population
density) relative to urban (high population density) areas but the differences
are not significantly different.[107]
6.160
However, an interesting finding seemed to substantiate claims made
earlier in this chapter that perhaps Australia does not need 100 Mbps:
...all of these productivity gains can be attributed to the
adoption of slow relative to no broadband, with no discernable additional
effect arising from a shift from slow to fast broadband.[108]
6.161
The report cautions that this finding should be interpreted with care,
citing a number of possible reasons for the finding, and suggests that further
research would beneficial.
Home-grown examples
6.162
The committee was fortunate to hear from several witnesses who are
already reaping the benefits of broadband. Although no attempt has yet been
made to quantify and/or monetise these benefits, they were none-the-less
apparent.
6.163
In Melbourne the committee heard from executives of Ballarat ICT
Limited, which 'is a partnership of industry, government and educational
institutions', with the underlying belief 'that ICT is critical to creating
sustainable and dynamic growth across the region.'[109]
When asked to comment on the impact that the availability of higher speed
broadband has had on the economic success in the region's ICT sector, their
response was:
If you look at development of technology, there is a strong
correlation between the infrastructure in place, including really good optical
fibre into the [Ballarat Technology] park, and the developments that occurred.
The reality is that to attract investment out of the capital cities you have to
provide the appropriate infrastructure.[110]
6.164
Noting the attraction factor of the high speed fibre connectivity into
the Ballarat Technology Park, another witness said that it 'gives us an
economic development advantage'.[111]
In fact, the group noted that the Ballarat Technology Park had experienced a
slight increase in employment over the past twelve months, despite the global
financial crisis:
In actual fact, we have had a marginal increase in
employment. We are still talking to further investors in this sector ... It gives
me added confidence to continue to push to grow the ICT sector within Ballarat.
It is almost like a risk mitigation sector.[112]
6.165
One sector within the Ballarat region that is benefiting from reach of
the Ballarat ICT Ltd is the Grampians Rural Health Alliance; the Alliance
established a company called GRHANet with the purpose of building a broadband
network across the Grampians region. This infrastructure in turn has enabled
VoIP services within the region's health sector, so that:
...every health service in the region is using IP telephony... So
all calls between all health services in the region are free.[113]
6.166
This has obviously been financially beneficial to each health service. In
addition, GRHANet has enabled administrative benefits to each health service
entity across the region through the establishment of shared service set-ups:
We provide applications, internet services, electronic health
records, electronic referral systems and the like from that major centre, that
shared service.[114]
6.167
Chapter six discusses the benefits of GRAHNet to local healthcare in
further detail.
6.168
There were also benefits for staff in remote locations having the ability
to access specialist opinions. This had multiple flow-on benefits of increasing
the skill levels of remote health workers, increasing their confidence levels.
Having specialist advice available on-call and face-to-face had an unexpected
benefit of decreasing staff turnover and also acting as an attraction in the
recruitment of new staff.[115]
6.169
All these benefits are having very real, positive impacts across the
Ballarat health sector and on to Melbourne. Unfortunately none have been
collated and documented.
6.170
Another Melbourne witness gave evidence of the productivity improvements
resulting from the use of broadband. Mr Brad Wynter, from the City of
Whittlesea, described a number of innovations that have been introduced within
the council with the aim of reducing the regulation burden on business. The
first was to design a common electronic smart form that could be utilised by
all Victorian councils and then made available to them across a common
platform:
That EasyBiz project built that platform to cover 21
different regulatory processes including planning, building, land based
information, health and local laws ... with the aim of simplifying for local
businesses their dealings with local government.[116]
6.171
Mr Wynter explained that this principle has subsequently been applied to
legislation governing food safety and compliance timetables. Even though there
were training programs for businesses that handled food, the council realised
there was no common template for businesses to record their compliance
information:
We built an online template system in conjunction with the
ANZFA standards and made it available to all Victorian councils. ... Since then
both New Zealand and Western Australia have looked at the system and have been
interested in utilising it.[117]
6.172
These and other innovations discussed by Mr Wynter, clearly demonstrate
that through the use of high-speed broadband, the council had improved business
productivity by reducing the administrative burden. Other 'mobile applications'
decreased the amount of travel required by council officers, again with increased
productivity and decreased fuel costs and resultant carbon emissions.[118]
6.173
Again, unfortunately these benefits have not been collated or documented
other than anecdotally here in Hansard.
Employment promises
6.174
One of the focal points of building the new network was the
government's promise that this would stimulate employment:
This is a major nation building project that will support
25,000 jobs every year, on average, over the life of the project. At its peak,
it will support 37,000 jobs.[119]
6.175
At that time, with the global financial crisis biting hard throughout
the world, this was a very welcome promise of economic stimulus and employment
opportunities.
6.176
Given that the first rollout has only recently commenced in Tasmania,
there have been no reports to date supporting the claim that local jobs are
being supported in the areas where the fibre deployment has commenced, or
whether the deployment has created new job opportunities, or is just supporting
existing employment.
