Chapter 6 - A blueprint for the future
I have always said that one thing the
government missed was a blueprint for telecommunications in Australia.
Where is the vision? What do we want to do? Where does structural separation
fit? Where does the monopoly fit? Where can we have competition? Unless we map
the whole thing and say what is needed, we will be having Senate inquiries like
this for the next five or 10 years. That is what will happen unless somebody
says, ‘This is the blueprint and this is the grand plan of action that we have
to put in place.’ The government never took the initiative; Telstra never took
the initiative. Unless we do such a thing we will always have contradictory
elements.[616]
6.1
In this report the Committee has highlighted a wide
range of matters within the current telecommunications regulatory regime which
impede competition and investment and do not adequately protect consumers. Most
glaring is the lack of a long-term strategic vision for telecommunications
throughout Australia.
The Committee concurs with the comments made by the Hon John Anderson MP, then
Deputy Prime Minister:
I have said several times over the past months that the real
telecommunications debate should be about securing the services that regional Australia
needs, not about selling a phone company. Today in Australia
we have what is essentially a 19th century telephone system trying to serve a
21st century information economy. What we should be doing is looking ahead. ... Our
responsibility, though, is to the national interest and the interests of
regional Australia
- and we will only serve their interests if we can create a 21st
telecommunications system for Australia.[617]
6.2
The Government's intention to privatise Telstra fully
as soon as possible appears to have diminished its will to develop this
long-term strategic view. Ms Rosalind
Eason from the CEPU argued there was 'a kind
of policy vacuum' in telecommunications:
... as far as the long view goes, the impending privatisation has
brought all of these strange ideas out of the woodwork, and some are stranger
than others. It is muddying the waters. It is very hard to have a policy debate
now about what sort of regulatory framework we might need in the next 10 years
without it being overlaid by the whole privatisation question. On the one hand
is the notion that the government is rejecting all ideas simply because it wants
to enhance the share price...On the other hand are various interests, more or
less opportunistic depending upon where they come from, who see this as the
moment—the kind of ‘we have only three months to get it right otherwise this
country is doomed’ sort of argument—to gain policy leverage. The whole thing
seems to us a very unfortunate conjuncture. That is why we have argued that the
privatisation matter should be put aside for the time being. Let us look at the
regulatory framework, let us look at new generation networks, the changes
happening and what is needed to roll out a modern communications suite of
services in Australia,
then let us perhaps come back to that matter 10 years down the track.[618]
6.3
As outlined in chapter 2, a dominant theme which
emerged during the inquiry was that insufficient progress has been made in
providing adequate telecommunications services to rural and regional Australia.
Further, there is broad community concern that the situation will worsen once
Telstra is fully privatised.
6.4
The Committee notes the Government's commitment to the
Telstra sale being conditional on adequate telecommunication service levels in
rural and regional Australia,[619] and urges the Government to honour
this pledge, including by holding off on passing the necessary legislation
until the condition is met. Accordingly, the Committee has kept the desired
outcome of improved rural and regional telecommunications services at the forefront
during the development of its recommendations.
6.5
The Committee was encouraged by the Minister's recent
announcement that a licence condition was soon to be placed on Telstra
compelling it to maintain a focus on rural services:
I expect to be imposing a Licence Condition on Telstra by the
end of the month ... This is not negotiable – T3 or no T3 – Telstra will be
required to maintain their level of service to the bush. ... Telstra will be
working over the coming weeks to present me with a workable and responsive
rural presence plan.[620]
6.6
The Committee notes that the Government announced on 4 August 2005 that such a licence
condition had been imposed.[621]
Telstra is required to develop a local presence plan which will be open for
public comment for at least six weeks and is subject to the Minister's
approval.[622] However, the Committee
emphasises that the value of such measures will depend almost entirely on their
final content.
6.7
This chapter summarises the findings of this inquiry
and proposes a number of initiatives in response in the following areas:
- the structure of Telstra;
- the ACCC;
- the TPA: Part XIB and section 46;
- the TPA: Part XIC;
- meeting consumer demands;
- the USO; and
- other consumer protection issues
The structure of Telstra: achieving greater transparency
6.8
In Chapter 3, the Committee discussed Part XIB of the
TPA, which is the regulatory mechanism aimed at addressing anti-competitive
behaviour in the telecommunications sector. A number of weaknesses in the
mechanism were identified. Central to the problem are Telstra's capacity to
mask the delineation between its wholesale and retail costs and the limitations
on the ACCC's ability to establish anti-competitive conduct.
6.9
The Committee has heard evidence which suggests that
the lack of transparency between Telstra's wholesale and retail costs is a
significant impediment to the effectiveness of the TPA.[623] Further, attempts to address this
issue, such as the introduction in 2002 of the enhanced accounting separation
regime (discussed in Chapter 3), have not given the ACCC a satisfactory means
of determining whether Telstra operates so as to give its retail arm an
advantage over its wholesale customers. As Optus submitted:
There is ongoing debate concerning the separation of Telstra. At
the heart of this debate is the concern that Telstra will continue to have
strong incentives to favour its own retail operations at the expense of
competitors who are wholesale customers. These incentives are very difficult to
detect or curtail. Optus is well aware of, and experiences on a daily basis,
Telstra’s behaviour in this respect.
The accounting separation regime that was introduced in 2002
required greater disclosure by Telstra of its costings and internal pricing. This
was designed to make it easier for both the ACCC and Telstra’s competitors to
determine if Telstra was favouring its own retail operations.
The result has been disappointing, a fact recognised by both the
industry and the ACCC. The information being provided is far too disaggregated
to be used in any meaningful way, and the ACCC has indicated that there is little
potential for improvement.[624]
6.10
In response to this lack of transparency and Telstra's
monopoly over the network, a number of models have been suggested which aim to
provide a clearer indication of Telstra's internal wholesale price to its
retail business. As Mr Ian Slattery from Primus told the Committee:
The arguments behind structural reform and structural
rearrangements of Telstra are at the heart of the issue as to what is currently
stifling competition, and they are Telstra’s monopoly or control over key
network elements which display monopoly characteristics which competitors rely
on as an upstream input to provide competitive retail services. The fact is
that Telstra is dominant in just about every market segment of
telecommunications. They are the drivers behind why structural arrangements
within Telstra need to be considered.[625]
6.11
The models most frequently proposed in response to lack
of transparency are structural separation and operational separation. These
models are reviewed below.
Structural separation
6.12
One proposed remedy is the structural separation of
Telstra into two separate organisations, that is, wholesale and retail. The
Australian Consumers' Association supported this approach:
... because if the normal logic of wholesale competition were
allowed to operate, access would become less of a foreground issue.[626]
6.13
Mr David
Spence from Unwired Australia told the
Committee that structural separation would stimulate competition and innovation.[627]
6.14
An article by Professor Peter
Gerrand[628] examined the arguments for
and against structural separation of Telstra, and in particular the buyback of
the 'natural monopoly' of Telstra's fixed network into public sector ownership.
Professor Gerrand
noted that the benefits of a buy-back were offset by the prospect of two major
electoral liabilities: the anger of minority Telstra shareholders if they lost
shareholder value and the excessive demands on the federal budget in the year
of the buy-back. Professor Gerrand
supported a hybrid solution, a two-stage process, whereby both the costs and
risks to the government could be significantly minimised.
6.15
However, arguments against structural separation of
Telstra are based upon claims of cost and complexity, akin to 'unscrambling an
omelette'.[629] Telstra argued that
structural separation would be costly and would result in a loss of efficiency:
It has become apparent that structural separation in
telecommunications imposes large costs in terms of efficiency and international
competitiveness. Structural separation results in a loss of the efficiencies
that are achieved through vertical integration. As a result, customers are
forced to bear higher costs. In addition, it is not clear that there are
significant benefits from separation, especially not of the order required to
outweigh the substantial costs involved.[630]
6.16
However, the true cost and complexity of the task of
structurally separating Telstra are unknown. The ACCC Chairman, Mr
Graeme Samuel,
told the Committee:
I think it is fair to say that there has been some work—but not
an extensive amount of work—done into the cost and benefits associated with
structural separation. The process that has been discussed by the ACCC in
previous submissions—and I think you referred to a document signed off by me
which would have involved a previous role that I had with the National
Competition Council—has indicated that it may have been beneficial to examine
the costs and benefits associated with structural separation. I am not aware
that such a detailed examination of those costs and benefits has been
undertaken.[631]
6.17
The Productivity Commission concluded in its recent
report on National Competition Policy Reform:
In such a rapidly changing environment, were full vertical
structural separation to be pursued, it could be very difficult to determine
precisely where the split should be made. Consequently, the scope for
regulatory error, and its attendant costs, would be high.[632]
6.18
Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra told the Committee that
'some constructs of structural separation' would now be 'technically impossible
to do':
What is often not taken into account in this structural
separation debate is that Telstra is a much more complex beast than it was
five, 10 or 15 years ago. At that time—and I am overstating it here—it was a
relatively straightforward copper network. Now we have copper; fibre; a layer
on top of that, which is IT systems; and a layer on top of that, IP systems.
They are completely integrated, so the question becomes: how do you make an
appropriate separation of that, without virtually having Telstra as it
currently is? ... To be quite frank, I have not seen anybody who has done any of
the work to be able to make the appropriate judgements about the costs and
benefits.[633]
6.19
Mr Stephen
Dalby from iiNet argued that in any case,
structural separation would not provide adequate transparency:
Structural separation between retail and wholesale does not
solve the problem for me when I am dealing simply with Wholesale. I might never
deal with Retail, although their behaviour may still affect me. I am trying to
strike a deal where I am moving from high-margin wholesale products to
low-margin wholesale products and negotiating with somebody that does not want
that to happen. I wonder really whether that is another layer of separation
that is required between these sorts of full function wholesale products versus
the bare bones building blocks.[634]
6.20
The Committee was also told that attempts to modify the
structure of the industry by legislation was unlikely to be more productive
than allowing regulatory and market processes to run their course:
It is yet to be demonstrated that legislated structural changes
in other industries in Australia
have produced superior long-term results than could have been achieved by other
less disruptive means. ... In telecommunications such separation would be likely
to result in inappropriate as well as inadequate investment in infrastructure;
that is assuming that the 'infrastructure' could actually be identified
separately from services equipment and after it was done, that the purpose or
use of the infrastructure would be known.[635]
6.21
Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra criticised the ACCC's
support for structural separation, arguing that accounting separation, the
mechanism currently employed to produce internal transparency between Telstra's
wholesale and retail businesses, had not been fully implemented and given an
opportunity to work:
We have not even fully implemented accounting separation, and
yet people in the ACCC are saying it does not work. So the question for an
organisation like Telstra when it goes before the board is: what do we say
about that? Because, on the face of it, it looks as though we have a regulator
that has decided that it wants to have structural separation of the company;
and to ensure that it puts itself in the best position to argue the policy case
for structural separation it will undermine.[636]
6.22
As both ATUG[637]
and Optus[638] noted, the Government
has made it clear that it has no intention of considering structural separation
of Telstra.[639] Mr
Peter Lindsay MP
told the Committee he opposed any form of forced separation of Telstra, which should
be allowed as a private company 'to make its own decisions about what it does
and how it runs its business'.[640]
However, some industry analysts believe that Telstra will eventually
structurally separate of its own accord. Mr
Paul Budde
told the Committee:
I am absolutely against forced structural separation. It is the
wrong way to go. It is politically totally impossible, so let us not even argue
about it, because that would be a waste of time. Structural separation will
automatically happen. Telstra is going to structurally separate itself—there is
no doubt in my mind about that—within the next five years. So let us assist it
to actually find the right sorts of models that will push it in a particular
direction rather than forcing it upon it when nobody wants it.[641]
6.23
Mr Budde
argued that Telstra had already begun internally separating:
You would be surprised how far Telstra have already moved
themselves in that direction. They will not tell you, but they have. There is a
very good wholesale division. The people in wholesale would be laughing and
jumping up and down if we did do structural separation. These are all good
people who want to look after their wholesale business. They all want to do the
best thing for their wholesale customers. So they would love to be passionate
about wholesale and sell the right to the services to their customers. ... If you
simply separate the wholesale division in that situation then the rest will
automatically follow because then the wholesale division
will get a much better focus and the retail division will get a much
better focus.[642]
6.24
Optus noted that during the 1980s, the US
government imposed a break up on the dominant company, AT&T. The company was
split into a long distance company and seven local telephony companies, each
under separate ownership.[643] The
Committee sought evidence on comparable arrangements in other Australian market
sectors such as energy. Mr Paul
Broad from PowerTel stated:
It is worth recognising that, in the energy sector, once a
private sector company got involved, for example in Victoria,
they immediately separated their network business from their retail business.
