Chapter 3 - Broadband uptake, impediments and competition
Introduction
3.1
This chapter examines the current level of competition
in broadband services. Specifically it looks at impediments to both broadband
uptake and competition. As the Australian Telecommunications Users Group (ATUG)
told the Committee in overview:
The Australian market is not effectively competitive due to lack
of robust infrastructure competition, and ineffective access to the
infrastructure that does exist.[81]
Uptake of broadband technology
3.2
The Australian Competition and Consumer Commission's
Snapshot of Broadband Deployment, as at 31 December 2003, found that total broadband take-up was 698,700
and that:
Broadband take-up has increased by 335 200, or 92.2 per cent,
from the December 2002 figure of 363 500.
3.3
However, the rate of broadband growth slowed over the
last three quarters of 2003:
In Q4 2003, the growth rate was 14.4 per cent, compared to 18.2
per cent in Q3 2003 and 22 per cent in Q2 2003.
During this period, the quarterly growth rate decreased across
each type of broadband technology.
3.4
The 14.4 per cent growth rate for the December 2003
quarter represents the lowest quarterly increase recorded in the period covered
by the survey.
3.5
Within this context, other DSL services continued to
achieve the highest growth rate, increasing by 31.4 per cent in the December
quarter.[82]
3.6
Of the report findings, ACCC Commissioner
Mr Ed Willett
said:
The 14.4 per cent growth rate for the December 2003 quarter
represents the lowest quarterly increase recorded in the period covered by the
survey.
However it should also be noted that these growth figures
pre-date the changes in pricing structures for broadband services that began in
February 2004. The impact of these changes will not become evident until take-up
figures become available for the March 2004 and June 2004 quarters.[83]
3.7
Mr Bill
Scales from Telstra told the Committee that the
company has set ambitious targets for broadband uptake:
We aim to have one million broadband customers by the end of
2005 and $1 billion in broadband revenue by the end of 2006. I am pleased
to say that we are on track to reach both of these quite aggressive targets.[84]
3.8
Telstra has argued that Australias level of ADSL
penetration, in year three of its rollout (2003) exceeds the level of uptake at
the same period in France, Canada and the United States and that international comparisons
suggest that Australias broadband progress is consistent with or better than other
countries in the early stage of technology adoption.[85]
Figure 1: International
comparisons of year three penetration rates[86]
3.9
Telstra's submission cited the Network Economics
Consulting Group (NECG) study, which investigated the impact of regulatory and
other economic factors on broadband take-up internationally, in support of its
contention that there was no evidence to confirm that its ownership of an HFC
network was leading to reduced broadband penetration:
NECG examined the full OECD broadband penetration database to
see if there was any correlation between broadband penetration and
participation by the incumbent telecommunications carrier in either the largest
cable network operator, or any cable network operator. The analysis allows NECG
to conclude that:
cross-ownership
of the largest cable and copper networks by the incumbent carrier does not
have a statistically significant adverse impact on broadband penetration.
In addition, although the dummy variables for the ownership
influence of incumbent carriers could not be considered statistically
significant:
[t]he
direction of influence implies that divestiture or removal of the influence of
the incumbent telecommunications carrier would lead to lower, not higher, penetration.[87]
3.10
NECG found that broadband penetration could be
explained by the age of the technology, real GDP per capita, and the
penetration of subscription television:
Australian broadband penetration rates are not significantly
lower than the average of the countries in the OECD data base, when due account
is taken of basic economic factors explaining penetration rates [O]ne cannot
conclude, based on a simple economic model and formal statistical criteria,
that the Australian penetration rate is significantly lowed than [the OECD]
average.[88]
3.11
However, the ACCC has raised concerns over the
statistical model developed in the report and the subsequent conclusions.[89] It submitted that:
In particular, the Commission has identified a number of factors
that may limit the explanatory power of the statistical model developed within
this report, including that:
-
as specified, it
does not take account of 'price', 'quality', 'competition' or 'computer
use/penetration' as factors explaining broadband penetration across countries;
-
it relied on some
questionable assumptions regarding how the 'age of technology' variable is introduced
into the analysis; and
-
preliminary
statistical testing suggests that it violates some of the fundamental
assumptions of regression modelling.[90]
3.12
The ACCC engaged Associate Professor Ian
Gordon of the Statistical Consulting Centre
at the University of Melbourne
to undertake an independent review on the NECG model and the conclusions drawn
from that model. Associate Professor Gordon
found:
There are significant problems with the model, even if the
variables considered are assumed to be the only ones relevant. I think that
the intrinsic complexity of the situation makes a regression approach of
limited value, for the goals of identifying whether countries are significantly
behind other countries, and assessing whether cross-ownership affects broadband
penetration. The other differences between countries with and without
cross-ownership make a causal inference very difficult, based on observational
data, and in my opinion such an inference cannot be drawn on the available
data.[91]
3.13
Overwhelmingly, the Committee heard that broadband take
up rates in Australia
were low and were falling in comparison to many international markets:
It is encouraging that the growth rate over the last quarter
remained steady rather than continuing to decline. This is still of concern,
however, as Australia is lagging behind many other developed nations in terms
of broadband take-upBroadband markets in Australia will need to develop much
more quickly if Australia is to retain, let alone improve, its comparative
international position.[92]
3.14
In September 2003, the OECD ranked Australia
21st in broadband uptake per head of population.[93] Vertel argued
that when contrasted with broadband penetration rates of other countries, Australia
fairs badly with only 5% of homes connected to broadband:
Hong Kong
|
52%
|
Singapore
|
25%
|
USA
|
19%
|
France
|
13%
|
Australia
|
5%
|
Figure 2: Percentage
of homes connected with broadband internet. [94]
3.15
Mr Paul
Budde told the Committee that:
Australia
is already well behind comparable trading partners in broadbanding. In 2003 it
features at the bottom end of the OECD rankings. A continuation of relatively
slow growth will see the country lagging further behind in years to come.[95]
3.16
It has been suggested that broadband uptake is driven
by a variety of factors including the ability of services to meet customer
service demands. The Committee heard that in order to drive broadband take up,
products and services need to be offered in a way that meets demand. Optus
contended that to date the demand for broadband has been driven by the
following factors:
(a) convenience -
customers wanting an always on connection and to be able to use the telephone
and access the Internet at the same time;
(b) value the cost of
the broadband service relative to the cost of dial-up (including accessing the
Internet using a second dial-up line);
(c) price certainty
being able to access broadband services using flat rate plans with no excess
usage charges (so users do not face unexpected prices for exceeding usage
limits);
(d) performance speed;
and
(e) content the
availability of video streamlining, downloading music and other multimedia
content.[96]
Impediments to broadband uptake
3.17
Undoubtedly, the reasons for Australia's
slow broadband growth and uptake in comparison to many other countries are complex.
