Chapter 2
Issues to do with separation of Telstra
Provisions of the bill on separation of Telstra
Addressing Telstra's vertical
integration
2.1
The bill provides that Telstra must separate either functionally or
structurally. The Government argues that separation of Telstra is needed
because:
-
Telstra is one of the most integrated telecommunications
companies in the world;
-
partly because of this integration, it has been able to maintain
a dominant position in virtually all aspects of the market despite more than 10
years of open competition; and
-
Telstra's high level of integration has hindered the development
of effective competition.[1]
2.2
The default position is that Telstra must functionally separate
according to a functional separation undertaking approved by the Minister. The
bill requires Telstra to comply with 'functional separation principles' listed
in the bill, including that there should be equivalence in relation to the
supply by Telstra of regulated services to its wholesale customers and its
retail business units, and related matters.[2]
2.3
Alternatively, Telstra may voluntarily structurally separate: that is,
the ACCC may accept an undertaking from Telstra that -
-
Telstra will not supply fixed-line carriage services to retail
customers using a telecommunications network over which Telstra is in a
position to exercise control; and
-
Telstra will not be in a position to exercise control of a
company that supplies fixed-line carriage services to retail customers using a
telecommunications network over which Telstra is in a position to exercise
control.[3]
2.4
If a structural separation undertaking is in force, Telstra does not
have to comply with the provisions about functional separation.[4]
The Government's stated preference is that Telstra should voluntarily
structurally separate.[5]
2.5
According to the explanatory memorandum, Telstra could undertake
structural separation in several ways:
A few examples are:
-
Telstra may elect to facilitate the transfer of the provision of fixed-line
carriage services to its retail customers to another carriage service provider,
over which Telstra is not in a position to exercise control.
-
Telstra may establish a new company to supply fixed-line carriage services to
its retail customers and divest enough of its interests in that company to
ensure that it is no longer in a position to exercise control of that company.
-
Telstra may elect to progressively migrate the traffic of its retail customers
to another national network for the provision of fixed-line carriage services,
such network being a network over which Telstra is not in a position to
exercise control.[6]
Addressing Telstra's horizontal
integration
2.6
The bill prevents Telstra from acquiring specified bands of spectrum,
which could be used for advanced wireless broadband services, unless it
structurally separates and divests its hybrid fibre coaxial (HFC) cable network
and its interests in subscription television broadcasting licences (ie Foxtel).
However the Minister may exempt Telstra from the requirements in relation to
HFC networks and subscription television broadcasting licences if the Minister
is satisfied that Telstra’s structural separation undertaking is sufficient to
address concerns about the degree of Telstra’s power in telecommunications
markets.[7]
2.7
The Government supports this measure on the grounds that:
Telstra’s level of horizontal integration across the
different delivery platforms—copper, cable and mobile—is in contrast to many
countries where there are restrictions on incumbents owning both cable and
traditional fixed-line telephone networks.... Telstra’s horizontal integration
has significantly contributed to Telstra’s ongoing dominance in the Australian
telecommunications market.[8]
Submissions on separation of Telstra
Submissions supporting the bill
2.8
Most submissions from stakeholder companies or consumer interest groups
supported separation of Telstra.[9]
Their core argument supports the government's view that Telstra's level of
vertical integration has allowed Telstra to behave monopolistically, to the
detriment of competition and Australian consumers. For example:
A number of international comparisons show Australia with
higher prices, less innovative offerings and poorer service levels including
broadband speeds and switching practices. ATUG believes this is due to lack of
effective competition in the telco sector. Examples include OECD Communications
Outlook 2009 and Oxford Business School Broadband Quality Score 2009.[10]
Telstra continues to identify the number of new carrier
licences and ongoing price reductions as indicators of a vibrant, competitive
marketplace, completely ignoring the figures included in the explanatory
memorandum which show the extraordinarily high figures for the HHI, the
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, for this industry. That is a standard measure of
concentration in industry that shows this industry is basically as concentrated
as a dysfunctional duopoly.[11]
2.9
Some noted that Telstra's market dominance has increased in recent
years; for example:
Data from recent Telstra annual reports further shows how
quickly competition has retreated in recent years. In the past three years
there has been a fall of 290,000 individual consumers lines connected to
competitors. This is a fall of 12.75% compared to a loss of 0.6% of basic
access lines by Telstra Retail in the same period.[12]
2.10
Submissions argued that functional separation has been successful in the
United Kingdom:
Perhaps the most compelling endorsement of separation is
provided by Ofcom which, following a recent assessment of the impact of the
separation arrangements introduced by BT, has concluded that separation has
been successful in delivering improved competition in the UK.[13]
2.11
Infrastructure Partnerships Australia noted the benefits of structural
separation listed in a 2003 OECD report and supported by the 1993 Hilmer report
on national competition policy:
The [Hilmer] report advocated the separation of natural monopoly
components (such as fixed copper network) from competitive functions (such as
retail services).[14]
2.12
Optus submitted that criticisms of separation 'do not stand up to
scrutiny':
These criticisms fail to acknowledge that the reforms have
been well signalled and that they are aimed squarely at delivering improved
outcomes for all Australians by putting the industry on to a more competitive
basis. The experience of the UK and New Zealand demonstrate the benefits that
separation brings in terms of delivering pro-competitive outcomes.[15]
2.13
The department argued that the dominance of one player in the market was
such that action was required:
In the explanatory memorandum is a quote by Lord David Currie
in the UK:
All that is needed is for the
incumbent not to try their hardest to achieve reliability, timeliness and
predictability to disrupt significantly the launch by competitors of a rival
retail proposition.