When owned by governments, the big conglomerates were the way to go. They
subsidised their retail businesses through their regulated businesses. They hid
all their back-office costs in the regulated businesses so that their retail
businesses could be competitive. They destroyed value. Once they were sold, the
private sector recognised that the market will rate the retail businesses
differently from the network businesses. ... The market will adapt. Once the
market signals are clear through the industry structure, then in my view we are
more likely to attract foreign investment compared to what we have today, which
is uncertainty about what structures are likely to emerge.[644]
6.25
The Productivity Commission argued that the transaction
cost to full structural separation would be large and therefore:
... such transaction cost considerations now tip the balance against
the full vertical separation of Telstra, regardless of the intrinsic merits of
a separated structure in a ‘greenfields’ situation. However, given the
continuing concerns about Telstra’s capacity to discriminate against its retail
competitors in the provision of network services, greater operational
separation is worth further consideration. ... Though the potential benefits
would be smaller than those on offer from full vertical separation, so too
would be the attendant efficiency and transaction costs.[645]
6.26
Some witnesses such as Mr
Charles Britton
from the Australian Consumers' Association pointed out that the need to engage
in a debate about restructuring Telstra remains:
We would accept some of the arguments about the fact that the
Telstra omelette is scrambled, if you like, and you cannot separate it out et
cetera. We would not have any sympathy for the notion that therefore we should
not move on to a debate about operational separation. ... It is certainly timely
to talk about operational separation because the time to talk about structural
separation may have passed but the problem that structural separation would
address has not passed. It is an ongoing reality that we have got a vertically
integrated, horizontally sprawling incumbent sitting in the middle of the
market.[646]
Operational separation
6.27
In light of the Government's rejection of structural
separation, an operational separation model is gaining momentum. As Mr Samuel
from the ACCC stated:
Operational separation is a concept that seems to be finding
favour with a number of significant stakeholders in the debate over the future
of Telstra – these include Government and Opposition spokesmen, Telstra’s
competitors and it seems, from media reports, possibly even elements of Telstra
itself. The ACCC is strongly supportive of the concept of operational
separation. [647]
6.28
Noting that there had been some confusion about what
was meant by operational separation, Mr Samuel
clarified the difference in the following way:
The essential difference between the two is that of ownership.
Both types of separation involve establishing some parts of Telstra as separate
business entities. Under structural separation these separate business entities
would be sold to new owners and would no longer be part of Telstra. Under
operational separation these separate business entities remain as part of
Telstra.[648]
6.29
Witnesses and submissions supported the concept as a
pragmatic alternative. Mr Ewan
Brown from SETEL told the Committee:
We have now developed a policy of operational separation because
we believe that it is feasible in the current mind-set and the current
marketplace environment. Given the limited extent of the powers of the ACCC, we
feel that there is an element of goodwill, and an element of pressure might be
able to bring that to bear and achieve that transparency of operation between
the wholesale and retail sectors which would really allow the provisions of the
Trade Practices Act to work properly in this marketplace.[649]
6.30
However, Mr John
Feil, Executive Director of the National
Competition Council, noted that operational separation was a 'trade-off':
... between the scope and complexity of regulation required to
moderate Telstra’s market power and the structure of the business. Structural
separation is likely to address both the ability and incentives for
anticompetitive behaviour, whereas lower order separation is likely to reduce
the ability to engage in anticompetitive behaviour principally by making such
action more apparent, along with the attendant regulatory consequences. But it
will have limited effects on the underlying incentive to utilise market power.
It is possible that structural separation would allow for less regulation
especially of those parts of the business that exhibit natural monopoly
characteristics and can be effectively separated from commercial activities.[650]
6.31
Similarly, Mr David
Forman from the CCC stated:
We regard operational separation as a mechanism by which you
seek to emulate as far as possible the outcomes that you would see in a
structurally separate Telstra with the recognition that without full structural
separation you can never get to the core incentive on Telstra that has been
identified in the past by the ACCC to discriminate against access seekers who
are its competitors at a retail level.[651]
What operational separation would
require
6.32
Mr Samuel
told the Committee:
... an ACCC enforced operational separation would enable us to
achieve the objective that I outlined in my opening statement, which is to be
able to promote effective competition in the telecommunications sector.[652]
6.33
The ACCC outlined its proposal for operational
separation in the following terms in its submission to the Productivity
Commission’s review of National Competition Policy:
Under this arrangement, each business would have its own
management, location and information systems, and operate as an independent
profit centre with specific objectives. The wholesale business would be
expected to treat both its internal retail counterpart and external third party
retailers at arm’s length and on a non-discriminatory basis. Legal or corporate
separation is a potential variation where the entities take the form of legally
separated firms.[653]
6.34
During this inquiry, the ACCC submitted that
operational separation would need to be underpinned by formalised arrangements,
including requirements that the two businesses:
-
deal with each other on a commercial arms-length
basis, including transparent pricing arrangements between Telstra’s wholesale
and retail arms as well as separate invoicing and billing;
- maintain fully separate accounts and reporting
systems, capable of capturing all transactions between the businesses; and
- maintain separate staff at all levels, with
staff remuneration tied exclusively to the performance of the relevant
separated business.[654]
6.35
The Australian Consumers' Association supported
'effective' operational separation, which would require 'ring-fencing' of
Telstra's retail and wholesale activities:
This should be more than just a strengthening of the accounting
separation framework and is more than the mere development of a separate wholesale
division within Telstra. It is necessary to effectively ring-fence Telstra
network operations from retail activities. This would create an internal
separation between a ‘retail business’ supplying services to consumers, and a
‘network business’ supplying network or wholesale services to both Telstra retail
and retail competitors. Such ring-fencing would have the following
characteristics:
- Maintenance of
separate legal entities for internal business units;
- Allocation of
costs in a reasonable manner;
- Transparent
pricing arrangements between wholesale and retail arms;
- Separate invoicing
and billing systems;
- Fully separate
accounts and reporting systems;
- Limitations on common staff and sharing
confidential customer information; and
- Staff incentives
linked exclusively to the relevant business unit.[655]
6.36
Optus argued that an effective operational separation
model would need to include:
- The establishment of Telstra’s access
division as a separate operational entity. Under this measure, Telstra Retail
would acquire the same services as access seekers. A transfer price would be
clear and visible, and Telstra Retail and Telstra Wholesale could be required
to prepare accounts based on retail prices.
- The establishment of requirements for
price and non-price non-discrimination by Telstra Wholesale, i.e. a clear
non-discrimination rule. Enforcement action to address breaches of the
non-discrimination requirements could be obtained in the absence of proof that
the breach has resulted in a substantial lessening of competition.
- The creation of monitoring and reporting
requirements for the regulator on measures of discrimination. Such monitoring
could focus on, for example, the access prices that Telstra charges its retail
division compared with those charged to its competitors, and the Service Level
Agreements (SLAs) applicable to Telstra Retail compared to those of its
competitors.[656]
6.37
The Committee heard that some of Telstra's competitors
supported operational separation if it delivered a level of transparency that
would address Telstra's current discriminatory practices against its wholesale
customers. Mr David
Forman from the CCC told the Committee:
We have argued that operational separation needs to deliver
transparency, but that transparency is there not as a means of itself—that is
accounting separation. It needs to deliver the ability for the regulator to
look for acts of discrimination. ... The other elements of the regime such as
separate boards, separate staff—and, we would argue, separate locations for a
number of operations, if that is not one of those issues—go to behaviour and to
the ability to discriminate. It is not simply about prices; it is about
discrimination that manifests itself in other ways. We have discussed it in
various documents: information asymmetry, information leakage, the issues of
Telstra’s ability to see into some of the arrangements that appear to be
conducted between a competitor and Telstra Wholesale and for some of that
information to apparently find its way into Telstra’s retail business.[657]
6.38
ATUG submitted that accounting separation was
'ineffective and not likely to work, as it is based only on notional data and
does not reflect actual prices/transactions between Telstra Wholesale and
Telstra Retail'.[658] ATUG argued that
operational separation was needed and that certain requirements must be met:
One of the outcomes of any move to Operational Separation must
be explicitly agreed contracts between Telstra wholesale and Retail which can
be mirrored with competitors to ensure equivalent access (price and non-price)
is being provided and to ensure that the behavioural and incentive changes that
are needed in Telstra for competition to be effective can occur. A critical
part of implementation of operational separation will be the introduction of
information systems to provide a high degree of confidence that equivalent
access is being delivered.[659]
The UK
experience
6.39
Optus highlighted the United Kingdom's (UK) approach in
relation to its market incumbent, BT. UK regulator OFCOM released a Strategic Review Telecommunications Phase 2
Consultation Document in November 2004 which argued that equivalence of
access must be tackled 'head-on'. Equivalence of access refers to the same or
similar regulated wholesale products, at the same price and using the same or
similar processes. In OFCOM's view, creating equivalence requires both organisational
and behavioural change:
- “Significant shift
in [the incumbent’s] behaviour at an organisational level in support of
equivalence at the product level
- “Changes in
management structures, incentives and business processes, which today remain as
a consequence of [the incumbent’s] historic structure as a vertically-integrated
operator
- “Information flows
within [the incumbent] which mirror the information flows between [the
incumbent] and its wholesale customers,
so that its customers are able to influence
[the incumbent] to the same
extent that different parts of [the incumbent] can influence each other
- “That this level
of equivalence within the organisation can be demonstrated through
transparency” (p15).[660]
6.40
OFCOM had noted that one option for consideration in
relation to BT was reference of the matter for investigation by the Competition
Commission under the Enterprise Act 2002
(UK), a possible outcome being the structural separation of BT. In February
2005, BT offered some voluntary changes to its business and organisational
structure and OFCOM has worked with them and other industry participants since
that time.[661]
6.41
On 20 June
2005, OFCOM published details of its new approach to regulation of
the UK's fixed
line telecommunications market.[662] BT
had offered legally binding undertakings[663]
in lieu of a reference under the Enterprise Act 2002 (UK)
to the Competition Commission and these were accepted by the OFCOM Board,
subject to final consultation.[664]
6.42
BT's undertakings include the following:
- An operationally separate business unit will be
established, provisionally entitled Access Services, to be staffed by about
30,000 BT employees currently responsible for BT's local access networks. The
unit will have separate physical locations for management teams, separate
employee bonus schemes, separate operating and trading systems and, in time,
new branding which emphasises its operational separation.
- The new unit will be required through formal
rules on governance and separation to support all providers' retail activities
on a precisely equivalent basis called 'Equivalence of Input'. This means that
all providers will benefit from the same products, prices and processes, to
ensure that they can order, install, maintain and migrate connections on equal
terms.
- The new unit will offer a universally available
product and service set, comprising Local Loop Unbundling products, all forms
of wholesale line rental and backhaul products. Equivalence of Input will also
apply to BT's wholesale internet products used by many ISPs to provide
broadband connections.
- There will be 'a number of clear principles'
which BT should follow in the design, procurement and guild of its next
generation 21st Century Network, in order to help ensure other
providers who rely on the network do not suffer competitive disadvantage.
- A new Equality of Access Board will monitor
compliance with the undertakings (but will not be an operating management
board).[665]
6.43
OFCOM's Chief Executive Stephen
Carter was quoted as saying:
The OFCOM Board proposed to accept BT Group plc's proposed
undertakings on the critical assumption that BT Group plc does not merely
deliver the letter of the undertakings, but also the spirit.[666]
Regulatory models in other sectors
6.44
As noted earlier, the Committee sought further
information about regulatory models in other market sectors during this
inquiry. In the Australian energy sector, models exist for ‘ring-fencing’ the
monopoly and competitive activities of utility companies.