Evidence to the inquiry suggested that the key impediments to broadband uptake
include availability of infrastructure, technical limitations, price and knowledge
and perceptions about the value of upgrading to broadband technology.[97]
Network capability
3.18
The vast majority of the Customer Access Network (CAN),
laid over decades, was designed to only deliver voice telephony. Twisted pair
copper has been used since the 1880s as submarine cables and domestically from the
1930s and 1940s. After this period insulated copper pairs were used in the
standard access network and almost all residential homes connect with it. Much
of this cable has now been in the ground for 40 years and as the copper has
aged it has crystallised and become brittle.[98] The ageing
network, coupled with the fact that the CAN was not engineered for the provision
of data services is an impediment to the growth of broadband uptake. As Telstra
explained:
The bulk of Australias
existing copper telephone network (and the networks in all other countries) was
developed prior to the invention of the Internet, and was never designed to
carry ADSL.[99]
3.19
A number of submissions similarly made the point that
broadband services are not widely available because of the limited capacity of
the existing infrastructure:
It should be profoundly obvious to all but the most inept, that
the common technologies used for providing access for telephony are not suitable
for Broadband distribution. An entirely different customer access network
infrastructure is an imperative that must be implemented as a priority, and
this is the first and biggest impediment to be overcome: with or without
competition.[100]
3.20
Mr Charles
Reed from Personal Broadband Australia Pty
Ltd told the Committee:
The first point I would like to bring up is that our position
and our opinion is that the low uptake of broadband is largely a supply issue,
rather than a demand or pricing issue. Some of the supply reasons are quite
evident. They include issues around the existing copper network and the fact
that it was not really designed for a high bandwidth data type service, with
the limitations you heard about earlier on RIM block type areas leading toto
plagiarise your words, if I maypair gain victims. There are issues with DSL of
distance from the exchange, and there are difficulties and complexities around
things like multi-dwelling units in high-rise buildings. There is also the age
of the actual copper. As the copper deteriorates, putting high bandwidth
through it becomes harder. Our position is that it is a supply issue, rather
than a demand issue.[101]
3.21
Similarly, the Committee heard a significant amount of evidence
on the technical constraints which restrict broadband access:
The supply side is the dominant impediment to the uptake of
broadband technology. Whilst Telstra is an easy target in this debate, the
existing copper network was only designed to carry voice and simply is not
designed for the supply of broadband. The following problems with their network
are well documented:
Rim blocked areas;
Pair gain
impediments;
Distance from the
exchange (3.4 km or less);
Not available to
multi-dwelling apartments; and
Age of the copper
network affecting its quality.
As a result, broadband has a poor image in terms of both
availability and service quality and we believe this is a contributing factor
to broadbands low adoption rate. [102]
3.22
Asymmetrical Digital Subscriber Line (ADSL) technology
was developed in order to allow delivery of broadband technology over the
copper twisted network. However, submitters advised the Committee that ADSL and
other broadband services are simply not available to many regional institutions[103] and large
numbers of individuals.[104]
3.23
Telstra contends that there are three main reasons why
some customers may not be able to access broadband via ADSL. These are:
-
the serving Telstra exchange may not be
ASDL-enabled;
-
the customers premises may be beyond the
technical limits for ADSL transmission;
-
the telephone service may not be provided via a
straight copper line but via some kind of electronic access line technology,
commonly referred to as a pair gain system (PGS).[105]
3.24
A number of submissions were received from private
citizens unable to access broadband technologies due to either lack of
infrastructure or unsuitable infrastructure.[106] Mr
Kaon Li told
the Committee that:
My current place of abode cannot get ADSL or cable. When I
apply for ADSL, I have received a notification that the exchange I'm on is a
secondary exchange, and there is no plan to upgrade the exchange to support
ADSL anytime soon according to Telstra. I believe there are a lot more people
like myself in Australia
who cannot get access to either ADSL or cable, and the greatest impediments to
uptake of broadband technology may be that for many it simply isn't available.[107]
3.25
Similarly, Mr Graham
Leake told the Committee that:
There are a large number of people unable to connect to a
physical (non-satellite) broadband connection in any older or outer suburbs of
capital cities, including myself. Most CBDs are wired up with new cable or radio-WAN;
country areas are being focussed on through issues with selling Telstra, but
those of us in the middle are falling through the cracks.
I have tried for 3 years to get connected to ADSL or any other
512kbit or faster interface, and I am only 9km from the Perth GPO. We are the
group of people "more than 3km from an exchange", usually on older
exchanges.
I have spoken to many people over the last few years who are all
in the same position - can't get ADSL, can't get cable, and radio WANs have not
yet been set up to cover residential areas. I also notice a lot of similar
complaints on the Whirlpool broadband internet forum.
In conclusion, the above problem of the outer and older suburbs
is impeding the take-up of broadband services.[108]
3.26
The inadequacy of telecommunications infrastructure also
affects populations living in newer suburbs, such as in Gungahlin in the ACT.
TransACT told the Committee that:
Gungahlin is one of the fastest growing areas not only of Canberra,
but also across Australia.
There were almost 20,000 persons living in Gungahlin in the year 2000 with
projected estimate of 37,000 persons by 2010. This represents an annual
population growth of 8.8%. Gungahlin is currently not well served
by Broadband technology because of the inadequate Telecommunications
infrastructure. All electricity cabling is underground. The costs of connecting
services to underground cabling is high and as a result, TransACT has had to
rate Gungahlin as a later priority for providing its Broadband Services. In the
past, Telstras ADSL service have been unavailable in Gungahlin resulting in
significant negative impacts on residents, families and local business.[109]
3.27
As discussed in Chapter 1 of this report and throughout
this Committee's earlier report on the Australian telecommunications network, broadband
services can be delivered by a range of technologies. The Committee notes that,
in every circumstance where broadband cannot be obtained via DSL technology, it
is available through satellite. However, this technology is troubled by issues
of latency or propagation delay (for a more detailed discussion see the
Committee's report into the Australian telecommunications network inquiry) and,
as discussed below, is not an affordable method of broadband delivery for many
customers.
Cost
3.28
Pricing is an important and frequently underestimated
impediment to the uptake of broadband technology. The cost of broadband access
in Australia is
a significant factor in the low rate of broadband uptake, as is the relative low
cost of dial-up 'narrowband' connections.[110] Mr
James Nichols
told the Committee:
I am considering getting broadband, on either cable or ADSL, but
believe it is about $80 per month which is too much for my budget. Considering
I am single and in the top income bracket, I find it hard to see how the
average consumer can afford broadband services.[111]
3.29
The cost of residential ADSL in Australia
is high in comparison to a number of other countries, with Australia
having the third highest one-off installation cost.[112]
Figure 3: International comparison of broadband costs as a
percentage of monthly wage.[113]
3.30
A number of local governments emphasise cost as a major
impediment to uptake of broadband in their regions. Blacktown City Council told
the Committee that:
However, broadband from phone and cable companies can cost over
$60 a month. Many Web users will remain with dial-up due to cost. In Blacktown,
most households earn less than $50,000 a year, so many consumers simply can't
afford broadband.[114]
3.31
While the Townsville City Council argued that:
Pricing of broadband services remains unacceptably high and
unattractive to many Townsville consumers. At present, the entry price level
for domestic broadband services is around $60 per month plus installation
costs. For many residents and businesses, this price is simply prohibitive or
at the very least unjustifiable.[115]
3.32
The Australian Industry Group argued that cost
prevented 29% of all firms not using advanced telecommunications from broadband
uptake.[116] However,
a number of submissions went further to claim that a pricing structure which
includes limits on the volume of downloads per month was an impediment to broadband
uptake and expansion.[117]
Most broadband service agreements restrict the amount of data
that can be downloaded in any month. This severely restricts the way in which
the service can be used. In business terms, it equates to one reasonable sized
database or one relatively small software application. The capabilities of
broadband services currently on offer are more commercially aligned to premium
narrowband services than to a true broadband service offering connection speeds
measured in multiples of megabits with no download limits. This is because the
current pricing arrangement effectively restricts the use of a broadband
service so that while it may be fast and always connected, it is used sparingly
due to the cost of exceeding the download limit.[118]
3.33
The extensive use of download caps and 'throttles' by
ISPs also deters broadband usage and modifiers the end user's behaviour so that
broadband services are used as a high-speed data service rather than as a true
broadband.[119]
Submitters were critical of this practice:
Price elasticity is further impacted in the Australian context
by the prevalence of broadband caps. Australia
is one of the few countries that has caps, which act as a strong deterrent to
the use of broadband applications by end-users. It is ironic that
telecommunications is one of the few industries in Australia
that actively promotes a limitation of use! The price penalties for exceeding
caps are also significant. Some ISPs throttle services as users reach their
caps; others allow users to continue using and charge very high surcharge
penalties. Both of these responses have the effect of deterring usage of the
broadband service, thereby reducing the public benefits of broadband service
provision.[120]
3.34
For regional and remote populations which rely on
satellite services, cost of infrastructure installation is a significant inhibiting
factor.[121]
The Committee was told that installation fees for satellite services are in excess
of $1000 for a single user in Alice Springs[122] and significantly
more in less populated regional towns. The Cabonne Council located in Molong,
central NSW noted that two-way satellite costs approximately $4000 to install
and $80 per month to access.[123] The Communications
Expert Group told the Committee that:
Satellite Broadband is too expensive and is likely to remain
beyond the reach of many businesses and individuals in remote areas.[124]
3.35
Conversely, Telstra told the Committee that the extent
to which the price of broadband influences the rate of broadband penetration is
an open question. They cite the Western Australian Technology and Industry
Advisory Council which found that:
There appears to be little correlation
between affordability and take-up. For example, South Korea performs poorly in terms of affordability of both cable and
ADSL services. This is despite the fact that they have the highest take-up of
broadband services in the world. Similarly, France has a broadband take-up rate fractionally higher than Australia despite the fact that both ADSL and cable services are
significantly more affordable in Australia (measured as a percentage of per capita GDP) than in France. Again this suggests that the impediment to broadband take-up
is not ability to pay but willingness to pay.[125]
3.36
However, in the United
Kingdom rapid broadband uptake was achieved
after regulatory intervention saw prices dropped significantly.[126] Similarly, Telstra
itself saw a considerable influx of new broadband customers after it lowered
its broadband price to $29.95 per month in February 2004. In a media release
dated 5 March 2004,
Telstra claimed that its lower retail prices were having a significant impact
on uptake of broadband services:
Consumers are voting with their feet and taking-up broadband in
record numbers, following recent price reductions across the entire market.