... It is at that end, not who is the largest mobile phone
player, the largest wireless player or the largest fixed-line player. It is
about that competition angle. Are you able to disrupt someone’s ability simply
by not trying hard because across your set of businesses that part of your
business that does infrastructure supply can simply say, ‘I think I’ll just be
passive in the face of this person’s needs. I might delay it or lose it or
sleep on it.’ None of that is unusual behaviour in marketplaces, and we all
know it. The question in this is: has it arrived at a point where it
sufficiently impedes supply of innovative services to consumers and businesses?
The conclusion we have reached is that it does.[16]
Other suggestions from supporters
of the bill
2.14
Supporters of separation made some detailed suggestions for amendments.
The Competitive Carriers Coalition (CCC) argued that the principles for
functional separation should be legislated in more detail.[17]
The CCC argued that it should be legislated that Telstra must at once implement
changes to remove its incentives to discriminate against other retailers,
although structural separation may take some years.[18]
Unwired Australia argued that the legislation should provide more detail about
the grounds on which the Minister may exempt Telstra from the pay TV and HFC
network divestment provisions.[19]
Unwired Australia suggested that if Telstra breaches a functional separation
undertaking, the ACCC should be able to apply to the Federal Court to force
divestiture.[20]
Submissions opposing the bill
2.15
Stakeholder groups who opposed the separation provisions were Telstra
and a number of investment managers or shareholder interest groups concerned
about the likely effect of the changes on the value of Telstra shares.[21]
Their main arguments were:
-
separation will discourage investment or cause efficiency losses;
-
separation will have high transitional costs for Telstra;
-
separation will reduce Telstra's share value.
2.16
Submissions from individual Telstra shareholders mostly focussed on the
third point.
Effects on efficiency and
investment
2.17
Investors Mutual argued that economic literature supports vertical
integration:
In industries that face significant uncertainties only
vertically integrated firms are the most economically efficient allocator of
resources.[22]
2.18
Telstra argued similarly that vertical integration 'reduces costs and
facilitates innovation and is supported by international studies'.[23]
In reply Unwired Australia said:
...Telstra also claims that separation is not required if it
makes a series of changes in the wholesale regime to provide transparency and
equivalence. I do not know how you can reconcile those two views: that you can
get equivalency and transparency in a wholesale structure with a vertically
integrated firm, yet the vertically integrated firm has a lower cost structure
and a greater ability to innovate than any other firm in the market. Quite
frankly, if the first statement is true, that vertical integration reduces
costs and facilitates innovation, then we should not attempt to have a
competitive telco regime.[24]
2.19
The Australian Shareholders Association argued that the bill will
discourage investment:
International investors in particular will consider Australia
to have a much higher level of sovereign risk if this Bill is passed and the
Government allowed to impose its will on a private company.[25]
2.20
BT Investment Management submitted that:
It’s a circular argument to suggest that because Telstra owns
the only regulated bottleneck asset that it makes the bulk of fixed line market
profit and should be broken up...