6.45
Both the National Gas Code and mandatory guidelines
issued by the ACCC under the National Electricity Code contain ring-fencing provisions
that have been operating for some time. Under these provisions, utilities are
required to maintain separate legal entities for their internal business units.
These arrangements do not preclude the separate businesses from being owned by
the same shareholders, but they improve transparency and address underlying
incentives to engage in discriminatory behaviour.[667] Mr
Paul Broad
from PowerTel Ltd told the Committee:
In all the energy businesses I know around
the world, separation from network and retail has occurred in some form or
other. With regard to the model that the ACCC are referring to, businesses in
fact did most of that. The ACCC encouraged it and threatened it. Of course,
they had the power to do it and made us all sit up and take notice. When we did
do it, it was the best thing for our businesses, because we could actually see
where we were making money, particularly in some of the old network businesses
that had retail attached to them and found the retail businesses were losing
lots of money.
To me, it is in Telstra’s best interests, in the market’s best
interests and in the interests of those who are competing. It goes to the heart
of: transparency and openness stops all these dead weight losses and the costs
involved in running inquiries and having regulators all over you. Surely, from
their perspective, they would want to be in the driving seat rather than be
driven to an outcome they are not comfortable with.[668]
6.46
In Melbourne,
the Committee heard from Mr Paul
Fearon, Chief Executive Officer with the
Essential Services Commission, who outlined ring-fencing arrangements in the
electricity and gas sectors:
The ring fencing for electricity and, for that matter, for
gas—and we are talking here principally about distribution and retailing—has
not been the issue that it has been with telecommunications. It comes back to
the fact that the contestable activities in energy and the natural monopoly
network elements are much more separable...
Nevertheless, we have put in place ring-fencing arrangements...The
ring fencing is essentially the financial or accounting separation, with what I
would call a relatively benign form of operational separation. That basically
comes down to separation of staff, access of information and some limits on
joint marketing. The reality is that there is not a strong internal driver to
keep these two businesses together anyway. In fact, those businesses that have
maintained both of those businesses have recognised that the value to their
business is maximised by having them fairly separate in terms of the skills,
attitudes and cultures that are required to run them both.[669]
6.47
The success of ring-fencing or operational separation
models in the energy sector was compared with the failure of the model applied
to telecommunications. As Mr Broad
bluntly stated:
The energy industry did the reform and did it right. In fact the
states that did the energy reform—and I have just spent seven years running an
energy company—did it right. The feds that did the telco one got it wrong.[670]
6.48
The effectiveness of the energy sector's approach to
privatisation and separation was also highlighted by Mr
Paul Fearon
from the Essential Services Commission:
In Victoria,
the businesses were legally separated but sold in a stapled form. Since then,
there have been a number of transactions which have essentially unstapled them.
But there is no regulatory or legislative barrier to these companies being
jointly owned. Basically, they were physically dealt with before they were
privatised. So the old gas and fuel sectors in Victoria
created three staple distributor retailers, and they were effectively
operationally and physically separated prior to privatisation.[671]
Concern about operational
separation
6.49
Some submissions argued that operational separation was
a knee-jerk reaction which had not been considered in concert with wider policy
and strategic plans for the telecommunications industry. The CEPU argued:
There is no consideration, for instance, of what further policy
provisions might be required for such separation, once established, to be
maintained. Would Telstra wholesale be permanently debarred from offering
retail products? Would Telstra retail be denied the right to invest in new
infrastructure (e.g. spectrum)? And what would be the effect of imposing what
amount to line-of-business restrictions on Telstra, but not on any other
vertically integrated operators?
What are the implications of the model for the pricing of
“wholesale” products which regulation currently requires be offered on a
retail-minus basis i.e. local calls? Would Telstra wholesale be allowed to
charge for these services at prices that allow the recovery of traffic
sensitive costs i.e. on a timed basis? If so, what happens to the untimed
(retail) local call obligation?
What impacts would “virtual separation” have on residual
cross-subsidies such as those involved in the geographic averaging of line
rental prices? What are the implications for the funding of universal service?
No discussion of “operational separation” which the CEPU has
seen to date offers answers to these questions.[672]
6.50
Similarly Optus, while supporting 'an examination of
further changes within Telstra to assist in delivering equivalency', cautioned
that operational separation, like accounting separation, could require
significant cost and effort for no net gain:
In assessing the imposition of any new regulatory requirement,
it is necessary to assess the benefits to be achieved against the cost in
implementing the requirement. ... While operational separation options may have a
theoretical attraction, there is a considerable danger is that the same barrier
will be encountered; namely, Telstra will resist change and the regulator will
be unable to gain sufficient insight to force organisational and behavioural
requirements to deliver tangible outcomes. The end result could be significant
effort and cost for no net gain.[673]
6.51
AAPT argued:
Any such development needs to be carefully designed to ensure
that the separation is not merely illusory, as the consequence could be the
introduction of additional cost without matching benefit.[674]
6.52
Similarly ATUG submitted:
Record keeping rules such as Accounting Separation are
ineffective, and Operational Separation is a concept untried anywhere in the
world as yet and with significant problems even at concept stage. For example,
under Australia Corporations Law ATUG is not sure whether an access services
division, within Telstra, could ever be sufficiently independent of Telstra’s
overriding corporate responsibilities to grow and run the wholesale business
effectively. It may be that we require separate company structures at a minimum
for Operational Separation to be effective.[675]
6.53
Associate Professor Ian
Atkinson argued that operational separation
looks very similar to structural separation and may well be more complex and
difficult to manage:
I am essentially a scientist. I like to apply the principles of
Occam’s razor. If it looks like a cat, smells like a cat and moves like a cat,
then it is a cat. Within the Australian context, do we really have enough
people in business with enough skills to actually run a ring fencing operation
like that? I just think it would inevitably fail.[676]
6.54
Similarly Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra argued:
This does look to me like structural separation. It has all the
elements of structural separation. It has all the elements that the ACCC called
structural separation less than 12 months ago. I am inclined to think that if
it looks like a duck, walks like a duck and quacks like a duck then it is a
duck. This to me is structural separation under another name.[677]
6.55
However, representatives from the ACCC refuted Mr
Scales' claims succinctly:
Mr Willett—Mr
Scales is quite wrong on that, quite
ill-informed. It is not structural separation.
Mr Samuel—If
it is a duck, then it has no beak.[678]
Application of models to other
competitors
6.56
Not surprisingly, Telstra's largest competitor argued
that organisational reform legislation should be directed solely at Telstra:
Optus is concerned to ensure that any structural separation
measures are strictly targeted to where the harm exists, namely Telstra and its
fixed line network. Any legislative requirements should impact only on Telstra
and, to that end, the requirements should be placed in the Telstra Act, not in
the Trade Practices Act.[679]
6.57
However, the Committee notes that many of Telstra's
competitors also have the potential to grow to a powerful market position. Some
submissions stressed that Telstra was not the only large, vertically integrated
telecommunications company in Australia.
As Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra stated:
The dynamic nature of the telecommunications market and the
emergence of new technologies have further intensified the competitive pressure
on Telstra...[T]here are now over 150 licensed carriers in the market competing
with Telstra. Many of these competitors are vertically integrated and they are
also horizontally integrated. There are many affiliates of powerful foreign
owned and even foreign government owned corporate multinationals. Some of them
with whom we are competing today are actually larger than Telstra. These
affiliates can draw on the extensive resources of those multinational entities
when competing in the Australian market, and they do.[680]
6.58
Any legislation which would alter the structure of
Telstra must also be applicable to its competitors, who may find themselves the
beneficiary of regulatory intervention and consequently in a dominant market
position. As the CEPU argued:
... any proposal to structurally separate Telstra must be viewed
in the context of industry structure as a whole. ... Splitting Telstra into two
separate companies, while leaving (say) Singtel Optus to enjoy all the
advantages of vertical integration has never seemed to the CEPU to represent a
coherent policy option.[681]
The Committee's view
6.59
The Committee believes that greater transparency
between Telstra's wholesale and retail businesses is clearly needed. While the
Committee has heard many calls for operational separation and notes that there
is growing support for this model, the Committee is not entirely persuaded that
operational separation will provide the level of transparency required by the
regulator and by Telstra's wholesale customers.
6.60
The Committee recognises that true transparency may
only be delivered by structurally separating Telstra. This model will remove
the incentive for Telstra to favour its own businesses over its competitors. It
will encourage innovation and investment in infrastructure, as Telstra
wholesale will benefit from providing services to as many customers as
possible. The Committee agrees with Mr Paul
Broad who argued:
The culture of running a network business, where your objective
is to minimise capital and to load it up, is vastly different from the culture
of running a wholesale business, which is vastly different from the culture of
running a retail business. To use one to subsidise and not really know what
that subsidy is, to me, is not a sustainable long-term management practice for
running businesses.[682]
6.61
The Committee has previously recommended that the
Productivity Commission should be asked to undertake a full examination of all
the options for structural reform in telecommunications, including the
structural separation of Telstra.[683]
The Committee notes that the Productivity Commission in its report in February
this year concluded that full structural separation 'would inevitably be
expensive and time consuming' and that transaction cost considerations 'now tip
the balance' against full vertical separation, pointing to some overseas
experience.[684] However, the Committee
is concerned that there has still not been a detailed review of this option
with proper financial analysis, and for that reason repeats its previous
recommendation that there should be a full independent review.
Recommendation 1
6.62 The Committee recommends that the Productivity
Commission be asked to undertake a full examination of structural separation of
Telstra.
6.63
Despite the persuasive arguments for structural
separation, the Government has indicated that it is unwilling to explore this
option.
6.64
Operational separation appears to have gained support
from different segments of the telecommunications market as a second best
option. The Committee heard substantial evidence on the features that such an
operational separation model might include.
6.65
The Committee heard that the aim of an effective
operational separation regime should be to replicate as far as possible the
incentives and transparency of structural separation, whilst attempting to
avoid some of the costs of implementation. Based on this evidence, the
Committee has formed the view that if operational separation is pursued, the
model for this separation should, at a minimum, include the features of the
ACCC's proposed model. Any model of operational separation that fails to
incorporate these threshold requirements is likely to have limited prospects
for success.
Recommendation 2
6.66 The Committee recommends that if the Government decides
to pursue operational separation of Telstra over structural separation, it
should adopt as a minimum the framework and operating rules outlined by the
ACCC in its proposed model.
The ACCC
We also understand the principle of walking softly and carrying
a big stick. Those regulators who have a big stick can afford to walk softly,
whereas those without may have to trot nervously through the jungle.[685]
6.67
The Committee heard much criticism of the ACCC's
ability to deal appropriately with competition and access issues in
telecommunications. Criticising the ACCC's handling of the 2004 competition
notice process, some submissions queried whether it was a matter of a lack of
will on the part of the regulator or inadequate powers. Mr
Paul Budde
articulated this concern:
How is it possible that, given the apparently ‘blatant’
anti-competitive behaviour that has been occurring in the broadband market, the
regulator failed to act promptly and decisively. Other issues, such as mobile
termination rates, Internet peering and unbundled local loop, demonstrate that
the ACCC appears regrettably ineffective.
...This leads me to conclude that either:
- the ACCC’s current
powers are insufficient to act or
- the ACCC is not
using effectively the powers it had.
The fact that no decisive action is taken plus the fact that the
regulator has clearly indicated that Telstra is ‘too large to regulate’, caused
me to conclude that the ACCC indeed is an inadequately empowered regulator.[686]
6.68
Many acknowledged the ACCC's difficult task in
regulating a sector so heavily dominated by one vertically integrated company,
and argued that the regulator should be given further information-gathering
powers. The Western Australian Department of
Industry and Resources (WADIR) submitted:
The regulators have been assigned a difficult task and need
comprehensive and relevant information in order to make the best possible
decisions. Toward this objective, the Commonwealth Government should provide
all regulators with unfettered and mandatory rights to compel information from
telecommunications providers. In the interest of promoting fair and open
competition, substantially more information relating to the telecommunications
network should be disclosed publicly.[687]
Penalties
6.69
The ACCC's ability to impose adequate penalties to
deter anti-competitive behaviour was also raised. As discussed in Chapter 3,
some witnesses felt that financial penalties were insufficient. As Mr
Damian Kay
stated:
It is corporate bullying. That is a broad, sweeping term, but
how do you stop it? The rules are there now to say [Telstra] cannot do that.