The strong consumer response means the broadband market is
expanding rapidly, with more than 10 per cent of Australian homes already connected,.
By offering broadband at prices equal to those prevailing
elsewhere in the market, Telstra is helping expand the market and increase the
nation's rate of broadband take-up.
Since Telstra announced discounted broadband prices in the
middle of February, broadband applications have more than doubled, and the rate
of greatest growth was being experienced amongst wholesale ISP customers of
Telstra.[127]
3.37
In June 2004, Telstra issued a further media release
detailing the large growth in customer numbers as a result of its February 2004
price reduction. Mr Bruce
Akhurst, Group Managing Director, Telstra
Wholesale, Broadband and Media said:
Telstra has signed its 750,000th broadband customer this week,
following a 46 per cent surge in demand in just five months. Telstra will beat
its target of one million broadband customers by the end of next year. We are
now on track to achieve that six months early, by the end of June 2005.
By dropping broadband prices, Telstra set off an avalanche of
customer demand. We have been setting and then breaking records ever since.[128]
3.38
The Committee concludes that cost is a factor in the
uptake of broadband services. As Mr Steve
Ireland told the Committee:
[The] key impediment to the broad uptake of broadband [is]
price. I pay $94.95 per month. It's too much and the price needs to be $50.00.
End of story! This issue by far outweighs the rest of the issues.[129]
Customer knowledge
3.39
Many submitters point to a lack of customer
understanding as an impediment to broadband uptake. This issue is compounded by
the fact that available services and contract and terms of service are complex
and confusing.[130]
cBallarat argued that a lack of a general knowledge-base, service confusion and
complexity, including lack of understanding of what broadband means and complex
multi-tiered service contracts all impede broadband uptake.[131]
3.40
Additionally, Neighborhood Cable argued that the
general population has no clear understanding of what broadband over fibre is
or of the level of service that can be delivered over it. This may account to
some degree why customers do not take up the superior technology.[132]
3.41
The need for a public education program was raised with
the Committee as was the fact that Telstra uses market power to 'dumb down'
consumers in order to sell inferior telecommunications products:
There has been a lot of discussion this morning about defining
broadband. I must admit I think that is a key function. There are a lot of
statements in the marketplace at the moment and there is a lot of need for
education. I believe that education falls upon Telstra. With its marketing
dollars, the way it advertises and the way it spends, it should not dumb down
the market. That type of dumbing down of broadband is not doing anybody any
real benefit.[133]
Impediments to broadband competition
3.42
The Committee recognises that competition in broadband
services occurs in the CBD areas of Australia.[134] However, in
regional and rural Australia,
where it is more difficult to establish a business case for broadband
infrastructure deployment, competition is limited. Mr
Moore told the Committee that:
Although Optical Fibre is connected to major businesses in the
CBDs, virtually no optical fibre connects from the local exchanges to the homes
and this will be the next big move.[135]
3.43
Telstra submitted that there is strong competition in
all broadband market sectors, evident by the 200 ISPs competing for the
provision of one or more types of broadband services in Australia.
It added that effective competition has delivered broadband services over ADSL
and HFC cable at prices that are more affordable than in many other countries.[136]
3.44
However, it is widely argued that Telstra's monopoly
position limits effective competition in the broadband market. At a speech in
November 2003 to the Australian Financial Review Telecom Summit, ACCC Chairman,
Mr Graeme
Samuel, claimed that:
The existence of such extensive market power in a vertically
integrated firm is a major risk to competitive outcomes. Telstra has both the
ability and, importantly, the incentive to frustrate entry into complementary
and substitute markets by other companies.[137]
Broadband market
3.45
Telstra has 68% of the broadband market on its several
fibre and copper networks and is strong in both metropolitan and regional
markets. Optus has about 22%, predominantly in metropolitan markets, and the
other competitive providers share the remaining 10%.[138] Bits on
Light submitted the following comprehensive summary:
Both metropolitan and
regional coverage
-
Telstra HFC network - coverage is passing 2.5M
homes - 40,000km of cable covering Melbourne, Sydney, Brisbane, Gold Coast,
Adelaide & Perth. This required an investment of $4B. There is currently no
retail competition on this network.
-
Telstra Fibre network Telstra has deployed
over 140,000 km of fibre in Australia. Significantly in the metropolitan, suburban,
and regional network the breadth and depth of Telstra fibre coverage is without
parallel.
Predominantly metropolitan
coverage
-
Optus HFC network - coverage available to 1.4M homes
21,000km of cable covering Melbourne, Sydney, and Brisbane. Notably it is
widely believed there is an 80% overlap with the Telstra HFC. This required an
investment of $3B. The total number of Broadband customers on the Optus HFC
network is 110K and other Optus broadband networks is at most 9.5K. There is
currently no retail competition on this network.
-
Optus Fibre, LMDS and DSL network - Optus has
deployed over 8,700 km of fibre (1/16th of that of Telstra), including
inter-capital and CBD fibre rings in the capital cities. In addition over 100
exchanges have coverage with DSL. There is some retail competition on these
networks.
-
Other Competitive DSL providers include Request
Broadband, NEC/Nextep, Primus, AAPT and Powertel. These have all focused on the
business market & therefore collectively only currently have coverage in
<110 largely="" overlapping="" exchanges.="" the="" non-telstra="" dsl="" networks="" rely="" heavily="" on="" the="" declared="" services="" of="" facilities="" access="" to="" exchange="" building,="" ull="" and="" spectrum="" sharing.="" in="" addition="" they="" rely="" on="" transmission="" services="" (bandwidth),="" which="" is="" not="" declared,="" to="" the="" exchange="" buildings.="" there="" is="" significant="" retail="" competition="" on="" and="" between="" these="" dsl="" networks,="" however="" the="" retail="" floor="" price="" for="" these="" business="" services="" is="" currently="" close="" to="" $100,="" due="" to="" the="" high="" input="" costs="" of="" the="" declared="" services.="" the="" estimated="" number="" of="" broadband="" customers="" on="" these="" dsl="" provider="" networks="" is="">110>< 20k.="">
-
Uecomm Fibre network - Uecomm has fibre to over
650 buildings primarily in the CBD areas Brisbane, Sydney, Melbourne and the
Gold Coast, with some metropolitan coverage. There is some retail competition on
this network.
-
Powertel Fibre network - Powertel has fibre to
over 400 buildings primarily in the CBD areas Brisbane, Sydney, Melbourne and
the Gold Coast, with some metropolitan coverage. There is some retail
competition on this network.
