Additional Comments from the Australian Greens
1.1
We are living in a global warming emergency. Scientific evidence reveals
that the impacts are already severe and will worsen rapidly as we are on a
trajectory to a 4‑6 degrees increase in global temperatures. There is no
time for Australia to waste on the ineffective, expensive policy that is Direct
Action. Replacing our emissions trading scheme framework is fiscal and
environmental vandalism.
1.2
As the world moves to a 2015 treaty to seriously limit emissions, it is
inevitable that pricing greenhouse gases will be a permanent feature of the
global economy. Should the 44th Parliament repeal the Clean
Energy Future package and replace it with Direct Action, Australia will be
dismantling infrastructure that will have to be reconstructed again in a very
short time period. There would be a significant cost to Australia in lost time,
money, innovation and competitive advantage.
1.3
Direct Action is not a viable replacement and is vastly inferior to
existing law. While it should be acknowledged that Direct Action is still
transforming from a slogan into a policy, there was not one single economist in
written submissions or testimony who supported Direct Action over the existing
emissions trading scheme. In contrast, economists have supported the retention
of the existing law.[1]
1.4
Direct Action is a high-cost, narrow, government controlled scheme
intended to replace the existing market driven, economy-wide, lowest-cost
method of reducing harmful greenhouse gas emissions.
1.5
Stripped down, the centrepiece of Direct Action is the Emissions
Reduction Fund (ERF), which is a small grant-based subsidy scheme for polluting
industries. It will drive no transformation in the economy because of the
following main reasons:
- It is short-term, lasting a few years at most. It is incapable of being
scaled up to meet a higher ambition under future international agreements
without a devastating impact on the national budget;
- Finance institutions are not interested in Direct Action because the
grants are so small, contracts are limited to five years and prices on offer
are likely to be so low that it falls far short of creating investment grade projects;
- The requirement that the lowest-cost abatement is awarded will direct
most, if not all grants towards energy efficiency projects leaving carbon farming,
energy generation, fugitive emissions from mining and transport will all be
uncompetitive and cast aside from the ERF;
- Because it is optional, there is no incentive for polluters to
participate. The costs for firms to prepare tenders means the scheme will be
underutilised resulting in low participation, an inability to spend the grant
money but higher total abatement costs because of less competitive pressure and
substantial departmental costs in operating the scheme. All these
characteristics were revealed by the Auditor-General in 2010 when reviewing the
Howard Government's Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme. The ERF is a rebirth of
that failed policy;
- There is nothing that will promote innovation and the deployment of
technological advances. This will result in a huge opportunity lost for our
research and development industries where Australia has a natural competitive
advantage; and
- Those projects that are most likely to be successfully subsidised by the
Fund will be low-cost, straightforward and have very short payback periods
meaning they were the projects that were most likely to happen without
government hand-outs. Firms will have delayed this investment in knowledge that
Direct Action will subsidise the changes.
1.6
The main accompanying policy in Direct Action is the baseline system
known in the Green Paper as the 'safeguard mechanism'. Without knowing much
detail on how it will work and the Minister having changed his mind several
times on whether there will be punishments or 'make good provisions' for
exceeding baselines, the inherent problems with such an approach is:
- It requires a guess as to how firms will perform in the future and
relies on the information provided by the firms as to how they have performed
in the past. It can never be accurate. In contrast, emissions trading measures
the actual emissions a firm sends into the atmosphere and makes them liable for
their performance.
- Any setting of the trajectory of a company's baseline emissions will
always be contested and uncertain. This means that any measurement of emissions
reductions will not be real, but just perceived against the estimate. This
process will promote rent-seeking and developing close relationships with
government to get a better outcome.[2]
- Designing, setting and monitoring baselines is a very expensive and
time-consuming task for departmental staff to be constantly engaged in. Even
after all this work is finalised, there is far from any guarantee that less
emissions will be put in the atmosphere as a result.
- Most of the money spent on the program will be sucked up by departmental
costs, meaning that there will be high costs for very little abatement in
greenhouse gases.
1.7
Finally, Direct Action as it is currently imagined will seal the fate of
the short‑lived Carbon Farming Initiative. Instead of land-based
abatement projects having a market to sell their Australian Carbon Credit Units
(ACCUs), there will only be one buyer—the Federal Government. There will no
longer be any identifiable market value of ACCUs, farmers will be bidding blind
and the significantly higher risks involved will result in farmers and land
managers leaving the market altogether.
1.8
A land manager would have to bid into the auction against all other
competitors in cheaper areas such as energy efficiency. Farmers have the major
barrier of not being well positioned to aggregate projects to bring their costs
down.[3]
This is compounded by the government’s stated intention to prefer large-scale
projects.[4]
1.9
Land-based abatement will not be competitive enough to reach the
expected tender price of around $8 per tonne.[5]
The Aboriginal Carbon Fund stated that savannah burning requires a price of $15
per tonne to be profitable[6]
while Sustainable Energy Now identified a price of $16-25 a tonne for tree
planting to be viable. These fledgling industries will have to close.
1.10
Soil carbon will be far more expensive than these two approved and
comparatively simple abatement methods. Soil carbon is the preferred abatement
method for the government which seeks to achieve a staggering 60% of its 431
million tonnes target from soil carbon.[7]
1.11
In the hope of making this commitment a reality the government has announced
it will reduce permanency requirements from 100 to 25 years and will permit a
methodology that will not have scientific integrity. There is no scientifically
agreed methodology to support soil carbon being included on the CFI positive
list and the government cannot name any scientific institution that has a
robust methodology to date.
1.12
Even with this abandoning of scientific integrity for soil carbon there
is unlikely to be any activity in soil carbon under the Direct Action proposal
as it is estimated to cost around $36 per tonne,[8]
far short of the estimated $8 benchmark price.
The Report's Recommendations
1.13
The Australian Greens endorse this report in full with the exception of
Recommendation 5. The Greens do not support bringing forward the floating price
period for the following reasons.
1.14
A carbon price is used to drive a seamless transition to a low carbon
economy. It is not in the interests of this goal to make it temporarily cheaper
for big polluters to emit greenhouse gases at the same time that the European
Union is rebuilding its trading price following its decision in February to
backload its permit auctions.[9]
An extra fixed price year is necessary to minimise the dislocation for clean
technology investors.
1.15
It is clear that there would be no move to bring forward flexible
pricing if the European Union price was €20
or more. This is a cynical move based on making it cheaper for big polluters.
It is not a policy position responding to the accelerating global warming
crisis.
1.16
There is insufficient time and a lack of preparation with our European
Union trading partners for the floating price period to commence on 1 July 2014.
Contributing to this lack of time and preparation was the Australian Labor
Party's decision to support the government's removal of regulations that guided
the auction of forward permits in the Senate. Without the regulatory procedures
to guide the Clean Energy Regulator, an immediate auction could not proceed
with clarity and certainty for participating businesses.
Senator
Christine Milne
Leader of the Australian Greens
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page