They have to provide the same service to the end customer, no matter who that
line is billed through. So the rules are there. If someone comes down hard on
Telstra out of this and says: ‘You can’t do this. We have all these examples
and we are going to fine you $20 million,’ they would have made more than $20
million out of this.[688]
6.70
Dr Walter
Green argued that corporations and
businesses that were caught engaging in anti-competitive conduct should be
'automatically' fined:
The biggest concern, and one that has been used not only by
Telstra but by a couple of others to destroy the competition, is the offering
of a retail price which is below the wholesale price. To me it should be in the
legislation that if you are caught doing that it is automatic that you will get
fined. Just improving that will change the whole dynamics as to how pricing is
done. In fact we have been asked to look into two current areas where what
Telstra is offering to the large corporate customers is below the wholesale
rate that is being offered to carriers.[689]
6.71
ATUG also submitted that to encourage fast compliance
an immediate fine should be levied on anti-competitive behaviour:
The monetary incentive should be used to encourage fast
compliance given the safeguards that are in place PRIOR to a notice being
issued. The fine should be applied immediately and return of same could be the
subject of negotiation on proof that anti-competitive conduct has ceased. Part
XIB is not designed to support the negotiation of access prices. That is the
role of Part XIC. Part XIB is designed to penalize anti-competitive conduct.[690]
6.72
The Committee notes that suggestions that the ACCC
rather than a court have power to impose immediate penalties for certain
conduct would present constitutional difficulties arising from the separation
of judicial and executive powers, and for that reason does not support these
suggestions. However, the Committee considers that the sentiments expressed
demonstrate the level of concern about the effectiveness of the current regime.
Other powers
I do not know that you necessarily need an army in the ACCC, but
they need to have the tools. There were some comments made about predetermining
what the pricing environment ought to be. That might be a solution and that may
avoid the need for building up more muscle within the organisation. Take the
competition notice over the ADSL: I was involved as a witness in that process
and for 12 months I was giving witness statements. There were a lot of
resources spent.[691]
6.73
Optus argued that there was a need for further
regulatory reforms, including giving the ACCC additional tools so that it can
move more quickly to block Telstra’s anti-competitive behaviour. Optus'
specific proposals included:
A prohibition on Telstra unreasonably discriminating in favour
of its own retail operations through the introduction of a non-discrimination
rule. This would require Telstra to demonstrate it is not discriminating in the
way it treats its competitors and itself where it resells services. This would
overcome the significant hurdle of competitors currently having to prove
Telstra is discriminating when it behaves anti-competitively.
Measures that prevent Telstra targeting customers it has lost to
competitors for 180 days (such measures are in place today in Canada).
This would remove Telstra’s ability to use its competitive advantage to
undermine competitor’s efforts to acquire customers.[692]
Cease and desist
6.74
The Australian Consumers' Association suggested that
the ACCC should be given 'cease and desist' powers when seeking to resolve
apparent anti-competitive behaviour. This power, the Association argued, 'would
increase incentives to resolve competition issues, while improving the
sensitivity of the system to market entrants'.[693]
6.75
Mr David
Havyatt from AAPT argued that 'cease and
desist' powers would have been beneficial if they had been available during the
2004 ADSL competition notice episode:
... the issue with the price squeeze we saw was that Telstra had
dropped a retail price and then not adequately reduced its wholesale price. A
cease and desist order would have allowed the ACCC, rather than go through a
long process of having the wholesale prices negotiated, to say to Telstra, ‘You
cannot drop that retail price until you have satisfactorily dealt with the
wholesale price.’ Both of those would have had beneficial outcomes in terms of
the administration of the regime.[694]
6.76
Further, AAPT submitted:
... Telstra continued to offer anti-competitive prices after the
issue of the notice. The problem would be avoided if the ACCC had the power to
issue “cease and desist orders” in conjunction with a competition notice.[695]
6.77
Similarly, Unwired Australia argued that the ACCC
needed cease and desist powers 'as well as or in place of its competition
notice powers':
Only then will actions cease and irreparable damage to the
market that can occur during an investigation be avoided.[696]
6.78
However, the Committee notes that a 'cease and desist'
power raises a possible constitutional issue arising from the relationship
between judicial and executive powers.[697]
The 2003 Review of the Competition
Provisions of the Trade Practices Act[698]
(the Dawson Report) did not support a proposed amendment to Part IV to confer a
'cease and desist' power on the ACCC, noting:
There is a real question whether the proposed amendment would
involve the ACCC in the exercise of judicial power and hence be invalid. The
power to make binding orders (albeit temporary) based on a determination by the
ACCC that there was a breach of the Act, even though the orders would be
enforceable only by the Court, would appear to involve the exercise of judicial
power.[699]
6.79
The Dawson Report stated that those difficulties had
not been resolved. In any case, such an amendment was not supported because of
the availability of injunctions under the TPA and the lack of evidence to show
that a 'cease and desist' process would be speedier than obtaining an interim
injunction.[700] The Committee notes
that injunctions are also available for contraventions of the competition rule
and other rules in Part XIB.[701]
6.80
Dr Mitchell
Landrigan from Telstra also noted:
I would point out that as part of the Dawson
recommendations there is going to be quite significant bolstering of the
penalty provisions in part IV. I would have thought that for those who are
concerned about the administration of part IV that would be quite a welcome
thing.[702]
6.81
The Committee also heard evidence which suggested that
granting the ACCC 'cease and desist' powers may not deter anti-competitive
behaviour because of Telstra's extensive legal resources. Mr
Charles Britton
from the Australian Consumers' Association stated:
The cease-and-desist type power is possibly tainted. You have
the competition notice regime. In theory, that allows them to step in...If
cease-and-desist had the same unhappy outcome as the competition notice, then
that is what I am saying about a reluctance to get more shovels out for that
hole. It does dig us deeper in. Telstra has potentially got more lawyers than
the ACCC, so in that sense the ACCC is not going to win that arm wrestle for us.[703]
6.82
The Committee believes that if the ACCC had had 'cease
and desist' power in the 2004 ADSL competition notice matter, the process may
have been resolved in a more timely manner. However, the Committee also notes
the views on possible constitutional difficulties with the grant of this power
and the availability of injunctions. Accordingly the Committee does not
recommend 'cease and desist' powers for the ACCC at this stage.
Divestiture powers
6.83
The Committee heard from such groups as the
Communications Experts Group[704] and
the CCC which argued that the ACCC should be given divestiture powers, that is,
the power to compel structural separation in response to anti-competitive
behaviour, as part of its array of regulatory powers.
6.84
Mr David
Forman from the CCC stated:
We have consistently argued that that is a screamingly obvious
element that is missing from the regime at the moment. At the moment, the ACCC
has extensive competition notice powers that go to fines, but nothing beyond
that. We are talking about a $4½ billion company. It would have to be a pretty
substantial fine to mean anything, to be material...At the moment, I cannot see
that fines of the magnitude that is likely to be contemplated under any breach
of the act would be a sufficient disincentive to make Telstra walk away from
something that it considers fundamental to retaining its market power. If,
however, it had to consider the fact that the regulator may attempt to actually
change the structure of the company, then that could be a real disincentive.[705]
6.85
Mr Paul
Budde expressed similar views:
Facing the reality of a powerful government that is unwilling to
properly address the issue of structural separation, the ACCC should at least
be provided with the authority to use this threat as a weapon to force Telstra
to change its anti-competitive behaviour and its regulatory game-playing.[706]
6.86
However, not all submissions supported this proposal.
It was claimed that despite the antitrust court decision in the United
States some twenty years ago, in which the
Bell System was broken up, the industry has now reformed on lines not dissimilar
from the original structure.[707] Yet
it was argued that in the intervening period much time has been wasted on
bureaucratic regulation, some innovation has been retarded and there was
extensive overinvestment in transmission capacity.[708] Dr
Mitchell Landrigan
from Telstra noted that there had not been a detailed debate of divestiture
powers:
Divestiture is clearly a complicated issue and much of the
debate has not been about strict divestiture of entities as they currently
exist but about incremental power that has effectively resulted as an accretion
of creeping acquisitions. To my knowledge there has not been detailed debate
about divestiture per se of an entity in its existing form.[709]
6.87
Despite these concerns, the Committee has heard a
substantial amount of evidence which suggests that the current penalties
available to the ACCC to achieve enforcement of XIB and XIC are inadequate. The
Committee believes that the financial penalties do not act as a sufficient
deterrent to anti-competitive behaviour and that other deterrents are needed.
6.88
When Mr Samuel was asked whether the ACCC sought
divestiture powers, he stated that the ultimate aim was to bring about more
transparent arrangements between Telstra's wholesale and retail operations so
as to allow the ACCC to enforce the TPA provisions more effectively, and that
there were other means of achieving this:
So putting in place penalties, which for example, would have to
be of hundreds of millions of dollars to be in any sense meaningful, because
Telstra fails to adequately deal with operational separation, or putting in
place a divesture order because there is a failure to bring about operational
separation, I might suggest with respect, tends to be focusing much more on the
potential to do substantial damage to Telstra. Whereas it is far more important
that we get the ultimate objective which is: clear, transparent and commercial
arms-length dealings between Telstra’s wholesale and retail operations. One of
the simplest and certainly least damaging ways of achieving that is to have
regulations that require those transparent accounting and commercial
arms-length dealings to take place and to have those capable of being enforced
by a court of law.[710]
6.89
Mr Samuel
made clear that it is not a question of wanting divestiture powers; but rather
a question of identifying effective means to achieve transparency.[711] ACCC Commissioner Mr
Ed Willett
expressed similar views.[712]
6.90
Those supporting divestiture powers often referred to
the powers available to the United Kingdom
regulator, OFCOM. As ATUG submitted:
The UK
context has strong incentives for the parties to agree an outcome - including,
importantly, the ability of OFCOM to make a reference under the Enterprise Act
to the Competition Commission for an assessment of appropriate remedies
(de-merger) in the face of intractable market power arising from an enduring
bottleneck in the local access area.[713]
6.91
Mr Paul
Budde expressed similar views.[714]
6.92
However, as ACCC Commissioner Mr Ed
Willett pointed out:
... if OFCOM happen to find that the only way it could achieve
what it is trying to achieve was through divestiture, then I think you would
find the debate here might be very different. In those circumstances we
probably would not want to rule out seeking a divesture power, but we are not
in that situation.[715]
6.93
Mr Willett
argued further:
We are not in the business of asking for powers that we are not
sure we need to achieve the outcome. We have proposed some arrangements here
which we think should be given some thought and could be effective.[716]
6.94
Nevertheless, the Committee considers that the grant of
divestiture powers would strengthen the ACCC's capacity to deter
anti-competitive conduct by giving it another tool with which to encourage
compliance. Giving the ACCC a 'stick' as significant as a divestiture power
would substantially improve the ACCC's negotiating power when attempting to
address instances of large scale anti-competitive behaviour.
Recommendation 3
6.95 The Committee recommends that the ACCC be given
divestiture powers.
Resources
6.96
The need for the ACCC to have sufficient resources to
be an effective regulator has been raised frequently with the Committee, both
during this inquiry and its inquiry into the establishment of the Australian
Communications and Media Authority (ACMA).[717]
The Communications Experts Group submitted:
The ACCC has inadequate financial resources to defend a
prolonged court case, the ACCC should have the resources to effectively
construct a legal argument and obtain the required evidence to support by
interacting with carriers, and if necessary providing financial support in
preparing a case.[718]
6.97
Mr Richard
Thwaites from ATUG also noted that
inadequate financial resources may lead to a reluctance to take legal action:
... we believe the ACCC needs considerably more resources than it
currently has in order to mount its arguments and, therefore, to enable it to
feel confident in making its judgments and taking them to appeal when
necessary. We feel that the ACCC has done its best with the resources available
for this sort of thing, but it has been under a severe disadvantage given the
ability for it to be basically taken round and round the traps, with far
greater resources applied to questioning its judgments. Naturally, this creates
an environment of caution.[719]
6.98
The Townsville City Council submitted:
Most importantly, any regulatory agency must be resourced
appropriately to deal on an equal footing with one of the largest companies in Australia.