-
Other CBD Fibre networks include AAPT, Primus
and MCI/Worldcom. These networks are often limited to the CBDs of the capital
cities. There is some retail competition on these networks. The estimated
number of Broadband customers on these fibre networks is < 5k.="">
Predominantly regional
coverage
-
TransACT Fibre/VDSL network (Canberra ACT).
Coverage goal of 100K homes in the ACT, with currently around 60K homes and 5K
businesses covered with an investment of approx. $300M. TransACT has at least
20K customers on their network (incl. Pay TV, telephony & Broadband). There
is retail competition on this network. The estimated number of Broadband
customers on TransACT is 4.2K .
-
Neighborhood Cable HFC network (Geelong,
Ballarat, Mildura in Victoria). By the end of 2003, the coverage will extend to
90K homes with an investment of approx. $60M. Neighborhood Cable has 5.4K
customers on their network (incl. Pay TV, telephony & Broadband).The
estimated number of Broadband customers on Neighborhood Cable is 1.1K.[139]
3.46
The Committee consistently heard that Telstra's control
over considerable sections of the telecommunications sector and its near monopoly
control of the infrastructure in regional and rural Australia
was a significant impediment to competition in broadband.[140] Key
barriers include: the lack of facilities or infrastructure based competition,
especially in outer suburban and rural and regional areas; Telstra's slow
investment in alternative infrastructure technology; the power of the 1st
tier carriers to peer; and the interconnection of both Telstra's wholesale and
retail markets with Telstra's ability to bundle services and wall customers.
Investment in infrastructure and technology
3.47
The high cost to build infrastructure and Australia's
small geographically dispersed population significantly restricts infrastructure-based
competition in the telecommunications sector. The current level of
infrastructure based broadband competition in Australia
is minimal outside of CBDs. The Committee heard from Mr Fred
Grossman from Neighborhood Cable who argued
that:
Australia
is a long way behind most developed countries. I think that is a fact that I do
not need to talk about. One of the reasons for that is the lack of
infrastructure based competition. One of the reasons the US
has done well is the infrastructure based competition between
telecommunications and cable TV networks.[141]
3.48
As noted in Chapter 1 the Committee heard that in late
2003 the ACCC allowed Telstra, under merger regulations, to purchase the IP1
fibre optic network which runs from Melbourne
to Bunbury. The network was originally rolled out to provide direct competition
to Telstra across Western Australia
and that the recent acquisition of this network by Telstra is argued to have
had a negative impact on broadband competition.
3.49
Of the decision to allow Telstra to purchase the IP1
network and the effect on wholesale prices of infrastructure competition, Mr
Paul Budde
said:
The reality, unfortunately, is that Telstra was the only one to
do it. My heart bled, because when IP1 was announcednot installed;
announcedprices went down 40 per cent; that is, wholesale prices for Telstra.
In your state of Queensland,
Chair, in Central Queensland, with a whole new backbone,
prices dropped by 25 per cent instantly. That is what IP1, Next-Gen and all
these new backbones are doing. In Tasmania,
where there is no competition, prices are 40 to 60 per cent higher than on the
mainland. from a state development point of view that it really is a sad
story.[142]
3.50
Optus has HCF cable networks in certain parts of Sydney,
Melbourne and Brisbane.[143] Nexium Telecommunications,
Neighborhood Cable and TransACT have invested and rolled out limited cable
infrastructure in Queensland, Victoria
and the ACT respectively. However, infrastructure roll-out costs continue to
limit the number of competitors in this sector of the telecommunications
market:
Neighborhood Cable as a publicly listed private company has
invested private funds to build something for the community for the long term.
Yesterday we launched a network in Geelong.
There is $17 million in Geelong.
What was the last investment in Geelong
of $17 million? What was the last investment in Ballarat of $15 million or $16
million to put in infrastructure for the community?[144]
3.51
Additionally, the lengthy delays to recoup these costs
prevent infrastructure investment:
The problem was that after 1997 the industry made some bad
decisions. The industry went a bridge too far in terms of its build. It built
more capacity in the broadband space than the market could take. Therefore, the
capital markets now are not seeing a return on the assets that have been
invested. They will not return any true value probably for five to 10 years. We
are talking about the big broadband builds that were built that are not going
to give any return.[145]
3.52
The Competitive Carriers Coalition told the Committee
that:
I would simply suggest that the people at this table represent
investment in telecommunications infrastructure in this country in the order of
about $4 billion. I think Primus is proudly EBITDA positive. Nobody else
at this table has seen any return on their investment.[146]
3.53
Similarly, Optus contended:
Infrastructure investment is high cost and high risk. This is
particularly the case in the residential and SME market. A bold move, such as
that taken by Optus with its HFC network means large amounts can be spent and
take a long time to earn a return. When faced with a strong and powerful
incumbent, these risks are even higher.[147]
3.54
It has been argued that Telstra will not develop any
new CAN infrastructure before the end of this decade.[148] And a
number of submitters claimed that Telstra will not invest in new technology
which will erode income from or cannibalise their existing infrastructure
revenue. Mr Christopher
Eckermann from TransACT Communications said:
If you are dominant in that revenue and with minimal expenditure
you can capture the low end of the data market with ADSL, there is very little
incentive to spend a lot of money refurbishing your network. You risk
cannibalising existing products.[149]
3.55
Additionally, the Committee was told that Telstra uses
its powerful market position to limit infrastructure investment by its
competitors,[150]
and, that it uses its monopoly status to restrict the development of
alternative infrastructure and future technologies which would challenge its
market position:
Telstra has most effectively leveraged its incumbency and market
power to deter investments in alternatives to the existing copper access
network. Telstras success in equating DSL with broadband is important in that
it delays the emergence of market demand and investor support for alternative
access technologies that are truly future-proof.[151]
3.56
Similarly the Committee heard:
Telstra has a large influence in the progress (or lack thereof)
of this process by virtue of being the gatekeepers/owners of the copper loop
network, and arguably can slow the process down until or unless they themselves
have commercial plans to deploy the more advanced technology, as otherwise they
have no incentive to assist in introducing any changes.[152]
3.57
The Committee is concerned that there are limited
incentives for Telstra to invest in new technologies and that current Commonwealth
programs, such as HiBIS (as discussed in Chapter 1) continue to support Telstra's
position of limited investment and the roll out of old technology. Mr
Paul Budde
told the Committee:
countries around the world are now implementing, on a
commercial basis, fibre to the home. In my discussions with Telstra, Telstra
have clearly indicated that fibre to the home is not on their agenda; they do
not see a need for that. They believe that the copper cable network can be
upgraded and will be sufficient for a long time into the future. If that is the
case, are those 30 or 40 countries absolutely stupid? I dont think so.[153]
3.58
While a number of submitters argued the need for
increased infrastructure investment and build as a means of increasing
broadband competition, the Committee believes that Australia's
vast size and low population density does not support a business case for
multiple national infrastructure builds:
We do not have the population density to support lots of people
rolling out infrastructure. I think the national challenge is to get the whole
nation equipped with one good set of infrastructure. If you think about the pay
TV roll-outs, there are 2.7 million homes passed but 2.2 million of those homes
are passed by two companies offering very little differentiation in terms of
technical capability. If, instead of 2.7 million homes passed with a high level
of overlap, you put those figures end to end and we had Optuss 2.2 million and
Telstras 2.5 million, we would have 4.7 million homes passed and in a much
better position than they are today.[154]
Access to infrastructure
3.59
Telstra's copper network (the local loop) is the only
ubiquitous telecommunications network reaching the majority of Australians and
all ISPs and carriers are dependent on Telstra. The Communications Expert Group
told the Committee that:
There is limited competition in the Broadband market because all
ISPs and carriers are dependent on either Telstra wholesale broadband carrier
products, or the purchase of Telstra backhaul capacity from points of
aggregation.[155]
3.60
Telstra is the owner of bottleneck infrastructure and affects
operators both upstream and downstream of its infrastructure. It is widely