Whoever owns it will make such a regulated profit.... We
consider that Telstra’s profit is high because it is a well run integrated
business and because of its high level of investment relative to its
competitors. [26]
2.21
Telstra argued the changes 'have the potential to significantly increase
regulatory uncertainty and hence reduce investment in telecommunications
markets.' Telstra noted that it has a 62 per cent share of the market but makes
70 per cent of telecommunications sector capital investment (implying that this
is a desirable result of the status quo). In reply Unwired Australia argued
that the right comparison is with profit, not market share; Telstra still has
90 per cent of the industry's profit; thus Telstra is under-investing: 'Only
people with market power can withhold investments'.[27]
Transitional costs
2.22
Telstra argued that the cost of separation would be in the range $500
million to $1.2 billion.[28]
In the Government's view 'it is unclear what assumptions Telstra’s claimed
implementation costs or effects on its share price are based on... Telstra’s
claims can be assumed to represent the upper bounds of possible costs.'[29]
2.23
Others disputed the likely cost of separation. Optus said:
These costs are unlikely to be anywhere near as much as
Telstra has claimed. Optus notes that BT, which is a considerably larger
company than Telstra, incurred costs of £153 Million in implementing a very
detailed and robust form of functional separation... In many respects the costs
to be incurred in implementing separation will simply be displacing costs the
industry incurs to date operating under the present regulatory arrangements. In
recent years the industry will have incurred costs of no less than $200 million
operating within the present regulatory arrangements.[30]
2.24
The Government has argued that:
Telstra's vertical integration affects all Australians and
the economy more generally through higher telecommunications prices and reduced
innovation and investment in the sector.... It is the Australian Government’s
considered view that the medium- and longer-term competition benefits for the
economy, business and end-users of implementing functional separation outweigh
the short-term costs to Telstra of implementing functional separation if
Telstra decides not to voluntarily structurally separate.[31]
Effect on Telstra's share value
2.25
Telstra and some other stakeholder groups argued that separation would
reduce Telstra's share value. These submissions were mostly from investment
managers.[32] [33]
Their concern about share value was usually coupled with an argument that the
separation envisaged by the bill was unfair as it was not foreshadowed at the time of privatisation:[34]
In all three public offers Telstra was marketed as a strong
investment on the basis of its large size and its position as the Australia’s
only integrated telecommunications company. The same assets that the Government
as now insisting Telstra divest were promoted strongly as reasons for
investment in the company... Obtaining full value for those assets in the
situation of a forced sale will be difficult.[35]
We believe that the proposed structural separation if it
occurs would result in a permanent reduction in shareholder value... the
Government will be penalising Telstra for being successful and thereby
penalising the many Telstra shareholders who relied on Government
representations.[36]
2.26
It was sometimes unclear whether the claim was that the increased
competition caused by separation would cause a transfer of profit from Telstra
to its competitors in a zero-sum game, or that the community as a whole would
lose because they believe Telstra's market dominance is economically efficient.
2.27
Supporters of the bill argued that 'the government must stand firm and
put the long term interests of all 22 million Australians ahead of the short
term interests of less than 2 million Telstra shareholders.'[37]
2.28
On the question of whether the bill is fair to Telstra shareholders, the
department argued that the three Telstra privatisation prospectuses mentioned
regulatory risk adequately:
I have a list here of the quite generic warnings that went in
every Telstra share offer: 1997, 1999 and 2006.
The 1997 offer said: 'There can be no assurance that the
current or future governments will not take further steps which alter Telstra’s
competitive position or the manner in which the Australian telecommunications
industry is regulated.'
In the 1999 offer: 'There is also a risk that current or
future governments will take steps that further alter Telstra’s competitive
position or the manner in which the Australian telecommunications industry is
regulated.'[38]
2.29
The T3 prospectus in 2006 said:
Regulation impacts the way Telstra does business and Telstra
believes it is the most significant ongoing risk to Telstra. There can be no
assurance as to future policies and regulatory outcomes. Regulatory outcomes
may be significantly adverse to Telstra shareholders.[39]
2.30
The Competitive Carriers Coalition argued that complaints that Telstra
shareholders have been betrayed should not be taken seriously, since:
-
Every Telstra sale tranche acknowledged the simple reality
that the regulation of telecommunications was subject to change;
-
Telstra shareholders are asking to have interests protected
that are immeasurable. It is impossible to know what regulatory action might
result in Telstra share movements over time. Functional separation of BT was
followed by share growth, while Telstra’s value has declined precipitously in
recent years while it was brutally exercising market power;
-
It is not the Government’s responsibility to protect the
interests of the shareholders of one company over the interests of other
companies’ shareholders, and certainly not ahead of the interests of all
citizens who have paid inflated prices for crucial communications services
because of Telstra’s unconstrained monopoly power....[40]
2.31
Supporters of the bill argued that in any case the likely detriment to