Telstra has the resources to outlast and outgun the existing regulatory structure.
An example of this was the time it took regulators to deal with the issue of
Telstra's broadband wholesale pricing to competitors.[720]
6.99
In Perth, Dr
Walter Green
told the Committee:
... both the ACA and the ACCC, in my instance, are under-funded to
actually deal with these kinds of issues. They need a significantly larger
staff to debate and discuss with the industry.[721]
6.100
Some witnesses argued that the ACCC was greatly
under-resourced not only in financial terms but in staff expertise. As Dr
Green stated:
The ACCC have two problems. Firstly, they do not have the resources
to deal with it properly...Their budget is continually being undercut. To me,
they should be growing by eight to 10 per cent per year in their revenue over
and above what I call a cost of living increase. In fact, we have the converse;
it is going down. Secondly, it is a special set of skills that the ACCC has, so
they have to consider staff retention and how that all operates as well. To me,
they certainly need beefing up and need to be provided with both additional
funds and additional regulatory control.[722]
6.101
AAPT also referred to the importance of appropriate
staff.[723] Mr
David Havyatt
from AAPT told the Committee:
It has become apparent to us that the ACCC does not have the
resources to undertake the kind of ongoing analysis of the unfolding
telecommunications markets that is needed for the regulation of this regime. We
see that repeatedly in the nature and structure of inquiries that emerge under
the regime—there is no coherent whole-of-ACCC thinking unfolding.[724]
6.102
Mr Havyatt
argued for a full-time ACCC commissioner dealing with telecommunications, so as
to ensure that the sector was adequately scrutinised:
That commissioner should also be a member of the Australian
Communications and Media Authority. So there would be one person who was really
spending their time looking at this, and not the chairman and a commissioner
doing it as a part-time activity and occasionally weighing into the
consideration of telecommunications issues.[725]
6.103
The ACCC has a Chairman, a Deputy Chair and five
full-time Commissioners.[726] The
Committee agrees that, given the importance of telecommunications and the
separate regime established in the TPA for telecommunications regulation, it
would be desirable to have one commissioner with particular responsibility for
telecommunications. The Committee also agrees that this person should be a
member of the Australian Communications and Media Authority (ACMA) so as to
facilitate sharing of knowledge between the two organisations.[727]
Recommendation 4
6.104 The Committee recommends that one of the full-time
commissioners of the ACCC be given specific responsibility for
telecommunications, and that this person also be a member of the Australian
Communications and Media Authority.
6.105
Earlier this year the Committee recommended that funding
to the ACCC for telecommunications competition issues be substantially
increased as a matter of urgent priority, given the need for the regulator to
be well-resourced in order to be effective.[728]
In light of the evidence it has received in this inquiry, especially with
respect to the ACCC's conduct of the broadband competition notice and the
Mobile Terminating Access Services declaration, the Committee repeats that
recommendation.
Recommendation 5
6.106 The Committee recommends that funding to the ACCC for
telecommunications competition issues be substantially increased as a matter of
urgent priority.
The role of the ACCC
6.107
This Committee has discussed at length the ACCC's
responsibilities for managing anti-competitive practices and protecting
consumers. The Committee heard concerns that sometimes these two functions
appear to be in conflict. As Mr David
Spence from Unwired Australia stated:
One of the issues is that the ACCC is the consumer council and
the competition council. The Telstra drop of broadband prices to $29.95 may
have been very good for consumers and certainly improved the take-up rate, but
it may not be in the best long-term interests from a competition point of view.
If Telstra were to do that in order to dominate the market in the next couple
of years and eliminate all alternative infrastructure providers, then that is
not the best competition in the place. I believe that, if you look at
competition regulatory bodies around the world, you do not often find them tied
up with the consumer council as well... It would be hard for the ACCC to say to
Telstra, ‘Put the prices back up again from $29.95,’ when they are the consumer
council.[729]
6.108
However, the Committee notes that the object of
fostering competition is to promote the long term interests of end users. The
main problem that has become apparent during this inquiry is the ACCC's
inability to regulate anti-competitive practices adequately, and this has
obvious effects on consumers. The Committee does not support taking consumer
protection functions from the ACCC, noting that the former ACA (now the ACMA)
also has important responsibilities in that area, as discussed below.
6.109
The Committee also heard criticism of the ACCC's
involvement in policy. Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra stated:
If you have a regulator which is clearly determined to become
involved in the policy debate and is clearly determined to ensure that its
policy outcomes are achieved, then automatically what follows from that is the
potential moral hazard of the regulator establishing outcomes will ensure that
that follows...They are a natural consequence of trying to achieve a policy
outcome.[730]
6.110
AAPT submitted that policy reviews were more
appropriately carried out by the department rather than the regulator, and
called for additional resources for the department's policy work and policy
research, noting:
Departmental review does not preclude the views of the regulator
being sought. During the period of reform in the 1980s and 1990s many of the
developments were driven by the research of the Bureau of Transport and
Communications Economics, which in part continues as the Communications
Research Unit.[731]
6.111
However, in defence of the ACCC, Chairman
Mr Graeme Samuel
argued:
We do not get involved in policy debates unless we are either
requested to provide opinions on policy by government or asked our views by
parliament and parliamentary committees, and then there are the limitations the
chair described. We are a regulator. We are intimately involved with the regulation
of the telecommunications industry, with one fundamental objective, and that is
to bring about a competitive environment in the short- to medium- and long-term
future. We will continue to do so. Where it is necessary for us to express
opinions as to our regulatory responsibilities, we will continue to do so.[732]
The TPA: Part XIB and section 46
6.112
In Chapter 3 the Committee discussed the criticisms
that Part XIB of the TPA does not adequately define anti-competitive conduct in
telecommunications, particularly in light of the issues that surfaced during
the 2004 ADSL competition notice. In brief, section 151AJ defines
anti-competitive conduct as a situation where a carrier or carriage service
provider has a substantial degree of market power and takes advantage of that
power with the effect, or likely effect, of substantially lessening
competition.
6.113
Several witnesses argued that the ACCC must be
empowered to prevent Telstra from engaging in conduct that may constitute
misuse of market power or the reduction of competition in the
telecommunications market. There was a range of suggestions as to how the
legislation might be changed.
6.114
The Communications Experts Group argued that proof of
certain behaviours should suffice in itself, instead of needing also to prove
the detrimental effect of the behaviour:
In many cases the ACCC ha[s] to prove that a certain behaviour
is unacceptable, and that the alleged offender caused or undertook the
unacceptable behaviour e.g. offering retail prices below wholesale prices for
some services. There are a number of cases where unacceptable behaviour should
be specified, so that the ACCC only has to prove the unacceptable behaviour.[733]
6.115
Optus also criticised the test in Part XIB, proposing in
its place a 'non-discrimination rule' about price (that is, a prohibition
against 'unreasonable' discrimination on providing listed carriage services):
The non-discrimination rule (NDR) will mean that instead of
competitors having to demonstrate that Telstra’s behaviour is anti-competitive
by substantially lessening competition, Telstra would need to demonstrate that
it was not behaving in a discriminatory manner, so complying with the NDR. This
is an important change that shifts the onus of proof onto Telstra to
demonstrate compliance with the rule, rather than the much higher test for
non-Telstra providers to demonstrate that Telstra is not only behaving
anti-competitively, but that this behaviour is having a significant impact on
competition.[734]
6.116
The Committee notes that Optus' suggestion of a
'non-discrimination rule' is similar in some ways to the UK's
regulatory requirements imposed on telecommunications providers with
significant market power (SMP).[735]
Non-discrimination principles are applied to avoid or, at least, minimise
market distortion by those with market power, including vertically integrated
organisations that supply to internal and external customers.
6.117
Designated SMP providers must supply products at the
same price to external customers as to their internal retail arms, unless
differences are 'objectively justifiable'. The non-discrimination obligations
in the UK also
extend to non-price differences, including the 'timing of provision', the
'functionality of the product supplied', 'the reliability and efficiency of
transactional processes', and the availability of relevant product information.[736] Again, the terms and condition of
product supply to external customers must be the same as the terms and
conditions of product supply to an SMP provider's retail arm, unless the
differences are objectively justifiable.
6.118
The Committee notes that the UK
regulator, OFCOM, is currently reviewing its approach to investigating
potential contraventions of the requirement not to unduly discriminate.[737] The Committee considers that these
developments should be examined closely in considering future options for the
anti-competitive regime in Australian telecommunications. It may be that
imposing a positive duty on all industry participants with 'significant market
power' not to discriminate unduly would be beneficial. However, this is not
quite the same as reversing the onus of proof in individual cases, as the Optus
submission seems to suggest.
6.119
The Committee heard another suggestion about possible
legislative amendment, to address the concern about the requirement in section
151AJ to establish that a corporation 'takes advantage' of its market power.
Unwired Australia
submitted:
Telstra's position in the market means that any actions it
takes, regardless of its purpose in taking them, and whether or not it 'takes
advantage' of its position to take them, have dramatic impacts on its
competitors. If negative impacts are to be controlled, the provisions should be
amended to remove 'takes advantage of that power' as follows to simply refer to
a corporation acting with the prohibited effect.[738]
6.120
However, the Committee considers that this suggestion
if implemented would broaden the operation of section 151AJ to an unacceptable
level. The Committee notes that a recent Senate committee report on section 46
of the TPA, referring to various High Court and Federal Court decisions,
recommended the insertion of a declaratory provision listing factors to be
taken into account in determining whether a corporation has taken advantage of
its market power.[739] The ACCC had
submitted that a court should consider whether: the conduct of the corporation
is materially facilitated by its substantial degree of market power; the
corporation engages in the conduct in reliance on its substantial degree of market
power; the corporation would be likely to engage in the conduct if it a lacked
substantial degree of market power; or the conduct of the corporation is
otherwise related to its substantial degree of market power.[740] The report recommended the
declaratory provision should be based on those suggestions.[741]
6.121
The Committee considers that such a provision may also
be helpful in relation to Part XIB.
Recommendation 6
6.122 The Committee recommends that section 151AJ of the Trade Practices Act 1974 be amended by
inserting an inclusive list of factors to be considered by the courts in
determining whether a carrier or carriage service provider has taken advantage
of its substantial degree of power in a telecommunications market.
6.123
The Committee notes that Part XIB was never intended to
be a permanent part of the TPA. However, it is clear that there are still
serious concerns about anti-competitive conduct. Accordingly, the Committee
considers that any suggestion that the ACCC should rely only on its general
powers under Part IV in the telecommunications market cannot be sustained.
6.124
In any case, the Committee heard concerns about the
operation of Part IV. Section 46 relating to general misuse of market power
prevents a corporation with a substantial degree of market power from taking
advantage of that power for the purpose of eliminating or substantially
damaging a competitor, preventing the entry of a person into any market, or
deterring or preventing competitive conduct in a market. The Committee heard that
the 'purpose test' is 'notoriously difficult to establish'.[742]
6.125
Consistent with its argument about the Part XIB
provisions, Unwired suggested that the 'purpose test' in section 46 should be
replaced with a test focusing on the outcome or effect of the action.[743] However, Dr
Mitchell Landrigan
from Telstra argued that 'purpose' has generally been either conceded or quite
easily proven:
I think the current position about that debate is that it is
quite redundant given that most of the High Court decisions in which concerns
have been raised about whether section 46 has worked have not been about
purpose. Purpose has generally been either conceded or quite easily proven,
largely because of provisions that are built into section 46. The taking
advantage of market power component has been the subject of some detailed
debate with some measures proposed about whether indicia about what market
power is should be built into the legislation.[744]
6.126
Any changes to Part IV would have implications that
range far beyond the telecommunications industry. In light of the ACCC's access
to special provisions in Part XIB, the Committee does not recommend any changes
to Part IV.
The TPA: Part XIC
6.127
The Committee considers that the administration of the
TPA has a potential dampening effect on investment in infrastructure services
because of the risk of exposure to access regulation, particularly where there
is a risk that regulated returns may not provide a sufficient return on
investment. In reaching this view, the Committee is mindful that the benefits
of competition in the services sector will be available over the longer term
only if there is ongoing investment in the infrastructure that provides those
services.