recognised that this vertical integration is a key impediment to competition in
broadband services. Despite the declaration of the local loop and attempts by
the ACCC at regulation, Telstra maintains control over access to its network by
competitors. The ACCC has argued that progress in achieving effective
competition in telecommunications has slowed and the regulatory regime directed
largely at the incumbent has failed to deliver the level of competition
originally envisaged. Comindico submitted that:
Telstra presently is in a position to control and determine
sectoral outcomes and overall industry structure to a greater degree than in
most advanced economies. This leads to systemic market distortions in the
Australian telecommunications sector. Telstra is the owner of bottleneck
infrastructure and acts both a supplier of retail and wholesale services
utilising this infrastructure. Regulation seeks to employ purely behavioural
remedies to force Telstra not to use this power to its advantage against direct
competitors. Put simply, regulatory mechanisms to create competition rely
almost exclusively on creating an obligation for one company (Telstra) to sell
services it does not wish to sell.[156]
3.61
Similarly, Primus told the Committee that:
Telstras control over bottleneck
facilities continues to frustrate Primus ability to deliver broadband services
to its customers.[157]
3.62
Resellers without infrastructure are at the mercy of
Telstra, which is in a position to use its monopoly over the infrastructure
that carries services (backhaul) and of the infrastructure that delivers
services to individual users (last-mile services) to 'tighten the collar' on
regional competition, thus making network expansion difficult.[158] Mr Ian
Slattery from Primus told the Committee that:
Primuss contention is that competition is far from effective in
this area. That is largely due to Telstras control over the network which all
competing carriers require access to in order to supply broadband based
services and drive the take-up and penetration of broadband services in this
country.[159]
3.63
However, not all submitters were critical of Telstra's
behaviour in regard to network access. Mr
Charles Reed
from Personal Broadband Australia told the Committee that:
I would like to add that we are purchasing some transmission
from Telstra, and in fact they have been terribly constructive to date. They
have been very professional about their relationship with us and they have
worked very closely with us.[160]
3.64
The ACCC is sensitive to the fact that new entrants are
unlikely to enter the market without first purchasing access services from the
incumbent and gaining a customer base. Commissioner Ed
Willett in a recent paper on challenges in
telecommunication competition and regulation said:
The key challenge for a regulator, therefore, is to develop a
framework that provides incentives for competitors to seek access to a fuller
set of services over the shorter term while also providing incentives for these
competitors to build their own infrastructure and rely less on the incumbent
over the longer term.[161]
Access to information
3.65
Information asymmetry is argued to be a barrier to
broadband competition as without appropriate geospatial information the
telecommunications industry is unable to plan, analyse and invest in broadband
infrastructure. The Committee was advised that:
Telstras role in the provision of information to a successful
broadband industry is critical and well understood. However, subtle differences
in what Telstra chooses to provide industry can hinder its competitors, and
therefore, the development of a broadband-empowered Australia.
Nowhere are these subtleties more apparent than in the different
approaches between the provision of DSL-enabled telephone prefix lists and the
provision of exchange boundaries in digital map form.
The impact to industry of not having ready access to
comprehensive exchange/ RIM boundary information includes the following:
-
uncertainties about market size (inc
DSL deprived) in particular areas;
-
reduced opportunity to employ
precision-based tools such as Addressed-based DSL prequalification. Such tools
have the ability to improve provisioning yields and reduce ordering frustration
amongst customers;
-
delayed resource allocation decisions
(infrastructure planning, marketing, provisioning) by competitive providers;
and
-
frustration amongst State government
bodies who have strategies to facilitate competition and reduce entry barriers.
These bodies may have negotiated exchange boundaries for their own planning
purposes typically over lengthy timeframes. However, they cant necessarily
promise that Telstra would provide competitive providers with the exchange/RIM
boundary information critical to a successful commercial implementation.[162]
3.66
Members of the Committee were informed that Telstra has
four geospatial data sets, of which DCITA has access to two. Telstra's
reluctance to make publicly available information which may be perceived as commercial
in confidence significantly impinges on Telstra's competitors being able to
offer a service or plan the deployment of infrastructure. Comindico told the
Committee:
The problem of information asymmetry where Telstra holds far
more information about network conditions and costs, customer profiles, and
competitors product designs, than those it is competing against undermines
confidence further and makes risk profiles of new ventures almost impossible to
quantify.[163]
3.67
During estimates hearing questioning on 24 May 2004, Telstra told the
Environment, Communications, Information Technology and the Arts Legislation
Committee that it does not charge its competitors for technical information
about the copper network for the purpose of accessing HiBIS subsidies to
install ADSL or DSLAMs in exchanges. Mr Bill
Scales, the Managing Director of Regulatory,
Corporate and Human Relations said:
We do not sell that information.They would talk to our
wholesale division and they would provide.[164]
3.68
Despite these claims the Committee has taken evidence
which is critical of Telstra withholding or selling, at high prices, geospatial
information on its copper network. ATUG argued:
ATUG understands from industry that Telstra has elected to
charge entities a fee between four and five digits, depending on the
combination of geospatial datasets required. In ATUG's view this sizable fee
further hinders the development of broadband, particularly for niche regional
players who cannot justify these sums.[165]
3.69
Similarly, PowerTel made a submission to the Committee
in regard to Telstra's claims on information access raised at the estimates
hearing. It stressed the detrimental effect of restricted information access on
its ability to compete with Telstra in an effective manner, as was Telstra's
intention to charge competitors for information access. PowerTel submitted that:
It has been PowerTel's experience that the obtaining of ESA
[Exchange Service Areas] information from Telstra has been a long and arduous
process. PowerTel has sought this information for a considerable period of time
from Telstra and found it excessively difficult to obtain. Notwithstanding
this, Telstra has recently provided PowerTel with ESA data however, in doing
so, Telstra required an acknowledgement from PowerTel that the provision of
future ESA data would be subject to new terms and conditions, including the
imposition of charges.[166]
Interconnection between wholesale and retail markets
3.70
The Committee has heard evidence which was critical of
Telstra's wholesale and retail pricing activities. A number of submissions
argued that the structural integration of Telstra is the primary point of
failure of telecommunications competition. As ACIL Tasman has argued:
The market power of the incumbent owner of the local loop is
significantly magnified if the owner, as in Telstra's case, is part of a
vertically integrated company that also operates downstream from it. Being an
essential facility owner and retailer at the one time places the vertically integrated
firm in a kind of conflict of interest. The extra power enjoyed by the
vertically integrated firm comes from its ability to monopolise areas of the
downstream market by providing its own subsidiary with local loop access on
favourable terms.[167]
3.71
Comindico told the Committee that Telstra uses its monopoly
control of infrastructure to deny wholesale services to competitors:
There have been many cases reported by wholesale acquirers of
Telstra ADSL connection services where the application by a customer for a
non-Telstra retail service has been refused on the grounds that Telstra
wholesale cannot provide the service over the copper line available to that
particular residence, only for that same customer offered an ADSL service by
Telstras BigPond retail arm.[168]
3.72
Additionally, companies who do not own their own
infrastructure are subject to Telstras interconnection charges. The Committee
heard that Telstra's wholesale prices are not sufficiently separated from
Telstra retail prices. Optus argued that:
Telstra does not provide competitors with a wholesale local
calling product (a local call resale service) at prices that permit effective
competition or that reflect costs Telstra avoids from not retailing local
services. Hence Telstras competitors, when adding their own retailing costs,
are required to loss-lead in the provision of local calling via resale if they
are to provide consumers with the one-stop shop or complete telephony service.