Telstra's share price is uncertain or overstated. For example:
The market reaction to the announced package of reforms has
been fairly mooted with Telstra’s share price recovering after an initial small
drop. More significantly, Optus notes that many industry analysts have retained
their “Buy” recommendations on the Telstra stock following the Government’s
announcement and predict share price accretion over the next twelve months as
these reforms are implemented.[41]
A more considered view is that these reforms address the
inherent regulatory uncertainty within the industry, and once the reforms are
implemented they will open up enormous potential for Telstra and other industry
participants to pursue significant growth opportunities.[42]
If you look at what happened in the UK, BT share price
actually improved relative to both the rest of the UK share market and to some
of its standout competitors on the European continent. It improved because a
lot of the uncertainty was removed and there was the promise that, over time,
other aspects of regulation that constrained them in retail markets would be
removed.[43]
2.32
The ACCC, in its submission to the Government's April 2009 National
Broadband Network discussion paper, stated that vertical separation can enhance
the value of separated firms. It reasoned that there may be some vertical dies-economies
of scope which may arise as a firm takes on additional functions which are
outside the scope of its core functions and which the firm is not well equipped
to perform. It gave examples of previous voluntary separations to support these
claims.[44]
Comments on horizontal separation
of Telstra
2.33
Generally, stakeholders who supported structurally separating Telstra
also supported horizontal separation:
Access to valuable content is likely to become an important
force driving the take-up of higher speed broadband services. This creates a
very real risk that a monopoly in premium content could be used to undermine
future competition in broadband services.[45]
The level of Telstra's horizontal integration across all
Australian telecommunications platforms, including fixed line, mobile, coaxial
fibre cable and Foxtel cable, is unusual if not unique among advanced
economies. Telstra's integration across all telecommunications technologies has
significantly contributed to the organisation's ongoing dominance in the
Australian telecommunications market and has allowed the organisation to
utilise undue influence to block market participants.[46]
The fact that FOXTEL has not extended its product portfolio
to offer a competing broadband access product, unlike other major pay TV
providers in the developed world, is a clear indication that the services and
products available to consumers are being limited by the integration of Telstra
and FOXTEL. AUSTAR believes that the divestiture of FOXTEL is a critical step
in addressing competition concerns raised by Telstra’s horizontal integration.[47]
2.34
Optus noted that the horizontal separation provisions are ultimately
discretionary and can be waived if the Minister is satisfied with the terms of
Telstra’s structural separation plan: 'On balance this approach appears
reasonable.' [48]
2.35
Opponents of the bill were often critical of horizontal separation.
These included:
-
Australian Foundation Investment Company: 'shareholders have
borne the risk of the [Foxtel and HFC] investments and should be allowed to
reap the rewards'; and
-
BT Investment Management: 'restricting Telstra's access to 4G
spectrum is counter-productive to effective industry development.'[49]
ACCC's role in structural or functional separation of Telstra
2.36
The provisions concerning structural separation give the ACCC the role
of accepting Telstra's undertaking concerning separation. If the ACCC considers
that Telstra has breached the undertaking it may apply to the Federal Court for
a remedy.[50]
2.37
The provisions concerning functional separation give the ACCC the role of
advising the Minister whether to accept a functional separation undertaking.[51]
The ACCC must monitor and report annually on Telstra's compliance with a
functional separation undertaking.[52]
2.38
Submissions were generally supportive of this role. The Competitive
Carriers Coalition urged that the process by which the ACCC considers
structural separation should have the highest level of public consultation, and
there should be more guidance to the ACCC on what would be acceptable in an
undertaking by Telstra.[53]
2.39
Foxtel argued that the ACCC's discretion regarding Telstra's undertaking
to structurally separate would be too broad, and matters that the ACCC should
consider should be set out in the bill.[54]
Committee comment
2.40
The object of telecommunications policy is to promote innovation in
telecommunications, and more efficient and competitive services for the
community as a whole. The Committee accepts the view of the Government and most
industry stakeholders that the separation of Telstra will bring long term
benefits.
2.41
In the committee's view the three Telstra sale prospectuses were clear
enough about the potential of regulatory changes in the telecommunication
sector that might affect Telstra's competitive position. The committee notes
that in any case there is a lack of consensus around what might be the long
terms effects of separation on Telstra's share price.
2.42
It is not the government's role to support the share value of one
telecommunications company in preference to its competitors, however the
committee does not believe that sufficient evidence has been presented that
these regulatory reforms will be detrimental to Telstra's share price. The enhanced
consumer protections offered in the bill, the greater regulatory certainty that
will be brought about by its passage, and the improved efficiency and
competition in the sector as a result, should together ensure a sound future
for all Australia's telecommunications providers.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page