6.128
Another element which the Committee is convinced is
having a damaging effect on investment in infrastructure by new entrants is
Telstra’s behaviour. The Committee has identified at least two ways that this
arises: by impeding access to its network on satisfactory terms, so that access
seekers cannot build customer bases and profitable businesses sufficient to
enable investment in their own facilities; and in the way it directly responds
to facilities competition.
6.129
That Telstra can impede access would suggest that the
access regime is not working in accordance with the intent expressed in the
Competition Principles Agreement between the Commonwealth and the States. The Committee
notes that the Agreement provides that legislation with the following effects
should be implemented:
6(4)(m) The
owner or user of a service should not engage in conduct for the purpose of
hindering access to that service to another person.
6(4)(e) The
owner of a facility that is used to provide a service should use all reasonable
endeavours to accommodate the requirements of a person seeking access.
6.130
The thrust of these requirements would appear to be
effected by section 152EF of the TPA, which prohibits the hindering of the
fulfilment of the standard access obligations. Notwithstanding this provision,
however, the Committee heard much evidence of behaviour that seems to fall
squarely within the prohibition.
6.131
The Committee has heard evidence of attempts by some
firms to respond to demand by delivering services, or building or attempting to
build, alternative facilities. Almost invariably, such efforts have been impeded
by Telstra.
6.132
The Committee has heard evidence of Telstra
overbuilding infrastructure—or dropping its prices for existing services—in
response to a threat from potential facilities competitors. Not only does this action
block that particular competitor, but it sends a clear signal to the market
about how Telstra is likely to respond to similar initiatives.
6.133
The Committee also heard evidence that the cost of
transmission—a declared service on many of the routes in question—was too high
to justify investment in facilities or services in many markets and, most
notably, regional areas.
6.134
It is apparent from these examples and from other
evidence received during this inquiry that as long as Telstra has both the
incentive and ability to favour itself over competitive service providers, a rigorous
access regime is still needed.
6.135
The Committee believes that the access regime should be
focussed on bringing about more timely and acceptable resolution of access
requests. To this end, the Committee considers that the regime should include
not just measures designed to reduce the ability of access providers to impede—or
unreasonably delay—access but should also aim to reduce the incentive for it.
6.136
The Committee considers that the object of Part XIC of
the TPA should remain the promotion of the long term interest of end users. However,
the Committee considers that the objectives to which the ACCC must have regard in
determining whether that object is promoted (in section 152AB) need to be
weighted differently. In the Committee’s view, the objectives of promoting
competition in downstream markets and achieving any-to-any connectivity will
not be achieved in the long term unless there is continuing investment in
infrastructure services. For this reason, the Committee considers that the third
objective in subsection 152AB(2)—encouraging the economically efficient use of,
and the economically efficient investment in, infrastructure—should be given
primacy.
6.137
The Committee notes that the Government has proposed
that the objective of the general access regime in Part IIIA be ‘to promote the
economically efficient operation of, use of and investment in the
infrastructure by which services are provided, thereby promoting effective
competition in upstream and downstream markets’.[745]
Recommendation 7
6.138 The Committee recommends that the third objective of
the access regime as set out in subsection 152AB(2) of the Trade Practices Act 1974—encouraging the economically efficient use
of, and the economically efficient investment in infrastructure—be given
primacy.
6.139
As discussed in Chapter 4, it appears that the access
regime is not working in accordance with the intent expressed in the
Competition Principles Agreement between the Commonwealth and the States.
Accordingly the Committee makes the following recommendations.
Recommendation 8
6.140 The Committee recommends that in order to clearly
satisfy the Commonwealth's obligations under clause 6(4)(e) of the Competition
Principles Agreement, the Trade Practices
Act 1974 be amended to include a provision that requires the owner of a
facility that is used to provide a service to use all reasonable endeavours to
accommodate the requirements of a person seeking access.
Recommendation 9
6.141 The Committee recommends that to clearly satisfy the
Commonwealth's obligations under clause 6(4)(m) of the Competition Principles
Agreement, section 152EF of the Trade
Practices Act 1974 be amended to prohibit conduct that has the effect—and
not just the purpose—of preventing or hindering the fulfilment of a standard
access obligation or an obligation imposed by a determination made by the ACCC
under Division 8.
6.142
The Committee notes that the ACCC has power to
determine model terms and conditions in relation to ‘core services’. The core
services are listed in section 152AQB and can be expanded by regulation.[746]
Recommendation 10
6.143
The Committee recommends that the Government consider
expanding the class of ‘core services’ in relation to which the ACCC must
determine model terms and conditions for access. In particular, the Committee
recommends that for the purpose of improving services in regional areas,
certain transmission (or backhaul) routes be specified in the regulations as
‘core services’ under section 152AQB of the Trade
Practices Act 1974.
6.144
The Committee notes that the ACCC has already indicated
its intention to make variations to 2003 Model Core Services Terms and
Conditions Determination for the Unconditioned Local Loop Service. The
Committee notes the evidence that the practice of delaying access to declared
services seems to be common. While Recommendation 9 above addresses this issue,
it necessitates legislative change which may take some time. The Committee
considers that the matter may be dealt with more expeditiously in any model
terms determined by the ACCC.
Recommendation 11
6.145
The Committee recommends that the ACCC include
prohibitions on behaviour that has the purpose or effect of impeding or
unreasonably delaying access in any model terms and conditions for core
services—and particularly those relating to the unconditioned local loop
service.
Recommendation 12
6.146 The Committee recommends that the Trade Practices Act 1974 be amended to require the ACCC to give
greater importance to model terms and conditions in arbitrations. In addition
to the ACCC merely ‘having regard to’ model terms and conditions determinations,
such determinations should apply presumptively unless the parties can show good
reason to depart from them.
6.147
At the very least, the ACCC should have an influence over
price sooner in the process, that is, prior to an access dispute arising. The Committee
does not have a view about the method by which the prices are set, although, in
relation to transmission prices in regional areas where there would appear to
be the least prospect of competition emerging to solve the access problem,
prices should be more tightly controlled. The Committee notes the view of the Western
Australian Department of Industry and Resources that distance based tariffs
should be replaced with volume based tariffs.
Recommendation 13
6.148 The Committee recommends that the ACCC be granted
powers to set prices in addition to, or instead of, developing pricing
principles.
Recommendation 14
6.149 The Committee recommends that subsection 152AQA(6) of
the Trade Practices Act 1974 be
amended to require the ACCC to have regard to its pricing principles when it is
assessing undertakings as well as in the arbitration of access disputes as is
presently provided.
6.150
The Committee favours the approach taken in Part IIIA
of the TPA, which allows the ACCC to require the giving of an undertaking and
gives it the power to amend undertakings or substitute its own.
Recommendation 15
6.151 The Committee recommends that subsection 152AQB(6) of
the Trade Practices Act 1974 be
amended to require the ACCC to have regard to any model terms and conditions
when it is assessing undertakings as well as in the arbitration of access
disputes as is presently provided.
Recommendation 16
6.152 The Committee recommends that further amendments be
made to the undertakings scheme to prevent or discourage their use to delay
access and to bring more certainty to the market. In particular, the Committee
recommends the imposition of shorter target timeframes in relation to access
decisions.
6.153
By way of example, the Committee suggests the following
targets:
- sections 152AT and 152ATA of the Trade Practices Act 1974 be amended to
require decisions on ordinary and anticipatory exemptions to be made within a
period shorter than 6 months.
- sections 152BU and 152CBA of the Trade Practices Act 1974 be amended to
require decisions on ordinary and special access undertakings to be made within
a period shorter than 6 months;
- section 152CF of the Trade Practices Act 1974 be amended to require the Australian
Competition Tribunal to make decisions within a period shorter than 6 months. The
Committee notes that such a change has been proposed in relation to decisions
of the Tribunal under part IIIA.
6.154
The Committee also notes that it is important that the
ACCC has adequate resources to fulfil these requirements, and reiterates its
call for further funding for the ACCC as set out in Recommendation 5.
6.155
The Committee considers that the need for legislated
‘access holidays’ has not been demonstrated and therefore supports continuation
of the present scheme. The Committee agrees with the ACCC's view that the
overturning of the Foxtel/Telstra exemption turned on the particular facts of
that case and did not reflect a flaw in the exemptions scheme or prevent the
ACCC from making exemptions in the future.
Recommendation 17
6.156 The Committee recommends that the present scheme of
anticipatory exemptions and special undertakings remain unchanged for the time
being.
Foxtel and the HFC
6.157
In its 2003 report on Emerging market structures in the communications sector, the ACCC
discussed at some length the incentive for anti-competitive behaviour arising
from Telstra’s half ownership of Foxtel and its ownership of the HFC network on
which it is delivered. The ACCC's specific concerns are that Telstra has full
ownership of the main HFC pay TV distribution network and a copper network, as
well as a 50 per cent shareholding in the major pay TV operator in Australia.
This ownership has specific effects, as the ACCC stated:
Telstra’s ownership of a HFC network:
- diminishes
opportunities for competition by actual and potential network competitors
-
means Telstra’s
copper and HFC networks do not compete with each other denying potential price
and service benefits that such competition could deliver to consumers.
Telstra’s partial ownership of Foxtel provides it with the
incentive to:
- foreclose supply
of pay TV channels by Foxtel to other networks competing with Telstra for the
supply of telecommunications services
-
prevent other pay TV businesses or channels from gaining
access to Telstra’s HFC network.[747]
6.158
In relation to Foxtel, the ACCC noted:
Through its partial ownership of Foxtel, Telstra has the ability
to veto supply of pay TV channels by Foxtel to other networks. Foxtel and
Telstra also have an interest in preventing other pay TV businesses or channels
from gaining access to Telstra’s fixed customer access network. Therefore,
Telstra is in a position where it controls important inputs of supply for its
potential and actual broadband network competitors, as well as for pay TV
operators competing against Foxtel (on the Telstra HFC network).[748]
6.159
The report noted that Foxtel is presently supplying
content to other carriers, and that proposed access to content arrangements
will help to facilitate this further. Telstra’s influence on these agreements
remains and access regulation will only go so far to reduce this influence. The
ACCC concluded that requiring Telstra to divest its Foxtel shareholding would
remove Telstra’s influence in preventing Foxtel supplying its pay TV channels
(particularly premium channels) to other networks. Divestiture would also be likely
to make Telstra more willing to allow other pay TV businesses or channels
access to Telstra’s HFC network (in the event it is not divested).[749]
6.160
The ACCC also considered Telstra should divest itself
of its HFC network because Telstra owns two of the three major fixed
telecommunications networks. As firms do not compete with themselves, Telstra’s
continuing focus is not to maximise the revenue from each network separately
but rather to maximise revenue across both networks. Therefore, in seeking to
protect the revenues of both networks, investment will not be made, or will be
delayed, in services that would cannibalise the revenue of the other network.