This has decreased effective competition in both local and long-distance
calling as well as the Internet services market. If competitors are to match
Telstra's retail price, they have little room if any to add in their retail and
customer acquisition costs. This price squeeze which erodes access seekers'
margins, is promoted by regulation and maximised by Telstra's regulatory gaming
behaviour. The end result is that it constrains competition and harms end
users. Resale competition is a vital stepping-stone to infrastructure
competition.[169]
3.73
Since regulatory intervention in late 2001, retail
competition in ADSL has grown with over 200 residential broadband ISPs. The
Committee heard that Bigpond Broadband (including ADSL, Cable
and Satellite) retail grew by 12% (or 26K) to 240K end customers.[170] However, while
the Committee is encouraged by the growth in broadband ISPs, evidence to the
inquiry suggests that Telstra as both the supplier of wholesale and retail
services uses this position to 'provide it with a seemingly impassable
advantage over competitors'.[171] Bond
Wireless argued:
There seems to be a lack of a Chinese Wall between Telstra's
wholesale and retail business as we have potential customers that have
requested ADSL access for a very long time but upon learning of our solution,
Telstra Countrywide suddenly is able to provide MiniMux solutions.[172]
3.74
In mid February 2004 the media reported that Telstra lowered
the cost of its ADSL broadband services by $10 to $29.95 per month for 200Mb of
data. It also offered unlimited access for $59.95 per month, which was $20 less
that the then equivalent Optus service.[173] It was
argued that this pricing policy was to undermine long-term competition in the
broadband market.
3.75
Telstra's cutting of retail broadband prices was of
major concern to its competitors. The Committee was told that the cost of
buying bandwidth from Telstra at wholesale had become higher that the retail
price and this price was below the wholesale price being charged for its tails
in non-metropolitan regions, and was an unsustainably small margin below its
metropolitan wholesale price.[174] A detailed
case study of this episode is included at page 73 of this chapter.
3.76
The Townsville City Council told the Committee that:
Predatory pricing can be anti-competitive if it leads to a
vertical price squeeze. In this case, a carrier with significant market power
or dominance sets prices below a particular measure of cost, thereby
sacrificing short-term profits, with the effect of lessening competition by
squeezing out equally efficient competitors and/or deterring future market
entry.[175]
3.77
Some broadband wholesalers felt that Telstra's
entry-level plan was not uncompetitive - because of the low data limit set - but
voiced concerns about Telstra's higher-priced unlimited plan.[176] However, the
Committee believes that Telstra's current broadband prices, while appearing positive
for the consumer, are anti-competitive in the long-term. By pricing wholesale
only marginally below the retail price it is uneconomic and unprofitable for many
ISPs to compete. Mr Ian Slattery from Primus
said:
Primus believes it will potentially send smaller ISPs to the
wall. That is to put it in simple terms. In a bizarre sort of way, there might
be an upside for carriers like Primus whereby we can then acquire them, but I
do not think that is necessarily the ideal outcome. It is just a possible
outcome. But as I said before, a substantial percentage of Primuss dial-up
customer base is at threat here. Bear in mind that the $29.95 plan will lock in
customers for 12 months. They will have a Telstra modem. They will then more
than likely realise they are exceeding the 200 meg
download limit and Telstra will quite happily push them up the price scale.[177]
Accounting separation
3.78
The 2002 Telecommunications
Competition Act made a number of amendments to the Trade Practices Act 1974 to enable the ACCC to exercise its record
keeping rule (RKP). Under these powers carriers can be required to keep records
and supply reports to the ACCC and for those reports to be published.
3.79
In June 2003 the Minister issued a direction to the
ACCC requiring it to implement an enhanced form of accounting separation intended
to address competition concerns arising from the level of vertical integration
of Telstra's wholesale and retail services. The Act requires accounting
separation of Telstra's wholesale and retail operations, with Telstra to prepare
current cost accounts to provide transparency to the ACCC about Telstras
ongoing and substantial wholesale and retail costs, and that Telstra publish financial
statements in respect of core interconnection services.[178]
3.80
Telstra summarises accounting separation as follows:
The Government requires Telstra to make information available
showing whether Telstra (i) prices competitor access to its network fairly;
(ii) sets its retail and wholesale prices at levels sufficient for competitors
to generate satisfactory returns and (iii) does not favour its retail customers
compared to its wholesale end-users.
The information can be classified into three limbs:
Limb 1 is the requirement for Telstra to update its regulatory
accounting records from historic to current costs being the costs that would
be incurred if the network were to be built using todays up to date technology;
Limb 2 requires that Telstra provide data to the ACCC to show
the margins available between Telstras average retail prices for access/local,
STD, IDD and fixed to mobile services and the costs that a competitor would
incur in supplying these services if it were relying solely on Telstras
wholesale products for network inputs. The average available margin across the
full set of these retail services (the margin of relevance to full service
carriers) is also published; and
Limb 3 requires Telstra to publish a series of measurements that
compare its performance in terms of new service connections and fault rectification
for both wholesale and retail customers.[179]
3.81
The ACCC received its first reports under the three
RKPs in November 2003 and these were released publicly by the ACCC in December
2003. To a Question on Notice to the Senate Economics Legislation Committee the
Regulator Affairs Division at the ACCC stated that:
On the basis of the first set of reports the ACCC did not
identify any specific areas of concern pertaining to Telstra's treatment of its
competitors in using its access services. However the ACCC noted that it was
hard to draw firm conclusions from a single set of reports that were based on
limited data, and further reports could produce different results. The highly
aggregated nature of the reports could also serve to mask specific instances of
conduct that may require investigation.[180]
3.82
While there is community and industry support for the
introduction of accounting separation of Telstras wholesale and retail[181], concerns
over Telstra's ability to manipulate the reporting process were expressed to the
Committee:
Without going into too much detail about the accounting
separation, I am sure Telstra will come out with a lot of imputation test
information to support the $29.95 pricing. They will say that, if you look at
the suite of broadband services, this pricing passes all the tests. One has to
question whether you can actually use the current accounting separation testing
regime to bring to them to task on these things. The first report that was run
and released earlier this year was, in my view, an example of the system being
manipulated in some fashion. The strict guidance of the process was not adhered
to, so one would have to question whether you can actually use that information
to benchmark the next report and how effective it is.[182]
3.83
The Committee is concerned that the model used for
imputation testing to assess whether Telstra is engaged in a margin squeeze is
unreliable, as the ACCC has used highly aggregated data which is unlikely to
reveal a vertical price squeeze.
Bundling
3.84
The Committee heard that Telstra's vertical integration
allows it to implement pricing strategies, such as the 'bundling' of different
services into a single offering.[183] Bundling allows
discounts to be offered to buyers who acquire numerous services from one
supplier. The strategy brings a number of customer benefits:
Bundling can generate a range of benefits in terms of
efficiencies and pro-competitive outcomes. Economies of scope and scale may be
achieved through bundling; and consumers may experience retail price reductions
and service improvements.[184]
3.85
Similarly, TransACT told the Committee:
Communications technology convergence has prompted
Telecommunications providers to offer bundled services. Bundling has the
capacity to increase efficiencies and to encourage take up through the
provision of consumer benefits such as lower prices and single bills. For
example, ACTEW is now offering bundled services including ISP services. Bundling also offers the potential for
smaller Telecommunications providers to form partnerships to offer cheaper
services at a price that is competitive with established Telecommunications
providers.[185]
3.86
Telecommunications operators benefit from bundling
voice, video, and data services into a single offering by increasing average
revenue per customer, reducing potential customer churn and attracting new
customers by their range of services. Telstra's ownership of a wider range of
businesses and services than any of its competitors allows it to offer unique bundles
from their own resources. Telstra's competitors argue that some aspects of
bundling are anti-competitive:
On the other hand bundling may have anti-competitive effects.
Potentially bundling will make it more difficult for new and developing
companies to break into the market as larger telecommunications providers, with
the capacity to offer greater discounts, dominate the market.[186]
3.87
Evidence to this inquiry suggests that by bundling
services Telstra is able to offer customers retail prices which are below the
wholesale price charged to competitors:
There are situations that appear unjustifiable, such as where
elements of bundles are offered to retail customers at prices lower than the
wholesale price for which competitors can acquire the same services from
Telstra. Comindico understands anecdotally that there are corporate customers
who pay less for fixed to mobile calls than the wholesale price other fixed
networks pay Telstra to terminate a call from their network to a Telstra mobile
phone user.[187]
3.88
Similarly, the Competitive Carriers Coalition told the Committee:
It impacts on the business. I will mention one example of that
to you. Bundling is the underlying methodology of delivering it.