Skills shortage
6.177
While the committee acknowledges that it is early days in the NBN rollout
and that figures supporting the claim are most likely unavailable, there is one
issue that greatly concerns the committee, and that is the requirement for
highly skilled technicians to undertake this rollout.
6.178
The tasCOLT report highlighted the fact that the project, which was
comparatively minute in scale compared to the national NBN rollout, was significantly
hampered by the lack of skilled technicians required to deploy the fibre.
Availability and affordability of skilled installation
contractors also contributed to delay and final completion date of the network.[120]
6.179
This claim should ring alarm bells for the government to make sure that
there are sufficient skills training in the appropriate technical fields that
will provide the number of skilled, work-ready employees to undertake the
rollout in each region.
6.180
The committee sought some information from the Tasmanian Government on
how it would ensure there were sufficient numbers of appropriately trained
workers ready to rollout the NBN in Tasmania. The committee also sought to hear
from the Tasmanian Skills Institute on the courses they might currently have
underway that would provide places for those requiring new skills or an upgrade
of current skills. Both these potential witnesses declined to appear before the
Committee.
6.181
The committee did hear relevant evidence from the Ballarat ICT Limited,
who responded to the question of whether the NBN would result in local jobs.
The representatives noted that it was '[c]ritical ... to understand the
timeframes' that the training facilities would have to provide the training:
If the NBN was to be launched in Ballarat in six months,
there is no doubt that we would be challenged in finding the full range of
skills necessary to support implementation. If we have a window of three of
four years, ... the University of Ballarat, particularly through its TAFE
division, is one mechanism we would try to ramp up the skilling of labour.[121]
6.182
The committee highlights that the government needs a lead time of three
to four years to ensure an appropriately skilled workforce is ready to deploy
the NBN. Unfortunately, the reluctance of witnesses to speak with the committee
does not provide any assurances that the lessons learned during the tasCOLT
trial have been heeded by the government.
Committee view
6.183
The committee draws the attention of the government to the recently
tabled annual report by the Productivity Commission. In the section devoted to
'getting the most out of stimulus spending', the Commission highlights the
'long-term economic effects' that this stimulus spending will have. The Commission
states that:
The Government has affirmed that efficient public investment
in infrastructure requires the application of detailed cost-benefit analysis
and transparency at all stages of the decision-making process, to ensure that
the highest economic and social benefits are delivered. (Australian Government
2008c). It has committed to apply rigorous evaluation criteria to allocations
from the newly established 'nation building' investment funds ...[122]
6.184
The Commission highlights the fact that the 'guidelines have not been
universally applied to date', holding up the NBN as an example:
...the decision to build a National Broadband network, although
endorsed by Infrastructure Australia, was not based on detailed cost-benefit
analysis. ...
The consistent application of rigorous project evaluation
methods remains fundamental to ensuring that investments are the most
beneficial.[123]
6.185
The committee condemns the government's refusal to conduct a
cost-benefit analysis on the implementation of the national broadband network.
The committee urges the government to follow its own guidelines in requiring a
transparent evaluation of the costs and likely benefits of this proposal.
6.186
The committee urges the government to produce an interim report on the
Implementation Study, to provide the Australian public and the telecommunications
industry with a level of confidence in the progress of this massive
infrastructure project. The committee also urges the government to ensure the final
Implementation Study report is not delayed beyond February 2010 and is open to
public scrutiny.
6.187
The committee is disappointed at the lack of benchmark data that could
be used to measure the predicated impact on productivity of NBN. The committee
urges the government to commission an ongoing review by the Productivity
Commission to capture the productivity benefits across all Australian
communities and particularly across all sectors of business and industry. The
committee consequently makes the following recommendations:
Recommendation 4
6.188
That the government conducts a rigorous cost-benefit analysis of its NBN
proposal before the NBN Co enters into any new asset purchasing agreements for
the mainland deployment.
Recommendation 5
6.189
That the government provides an Interim Implementation Study Report by
31 December 2009. This must provide a progress account of the planning of the
NBN, including the progress of the deployment in Tasmania and lessons learned
from that deployment.
Recommendation 6
6.190
That the government immediately undertakes a skills audit for the NBN,
detailing the training course required, the training timeframes involved and
the training institutions available to ensure there is a fully skilled
workforce ready to deploy the NBN in each region.
Recommendation 7
6.191
That the cost-benefit analysis, the Interim Implementation Study Report
and the Final Implementation Study, are all released for public scrutiny within
14 days of completion.
Recommendation 8
6.192
That the government commissions the Productivity Commission to undertake
an annual ongoing evaluation of the impact on productivity resulting from
broadband uptake, across all community, business and industry sectors, with the
first report to be tabled in parliament before the last sitting day in 2010.
Recommendation 9
6.193
That if the Implementation Study concludes the NBN project
specifications are unrealistic, not practical or uneconomical, that the
government must reassess its overall policy approach.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page