For example, Telstra does not seek to supply telephony services on its HFC
network which would reduce the revenue that Telstra receives from its PSTN
network:
Divestiture of the HFC would introduce a new infrastructure
competitor into the market, creating conditions for increased rivalry and
innovation in the supply of a full range of telecommunications services,
including broadband services. The Commission believes that if the HFC is
divested, divestiture of Foxtel would become even more important so that
Telstra could not use its influence in Foxtel to deny the new network owner
access to Foxtel pay TV content.[750]
6.161
ATUG submitted:
The OECD's conclusion on ownership of cable and copper networks
and competition in broadband is clear, "... the broadband markets in one
third of OECD countries are being held back where the cable networks are not
providing independent competition with the PSTN. This is evident in the
difference in level of service, pricing and take-up of service. In these cases
all options need to be considered to increase the level of competitive
provision of broadband access including separating cable networks from
incumbent PSTN operators".[751]
6.162
The Committee notes that the OECD in an Economic Survey
report in December 2004 also recommended that Telstra be required to divest the
HFC network and its shareholding in Foxtel on the basis that there was 'no
effective competition in pay TV'.[752]
An earlier OECD report also stated:
Evidence continues to show that ownership of cable networks, by
incumbent telecommunication carriers, leads to a slower roll out of broadband
access. Overall broadband growth rates are clearly higher where there is head
to head competition between independently owned DSL and cable networks.[753]
6.163
Mr Charles
Britton from the Australian Consumers'
Association agreed there was a need for Telstra to divest itself of both its
share in Foxtel and of its HFC network. Mr Britton
also noted the positive effect on competition and infrastructure investment of
cable companies' and copper line telcos' competition in the United
States:
... you have a structural competition driver in the United
States where the cable companies are in
competition with the established copper line telcos and are driving voice over
IP as a competitive offering in the marketplace. We are not going to see
anything like the same structural pressure behind the rollover voice over IP
because we do not have the facilities competition that has emerged between
cable and DSL and we do not have the drivers that are going to produce it.[754]
6.164
The Australian Consumers' Association argued the need
for divestiture prior to the sale of Telstra:
In our view the requirement that Telstra divest itself of the
HFC cable network and the Foxtel service that it carries is an essential
pre-requisite to privatisation, in order to curb the horizontal sprawl of the
corporation into media, and the exercise of market power into both spheres in a
mutually reinforcing way that will over time deliver significant monopoly
benefits for the company and consequent detriment to consumers.[755]
6.165
Mr Paul
Budde went further in
proposing that Sensis and Foxtel should be amalgamated prior to divestiture:
'Let’s hive off Sensis from Telstra, put the Foxtel shareholding
in that and actually create a media company.’ That would solve a lot of
problems. The value of Telstra will not be diminished by Sensis, because there
is no synergy between Telstra and Sensis. If Sensis is not there, the mobile,
broadband or voice divisions are not suddenly going to be different—not at all.
If you unshackle Sensis, I guarantee it will increase rather than reduce in
price. So it would be great for the shareholders who the government wants to
look after. You are then creating a situation where you start pushing in the
direction of structural separation, without forcing it in that very rigid way
that some of the commentators are talking about and that we do not want. You
would actually be pushing it in the right direction and then you would start
seeing that if you start opening up that market, Telstra without Foxtel would
become far more involved in what is called broadband television, IPTV.[756]
6.166
Mr Budde
also argued that such a model would create competition in the media sector.
6.167
The Committee notes the CEPU's opposition to this
proposal,[757] but believes that
competition in the telecommunications market would be enhanced if Telstra were
required to divest itself of its share in Foxtel and of its ownership of its
HFC network, as it has previously recommended.[758]
6.168
The Committee heard evidence that ownership of both the
cable and copper network by a fully privatised Telstra, whose goal would be
maximising shareholder value and not national interest, would be disastrous for
competition and innovation. Telstra would continue to squeeze the maximum value
out of the 100% owned copper network, staving off competition in the HFC
network. As this behaviour would be difficult to regulate, the Committee
believes that if privatised Telstra should be required to divest the HFC cable.
If on the other hand Telstra remained in public hands, the Government as
majority shareholder could play a greater role in encouraging access to both
networks, although the Government has been reluctant in the past to be involved
in strategic and operational decisions. The Committee believes that further
consideration would need to be given to the merits of divesting the HFC cable
while Telstra remained in majority public ownership.
Recommendation 18
6.169 The Committee recommends that Telstra be required to
divest its shareholding in Foxtel.
Recommendation 19
6.170 The Committee recommends that:
- if Telstra is fully privatised, it
be a condition of the sale that Telstra be required to divest its HFC network;
and
- if Telstra remains in public hands,
the Government direct the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission to
provide further advice on its recommendations in its report Emerging Structures in the Communications
Sector that Telstra be required to divest itself of its HFC network.
Investment in infrastructure
6.171
In chapters 4 and 5 the Committee discussed concerns
that a large percentage of the Government's HiBIS funding, designed to promote
infrastructure competition in regional Australia, was going to Telstra to
upgrade its regional network and that there is growing concern in regional and
rural Australian about the future of the USO.
6.172
In regional NSW the Committee was told about the
presence of unused telecommunications infrastructure in the form of 'dark
fibre', that is, fibre optic cable which is not activated. As discussed in Chapter
4, Telstra asserted that dark fibre was laid to accommodate future demand or
serve as a back-up if activated cable were damaged. In north Queensland,
representatives from James Cook
University referred to a separate
fibre optic network which runs from Brisbane
through to Townsville, a distance of over 1500 kilometres. The Committee formed
the opinion that in populated corridors of Australia
there is currently a range of optic fibre infrastructure. Much of this
infrastructure is owned by State and Territory governments, government
authorities, and local councils and utilities, and some of this infrastructure
is still dark. Attempts by the Committee to seek a clearer national picture of
this infrastructure were largely unsuccessful. The Committee believes that in
order to stimulate infrastructure-based competition, an accurate national
picture of what currently exists must be established.[759]
6.173
Mr Malcolm
Moore provided the Committee with an outline
of a model for increasing telecommunication facilities in regional Australia.
However, he pointed out that for this to be achieved:
... it is essential to identify if there is any optical fibre
linking any of these areas, and these actual fibre routes need to be
identified. It does not matter who owns this fibre and if it is in use or not ...[760]
Recommendation 20
6.174 The Government should undertake a mapping exercise of
optic fibre networks in Australia.
Particular consideration should be given to mapping of 'dark' fibre and
infrastructure owned by government authorities, local councils and utilities.
Meeting consumer demands
6.175
While the Telecommunications Act states that one of the
main objects of the regulatory regime is to promote the 'long term interests of
end users', the Committee heard many times during this inquiry that the
self-regulatory regime has failed to give consumers adequate protection.
Moreover, the Committee heard repeated criticism of the USO, particularly in
rural and regional areas, in terms of the range and reliability of current
services. Access to broadband is now considered a vital part of many businesses
in rural and regional areas, but problems of availability, reliability and cost
are apparent in many areas.
The Universal Service Obligation
6.176
As discussed in Chapter 5, a key criticism of the USO
is that it only allows for the provision of a Standard Telephone Service (STS)
and the 'legitimate expectations of the Australian community' now go beyond a
copper wire voice service. Another criticism is the costing and funding
arrangements that require telecommunication service providers to subsidise the
Universal Service Provider, Telstra.
6.177
The Committee notes the suggestions that broadband
should become an integral part of the USO and could be used to explore future
opportunities in the USO environment.[761]
However, the Committee notes that there has been no attempt to analyse the
costs of providing this service to all users on request, and considers that
other policy options are available, as discussed in the next section.
6.178
The Committee also acknowledges that further broadening
of the USO would exacerbate conflicts about how the USO should be funded. Telecommunications
providers argue that the levy is another obstacle to expanding their broadband services
in regional and remote Australia,
while Telstra argues that it is subsidising the USO.
6.179
This inquiry heard strongly conflicting views over
whether the current funding arrangements should continue or whether Telstra
should fund the existing USO. The Committee notes in particular DCITA's
recommendation in 2004 that Telstra should fund all costs associated with the
traditional STS provision, and that this recommendation has not been
implemented. However, USO subsidies have been steadily reduced from $240m in
2001-02 to a projected $145m by 2007-08. Consequently the imposition on other industry
participants has been reduced significantly. The Committee considers that the
Government should review the basis of the funding in two to three years time,
prior to the setting of the next three years of USO subsidies. By that time,
other regulatory measures will be in place and there may be new or different
considerations.
Recommendation 21
6.180 The Committee recommends that the Government review the
basis of funding for the Universal Service Obligation prior to setting the
subsidies for the next three year cycle to commence from 2007-08.
Broadband
6.181
In recent years, the community's demands for access to
telecommunications have increased. To have equality of access for all
Australians now means equality of access to broadband, as the Broadband Advisory Group's Report to Government recognised
in January 2003. The report states:
The principal challenges are geographic considerations,
technological limitations and availability, perceptions about price and the
value proposition of broadband and the need for a national strategic approach
to broadband rollout...The Government should promote investment in those areas of
Australia that are likely to remain underserved purely by the private sector.
As identified in the Estens Inquiry, rural and regional areas are a priority.
The development of demand aggregation strategies should be used to assist in
this process.[762]
6.182
The Higher Bandwidth Incentive Scheme (HiBIS), funded
by the federal government, has gone some way towards providing broadband to
rural and regional areas. However, as noted in Chapter 5, witnesses indicate
that monthly payments are too costly for rural and regional Australians[763] and some service providers do not
sign up to the scheme because of recurring costs.[764]
6.183
The Committee takes particular note of the fact that an
equitable roll out of broadband services is of importance to Australians living
in rural, regional and remote areas, and that a strategy is required to achieve
universal access. As the CEPU states:
Contrary to the wishful thinking of the Page Report, there are
no short cuts to an equitable broadband future.[765]
6.184
The Committee further notes that at the recent Regional
Telecommunications Forum in Sydney,
representatives of 25 regional cities called for high-capacity broadband
infrastructure across Australia
by 2010. Delegates agreed that 'access to high-speed broadband was 'absolutely
critical' to ensure Australia
remained globally competitive'.[766]
The group aims to work with the Federal Government to achieve this goal.
Recommendation 22
6.185 The Committee recommends that the Government carry out
a cost analysis of the Higher Bandwidth Incentive Scheme (HiBIS) immediately to
ascertain how equitable universal broadband access can be ultimately provided.
6.186
The Committee recognises that there are no regulatory
requirements in place for the rollout of any infrastructure other than the
mobile infrastructure.[767] This
results in 48.9% of HiBIS customers currently being supplied by satellite,[768] which is the highest proportion of
all the methods available to deliver broadband. Satellite delivery does not
create an infrastructure that would otherwise provide opportunities for a
greater number of customers in a local area to access broadband. This does not
allow the Demand Aggregation Policy to deliver the required outcomes; it should
be urgently reviewed.[769]
6.187
Mr David
Spence from Unwired Australia stated that:
We believe that encouragement of other medium sized and smaller
companies to roll out in regional Australia
is beneficial for future competition and prices in the market. For instance,
there is the HiBIS fund at the moment for broadband in rural and regional Australia,
and Telstra gets most of the HiBIS funding. We believe it would be better in
the long term for that funding to go to companies other than Telstra.[770]
6.188
The Committee notes that the Government has put a
ceiling on Telstra's eligible claim on the HiBIS funds at 60%.[771] Latest figures available, as at 23 May 2005, indicate that Telstra
has received $25.218m of the total $39.353m of the HiBIS subsidy claimed to
that date.[772] Telstra has 11,233
customers using broadband in the scheme. The nearest HiBIS provider is
BorderNet, whose claims amount to $2.95m (1179 customers) to the same date.[773]
6.189
The Committee considers that to create broadband
competition, providers should be given incentives to apply for registration as
a broadband service provider through the HiBIS. The Committee believes that
incentives that favour proposals which create broadband infrastructure, rather than
proposals that simply provide broadband to a single customer through satellite,
would result in more opportunities for consumers to get access to broadband.
6.190
The Committee notes that the current HiBIS Program
Guidelines state:
The HiBIS Service Area may also be defined by the locations to
which it is technically or financially feasible to offer the proposed HiBIS
Service, rather than by a discrete
geographic area. For example, a HiBIS Provider providing HiBIS Services via
satellite may define its HiBIS Service Area to include those Premises only
serviceable by satellite solutions.
HiBIS Service Areas must be within the HiBIS Area.
An Applicant’s proposed HiBIS Service Area must be defined with
sufficient specificity to enable a clear understanding by DCITA and the
Applicant’s potential Customers of the circumstances and locations in which the
Applicant will provide a HiBIS Service.
DCITA reserves the right to reject any application which, in its
view, indicates the Applicant has defined the service area to target a
particular Customer group, rather than all Eligible Customers able to receive
the service in a HiBIS Service Area.[774]
6.191
The Committee recognises that the HiBIS currently
allows registered service providers to avoid developing infrastructure for broadband
delivery, thereby limiting the number of Eligible Customers access to
broadband. There is no obligation to provide a means for future customers to
access broadband.