Fixed-to-mobile call prices are a very good example. a recent initiative which
allows a 50 per cent discount on a Telstra fixed line to a Telstra mobile
service on call prices. That discount is not available anywhere else. No
equivalent can be delivered. There is a terminating access wholesale price
arrangement on mobile networks which, given that kind of discount off retail,
would leave absolutely no margin to compete with. You could not possibly
compete with that in offering a service in the retail market, as our colleagues
are trying to do.[188]
3.89
Neighborhood Cable told the Committee:
Neighborhood Cable objected to Telstras notification to the
ACCC of its third-line forcing conduct over the bundling of Austars pay-TV
product with Telstras telecommunications services on the basis that this
amounted to anti-competitive conduct. As Telstra pay TV would be simply
reselling the standard Austar offering, the public would not benefit from any
of the classic results of true competition.[189]
3.90
The Committee heard that package deals involving the
bundling of products are an attempt by Telstra to circumvent price regulations.[190] It is concerned
that bundling may be detrimental to competition in the longer term by enabling
the leveraging of market power from one market to another to foreclose or discourage
competition.
To be clear, I guess any carrier can match it. The point is for
how long do you want to take a loss?[191]
3.91
Additionally, the Committee heard assertions that the
bundling of Foxtel with Telstra's broadband services was an inhibitor of market
competition. Dr Walter
Green, the Director of Communications Expert
Group, told the Committee:
There is no doubt that the bundling of Foxtel with Internet and
telephone services, where significant reductions are offered on Foxtel, is
proving an inhibitor to competition, simply because the other carriers and
Internet service providers do not have the same access to Foxtel that Telstra
has.[192]
3.92
Telstra's ability to bundle services was argued to restrict
Telstra's competitors from achieving adequate returns on their infrastructure
investments. Mr Fred
Grossman argued:
I think it is public knowledge that we at Neighborhood Cable
opposed an issue that we thought was third-line forcing where Telstra applied
to the ACCC to allow itself to bundle the Austar pay TV product and rebrand. We
claimed in that submission that that was doing absolutely nothing for competition,
in fact stifling competition. The ACCC in its wisdom saw fit to allow Telstra
to bundle. We believe that adds absolutely no value. It is the same product to
the same customers, just a little bit branded build, stifling our competition.
Why does that bother us? It bothers usgoing back to the opening
statementbecause we have invested $60 million of private funds to build a true
broadband network for 250,000 local loop customers. We need to make a
commercial payback on that, as did railways and anybody else who did it a
century ago.[193]
3.93
The Committee appreciates that consumers find it easier
to receive bundled services with a single bill.[194] However,
the Committee is concerned that few competitors of Telstra can offer a similar
service:
Telstras ability to bundle wholesale access elements with a
full suite of services and content, including Foxtel Pay TV and mobile voice
services, is the most obvious manifestation of its ability to use its
structural integration to curtail inroads into its market share by competitors.
This is particularly evident in corporate and residential broadband markets.[195]
Peering and backhaul costs
3.94
The Department of Communications, Information
Technology, and the Arts defines 'peering' as the exchange of traffic between
two internet service providers (ISPs) on a settlement-free basis. In Australia
there are currently four companies peered and accepted as Tier 1 providers for
Internet backbone. These are Telstra
Bigpond, Telecom NZ/AAPT, Ozemail/Worldcom,
and OptusNet. Optus told the Committee:
The arrangements that we have for peering are effectively a more
efficient version of the alternative approach, which would be paying the
counterparty for data we download from their network and them paying us for
data they download from our network.
Our approach has been consistent in that we have a set of
objective criteria as to who we will enter into a peering arrangement with,
which are based essentially on traffic volumes. The underlying economic factors
that they relate to are the amount of investment that we need to be put into a
network to have points of presence that are widely distributed and a capacity
to physically carry and receive traffic. There is no particular magic about who
it is that we peer withit is just whoever has a volume of traffic that is
broadly equivalent to the volume that we have.[196]
3.95
All other carriers and ISPs rely on these Tier 1
providers for transit arrangements. Non Tier 1 providers were critical of the
current peering arrangements. Neighborhood Cable told the Committee that:
Because of Telstras position in the marketplace and its peering
arrangements it does not have the same backhaul costings or data costings that
we do. Therefore, how does a competitor compete with an unlimited product when
it is not able to purchase something that is unlimited?[197]
3.96
The Townville City Council submitted that:
Council is concerned that existing peering arrangements that
operate between the nations top 4 Internet Service Providers are creating
cost disadvantages for small regional providers. Such a situation has potential
anticompetitive consequences and could either squeeze otherwise efficient
competitors out of the market or deter future market entry.[198]
3.97
The Committee heard that Internet peering is an important
factor in the cost of domestic bandwidth and that the lack of affordable
peering arrangements makes international bandwidth cheaper than domestic
bandwidth for smaller ISPs:[199]
Again, I will make it very simple: we need to connect our
networks back to the Internet world and, in most cases, to use the backhaul
capacity and the peering. To remain competitive you have to look at what
pricing is out in the marketplace and how you price into that, and you have to
be able to buy for less than you need to sell for. We find that difficult in
certain circumstances. There is not a large capacity to negotiate.[200]
3.98
The costs associated with international peering
arrangements was raised by ATUG's Ms Rosemary
Sinclair:
The way we see it is that the current situation creates a
negative impact for Australian users. The cost to Australian providers of
getting traffic to and from the US
is more expensive because the Internet peering arrangements do not apply to
them. The reason people say that we have to charge users for downloads and that
we have to have download caps and that prices have to be download limit related
is that that is the way we buy the service. Within tier 1 carriers
internationally, they swap traffic without these kinds of imposts and charges.
We see an opportunity for this matter to be raised between Australia
and the USwhich
is the main focus of our concernas part of the free trade agreement. If we are
interested in economic growth and international cooperation, and in the
knowledge society and the information economy that we all talk about then
cost-oriented access is an important fundamental tool.[201]
3.99
Dr Paul Brooks when on to
argue that:
Few people know that Telstra is part of that club of tier 1
peering carriers. By virtue of putting its equipment over in the US,
it peers - with no data charges and no interconnect charges - with the United
States and the international Internet
backbone operators. But Telstras argument is that it has to pay for the
international circuit that links Australia
to the US, to
carry that traffic on. Part of that was built with shared funds from the
American carriers, in terms of building the physical fibre infrastructure and
rolling out the cable ships.
It is also not metered on a cents per megabyte rate. They
connect into the Internet, the traffic gets exchanged at no charge and the link
between Australia
and the US - even
though, essentially, the broadband service is paying itself for the
transmission carriage - is the same amount per month or per year, regardless.
That is true of other carriers which have capacity on the under-sea fibre
cables as well. By putting equipment in the US,
you can interconnect at no cost with all the other carriers and essentially
become part of that tier 1 peering club. Some carriers in Australia
are already part of that, but the recognition that they are no longer paying US
carriers for content has not filtered through into their pricing models or,
obviously, their arguments to various inquiries and commissions.[202]
3.100
Mr Maha
Krishnapillai from Macquarie Corporate
Telecommunications also commented that:
Domestic peering is the gang of four I referred to earlier:
Telstra, Optus, AAPT and OzEmail. They have a domestic peering arrangement that
was entered into under the auspices of the ACCC in 1998. This has exactly the
same impact on the Internet industry and, therefore, broadband in Australia,
whereby those four carriers are able to swap traffic at no cost and either
maintain a higher profit margin or gain a higher market share.[203]
3.101
The Committee heard that backhaul costs are charged on a
distance basis and therefore rural customers are financially disadvantaged. Mr
Jonathan Withers
from Personal Broadband Australia noted that government policy was focused
largely on supporting infrastructure roll-out in regional and rural areas with
little regard for the cost of back-hauling traffic in these rural areas:
The thing that generally degrades the business case, if you
like, for these rural areas, is the cost of back hauling the traffic. While a
lot of previous government policy has put money into the capital requirements
of putting infrastructure into rural areas that does not address what we call
the ongoing opex requirements of supporting that. One of the things we note is
that the Internet is the first telecommunications space which has absolutely no
distance based charging; you can access a site here in Sydney,
over in the US
or in the UK
for exactly the same priceit is a characteristic of the Internet. What works
against you in terms of wide-area deployment is that at the moment the back
haul costs are not following the same model, so it is considerably more
expensive to provide access in rural areas.[204]
3.102
The issue of backhaul costs is complex and significant,
as even modest bandwidths of two megabits per second for some rural locations
can cost in the order of $100,000 per year.[205]
Universal Service Obligation
3.103
The Universal Service Obligation (USO) ensures that
under the Telecommunications (Consumer
Protection and Service Standards) Act 1999 standard telephone services,
payphones and prescribed carriage services are reasonably accessible to all
Australians on an equitable basis, wherever they reside or carry on business.