Broadband options
6.192
There are a number of options available to achieve
equitable broadband accessibility, particularly in regional, rural and remote
communities. The Committee has heard that broadband should become part of the
USO, with the required extra funding coming from increased industry subsidies;[775] that the USO should remain as an STS
provision, funded by Telstra and leaving the development of broadband to the
telecommunications service providers;[776]
and that the government should set a ten year national target for an optic
fibre consumer access network roll-out, overseen by the ACMA.[777]
6.193
The Committee, however, favours the consideration of
further developing the Higher Bandwidth Incentive Scheme (HiBIS), so that a
service provider would receive suitable financial subsidies from the Government
to develop broadband services in specified rural, regional and remote areas
according to a scale that favours the development of broadband infrastructure
over single satellite pickup. The Committee does not suggest that satellite
services should not be subsidised at existing levels, but rather that financial
incentives be provided for developing infrastructure which may benefit multiple
users, where that is possible.
Recommendation 23
6.194 The Committee recommends that funding of the Higher Bandwidth
Incentive Scheme (HiBIS) be broadened according to the following provider subsidy
principles:
- a higher subsidy for a broadband service that
creates suitable and sufficient infrastructure for use by multiple consumers
(taking into account immediate and future needs of consumers in an area), such
as those using ADSL via cable or wireless; and
- the existing level of subsidy for a broadband
service delivered to individual consumers via satellite where other means such
as ADSL and CDMA can not be utilised.
6.195
The Committee also considers that HiBIS subsidies
should be sufficient to encourage potential broadband service providers to
apply for registration in the specified areas, and costed so as to allow them
to meet service obligations without undue financial and administrative burdens.
6.196
The scheme would rely on the development of realistic
pricing regimes for use of networks so as to encourage broadband service
providers to use cost-efficient means to deliver broadband to rural and remote
communities. The Committee has previously recognised the need for the ACCC to
investigate backhaul accessibility and costing arrangements for broadband
carriers.[778]
Recommendation 24
6.197 The Committee recommends that the ACCC examine the
availability of access to, and cost of, backhaul services for carriers building
or proposing to build new broadband infrastructure in regional Australia.
6.198
The Committee recognises the difficulties experienced
by smaller broadband service providers with fewer resources to apply for
registration with DCITA, and notes the complex application requirements, as
evidenced in the HiBIS Program Guidelines and Application for Registration.[779] The Committee considers that there
appears to be scope for simplification of that application process.
Recommendation 25
6.199 The Committee recommends that the Government consider
simplifying the HiBIS application requirements in order to give regional
broadband service providers more realistic opportunities to apply.
6.200
Apart from the complexities of applying for HiBIS
registration, the Committee heard evidence of delays in the processing of
completed applications. For example, one small telecommunications provider in
Townsville claimed that the ACA received its application for HiBIS registration
in October but did not finally register the organisation until April
the following year:
We were the first in Queensland
to come out with regional wireless broadband. We have been very restricted by
the authorities. We have got hundreds of thousands of dollars worth of capital
equipment sitting idle, waiting for licences and approvals from ACA.[780]
Recommendation 26
6.201 The Committee recommends that the Department of
Communications, Information Technology and the Arts streamline the processing
of applications from broadband service providers for registration with the
HiBIS.
6.202
The Committee recognises that the Digital Data
Service (DDS) and Special Digital Data Service (SDDS), which delivers access to
internet at around 19 kbps (non-broadband) through the normal telephony copper
wire, do not meet the legitimate expectations of the Australian community. The
broadening of the HiBIS as recommended by the Committee would mean that the DDS
and SDDS would eventually be replaced by broadband services that would meet
this expectation.
6.203
The Committee recognises the merit in local governments
developing business schemes with the potential to deliver affordable broadband
services to regional and remote areas, and supports efforts by local councils
in developing business models for trial.[781]
Recommendation 27
6.204 The Committee recommends that
the Government fund local governments to develop business models that focus on
delivering affordable local broadband services to regional and remote
Australians.
People with hearing and speech
impairment
6.205
The Committee is concerned that hearing and speech
impaired people do not have adequate access to telecommunications services. The
Australian Communications Exchange (ACE), in arguing for a new definition of
the Standard Telephone Service, argued that access to broadband would bring
significant benefits for hearing and speech impaired people. While the
Committee has not recommended that broadband be made part of the USO, improved
access to broadband through the HiBIS scheme would significantly assist hearing
and speech impaired people, providing that the service delivered the required
minimum 384kbps upstream and downstream for sign language over video.[782]
6.206
The Committee has previously recommended that a
disabilities equipment fund should be established,[783] and that consultation between
representatives of people with disabilities and telecommunications carriers
should be required to ensure that the new equipment will be available in
conjunction with the new technologies.[784]
Recommendation 28
6.207 The Committee recommends that the Government provide
funding to ensure that deaf and hearing and speech impaired people have equal
access to a suitable broadband service through HiBIS and through an independent
disabilities equipment program.
The Customer Service Guarantee
6.208
The Committee is concerned about the declining
telephone repair performance figures in rural Australia,
amounting to as much as five percent in recent years according to NFF
statistics. The Committee notes that the Government has yet to fulfil the
promise it made in 2003[785] to deliver
the outcomes recommended by the Estens Report. As the NFF noted, basic
telephone service fault and repair standards must be met before the Government
can claim that services in rural, regional and remote areas have been improved.[786] As discussed in Chapter 2, the NFF
disputes the Government's assessment of the status of implementation of several
of the Estens Report recommendations.
Recommendation 29
6.209 The Committee recommends that the Government fulfil its
promise to implement all 39 recommendations of the Estens Report. The Committee
further recommends that an independent audit of the Government's implementation
of the Estens Report recommendations be conducted prior to the introduction of
legislation providing for the further sale of Telstra.
Consumer protection
6.210
The Committee remains steadfast in its call for the
adoption of those strategies detailed in the ACA's Consumer Driven Communications (CDC) Final Report that better
protect the rights of the consumer in the telecommunications industry, and
supports the concept that telecommunications is primarily a service available
to all Australians. In particular the Committee endorses Recommendation 2 in
the CDC Report, which details proposed changes to paragraph 117(1)(i) of the Telecommunications
Act. The Committee seeks to ensure that the consumer drives the
telecommunications industry, and is disappointed that the ACA (now the ACMA)
has not yet responded to these recommendations.
Recommendation 30
6.211 The Committee recommends that the Australian
Communications and Media Authority give immediate and urgent consideration to
adopting the recommendations in the ACA research report Consumer Driven Communications: Strategies
for Better Representation so that the rights of consumers are better
protected, as previously recommended by the Committee.[787]
6.212
The Committee is concerned that there has been
considerable delay in the development by ACIF of some of the codes of practice
within the telecommunications industry. In particular, the Consumer Contracts
Industry code, which was five years in the writing, has still another year to
go before the ACMA can audit compliance. These delays have resulted, in some
cases, with undesirable industry practices flourishing unimpeded, particularly
those relating to unilateral alterations to the Standard Forms of Agreement
(SFOAs) in section 481 of the Telecommunications Act.
Recommendation 31
6.213 The Committee recommends that Part 6 of the Telecommunications Act 1997 be amended
to require the ACMA to enforce the development of codes within set time-frames.
Complaint handling and code
compliance
6.214
The Committee is concerned that many service providers
not only fail to resolve complaints satisfactorily but also fail to refer their
customers to the Telecommunications Industry Ombudsman (TIO).[788] The Committee notes that TIO figures
show only between 11% and 16% of all complaints to the TIO are referred to the
complaints handling scheme by the provider, despite the complaints code that
obliges providers to refer customers to the TIO.[789]
6.215
An ACA representative told the Committee the ACA had
sufficient power to deal with non-compliance,[790]
but the Committee is concerned that codes of practice have not been enforced by
the ACA, with only one instance of a direction being issued.[791] The growing number of overall complaints
and the growing number of customer service complaints dealt with by the TIO[792] indicate a fall-off in providers'
performance in resolving customer complaints. The Committee believes that the new
ACMA must do more to ensure compliance with industry codes of practice.
6.216
The Committee agrees with the CDC's recommendation,
supported during this inquiry by the Communications Law Centre, that the
Telecommunications Act should be amended to formalise monitoring of compliance
with codes of practice.[793] A new
section 120A should require reporting by suppliers/ industry associations on an
annual basis and, where the ACMA considers that monitoring is not providing
adequate or accurate data, monitoring by the ACMA.
Recommendation 32
6.217 The Committee recommends that the Telecommunications Act 1997 be amended by inserting a new section
120A that requires annual reporting by suppliers or industry associations of
compliance with industry codes and, where the ACMA considers that monitoring is
not providing adequate or accurate data, monitoring by the ACMA.
6.218
The TIO's figures on escalation rates of cases referred
to it show that almost 88% of customer complaints are not resolved between the
customer and the provider after referral back to the provider by the TIO (level
1 complaint). The TIO then has to escalate the complaint to level 2, at cost to
the provider. The TIO noted that since 2000, there had been 'a steady increase
in the level 2 escalation rate' (that is, the percentage of cases not resolved
at level 1). The rate was now 12% of all cases.[794]
6.219
The Committee believes that, to be effective, the
complaints handling scheme should develop in step with changes in the
telecommunications industry, should provide an adequate measure of protection to
consumers irrespective of the services and the technologies used, and should allow
consumers to bring a variety of complaints to the TIO in a way that increases
the efficiency of complaints handling in the industry, reduces any overlap in
jurisdiction and discourages consumers from forum shopping.[795]
6.220
The Committee has long held that the Telecommunications
Industry Ombudsman should be able to offer consumer services not only in
telecommunications but also in broader communications such as pay TV,
particularly in light of converging technologies.[796] The Committee repeats its previous
recommendation.
Recommendation 33
6.221 The Committee recommends that the Telecommunications (Consumer Protection and Service Standards Act 1997
be amended in order to establish a single Communications Industry Ombudsman.
Low income consumers
6.222
As Mr Paul
Budde stated, it must be remembered that
telecommunications provide not only economic but enormous social benefits:
It is important for our economy; it is important for our
lifestyle; it is important for our kids; it is important for poor people and
rich people and everybody else.[797]
6.223
The Committee considers that price controls provide
significant protection for low income customers. The Committee notes that the
Minister recently stated that the price control regime would be extended until 31 December 2005, pending the
Government's consideration of broader telecommunications regulation issues.
6.224
As discussed in Chapter 5, the ACCC considered that
Telstra's licence conditions which provide for measures such as LIMAC should be
amended to require Telstra to comply with a low-income package and associated
marketing plan specified by the Minister. The ACCC made a range of other
recommendations aimed at ensuring that Telstra's low-income consumers are no
worse off than its other users.[798] The Committee urges the Government to give
the ACCC's recommendations serious and prompt consideration and to report
publicly on which recommendations they will implement and which, if any, they
will not support, and the reasons why.
6.225
Groups such as LIMAC and CTN argued that all
telecommunications companies should have similar measures for those suffering
financial hardship. Moreover, it is clear that, although certain measures have
been put in place for fixed phones, there is concern about the impact on low
income consumers of mobile phones as well as new technologies such as 3G. The
Committee urges the Government and industry to put plans in place.
6.226
The Committee acknowledges that many consumers are
forced to purchase packages or bundles from service providers that contain some
services they do not wish to have, and that such consumers are only seeking to
access local services at minimal rates. Accordingly the Committee considers
that a basic residential package should be made available by all carriage
service providers.
Recommendation 34
6.227 The Committee recommends that all carriage service
providers make available a Basic Residential Package to households who want
only a clear, cost-based package of local access services.
The Emergency Call Service
6.228
Finally, the Committee is concerned that the ACA has
not yet considered the future development, funding, management and security of
the Emergency Call Service (E000) in light of the rapidly emerging
communications technologies, particularly VoIP.[799] The emergency call service,
currently administered by Telstra, is facing difficulties.[800] The Committee notes that, under Part
8 of the TCPSS Act, the ACA (now ACMA) may, by written determination, impose
emergency service requirements on all or any of the carriers, carriage service
providers and emergency call persons.
6.229
The Committee believes that planning and developing the
emergency service to take account of new technologies, particularly VoIP, is a
matter of urgency. After Telstra is fully privatised, the federal Government
should assume this responsibility.
Recommendation 35
6.230 The Committee recommends that the Government give
urgent consideration to the recommendations of the National Emergency
Communications Working Group, particularly in regard to new technologies such
as VoIP.
Senator Andrew
Bartlett
Chair
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page