Telstra is currently the only designated Universal Service Provider and this has
been identified as an impediment to broadband competition. Under the USO other
carriers cross-subsidise Telstra by in excess of $50 million per annum to
provide services in non-metropolitan Australia.
The Committee has been told that, where capital is already limited, the USO is
another major impediment to smaller companies investing in infrastructure.[206]
Smaller carriers operate on low profit margins, and the USO [that
is based on income or revenue] significantly reduces their available capital
for investment in broadband infrastructure.
There is one case where a carrier gave up its licence because of the
impact of the USO, and withdrew from providing broadband services in areas not
serviced by Telstra. ISPs are further penalised by the USO, as their USO
contribution is based on their total Internet and Telecommunication revenue.
There appears to be an emerging market for small carriers servicing ISP needs.[207]
3.104
Submitters were critical of the USO, and the policy position
which supported it, as it did not encourage infrastructure investment. Dr
Michael Bourk
from the Small Enterprise Telecommunications Centre argued:
We lament the reduction in competitionand, in particular,
facilities competition, which is really the engine, if you like, of competition
in the long term. We regret that. We think that, to a degree, that is a problem
with policy. Had the USO perhaps been able to naturally evolve as the network
was evolving and as we moved to an ISDN network, we would not be facing a lot
of these issues, because the bootstrap would have already naturally occurred.
Then you already have an increased, advanced take-up, if you like, of broadband
already occurring and making provision for the competitors. So we see that as a
policy problem.[208]
3.105
A number of submitters argued that the USO had reduced
the growth in broadband infrastructure and consequently reduced the competitive
pressures on Telstra. Optus submitted that the current USO funding arrangement
that requires competitive carriers to fund the provision of Telstras service
in rural and regional Australia
has a number of negative consequences for the promotion of competition:
-
in an environment where competitive
carriers are struggling to make inroads against the continuing massive
dominance of the incumbent, the USO regime actually requires competitive
carriers to cross-subsidise Telstras activities, and thus strengthen Telstras
position;
-
that the USO contribution acts as a
significant disincentive for competitive carriers to provide their own regional
and rural services. When a carrier is forced to pay another party to deliver
standard services, there is no incentive to itself provide standard services,
and a much more limited incentive to provide any additional services;
-
that the contribution of other carriers
to Telstra bolsters the significant value Telstra obtains from being the
national carrier, and providing an ubiquitous service. These benefits are not
considered when the USO is valued. Therefore, other carriers are paying Telstra
to entrench its rural and regional dominance. Telstra makes much of its Australia-wide
presence in its marketing yet that presence in much of Australia is
substantially cross-subsidised by Optus and other carriers; and
-
that there is no understanding amongst
rural and regional consumers of the USO regime, and that the industry as a
whole contributes to the provision of their standard telecommunications
services. This creates a perception amongst regional and rural consumers
cementing their loyalty to the incumbent, and making change less likely.[209]
3.106
Submitters to the inquiry argued that the USO could be
modified in line with National Communications Fund or Networking the Nation
type funding rather than being paid directly to Telstra. Carriers who are then
interested in rolling out services to regional areas could access this funding
on a dollar for dollar basis.[210]
3.107
The Minister for Communications, Information Technology,
and the Arts released the Review of the Universal Service Obligation and
Customer Service Guarantee in June 2004. The review analysed the current
arrangements for costing and funding of the USO and whether network extension
and trenching costs are impeding access to USO services. The findings of this
review are discussed in the Committee's recent report on the Australian
telecommunications network.
Walled Garden
3.108
It has been argued that Telstra's large retail customer
base and network infrastructure has allowed the organisation to develop a
pricing regime which keeps customers tied to the Telstra network. Described as
a 'walled garden' or 'castle', end users are charged for data they download
above a monthly minimum. Telstra uses its telecommunications network to
establish itself as a content aggregator, and Telstra retail broadband
customers accessing data from a Telstra website receive an exemption from their
download limit for that data. Describing the strategy last year, an article in The Australian reported that:
It involves Telstras power as the owner of the bulk of Australias
telecommunications infrastructure and its ability to charge you more if you
shop and surf anywhere else on the Internet other than a site of Telstras
choosing. Simply, Telstra is trying to herd the customer into its cyber castle
Telstra will lure them then slam the drawbridge shut. If they travel outside
the castle a heavy toll will be exacted as download charges zoom.[211]
3.109
The Committee heard that individuals find this facility
useful. Mr Steve
Ireland told the Committee:
I actually take advantage of
Telstra's "Free Sites" in which they don't measure downloaded data.[212]
Regulation
3.110
Industry regulation plays a significant role in the
promotion or restriction of competition in the telecommunications sector (as
outlined in Chapter 2). The Committee heard that the Australian Government is
now reliant on the private sector as the primary driver for investment
decisions, innovation and competition practices.[213] This strong
reliance on the market has been seen as a key impediment to broadband growth:
SETEL contends that the slow rate of
uptake of broadband and e-commerce is primarily due to Policy failure. The
Commonwealth Government has generically promoted the importance of broadband
services and their usage to the community in general but has failed to
implement policies to ensure that all users have access to ubiquitous,
affordable broadband services.[214]
3.111
Neighborhood Cable was critical of the regulatory
framework under which they and other carriers were given access to existing
infrastructure:
Government also needs to review the
legislative framework under which infrastructure builders can access and secure
tenure on existing infrastructure. For example, a carrier is entirely dependant
on the utility whose infrastructure it must rent in order to construct a
network. There is generally only one utility company, which has the potential
to create a significant imbalance of bargaining power. This can result in the
unreasonable shifting of costs and liabilities and insecurity of tenure over
the long term.[215]
3.112
Within the current regulatory regime Telstra's
continued market dominance is seen as a deterrent to many investors. Witnesses
have told the Committee that they require a clearer indication from government on
the management of Telstra's anti-competitive behaviour before they will commit
to infrastructure investment:
Investors in the present market
circumstances are particularly shy of investing in the disruptive, higher
risk end of the technology spectrum. An important reason for this is that they
lack confidence in the competitive environment. The evidence of Telstras
ability to use its size and market power to curtail the entry of new
technologies is powerful. The view that a new entrant will not get a fair go
at leveraging its investment in new technologies is widespread, and supported
by the ACCCs own analysis.[216]
3.113
Similarly, the Competitive Carriers Coalition told the
Committee that:
I think any suggestion that in this
environment anybody else would come in to put billions of dollars on the table
to invest in another network, particularly in the light of the events we have
seen in the last few weeks, is optimistic in the extreme. I think these events,
as much as anything we have seen in the last two years, says very clearly to
investors: You would be insane to think that you can put money on the table
and get a reasonable return on your investment. You are going to lose a lot of
money for a long time.[217]
3.114
The Committee heard evidence which was critical of the
current light touch regulatory regime, under which it is claimed Telstra acts
with impunity. SETEL claimed:
The application of 'light touch'
regulation has resulted in the dominant carrier, Telstra, being able to
increase prices of services to consumers with what appears to be a high degree
of impunity.[218]
3.115
Similarly, the Competitive Carriers Coalition argued:
From our observation, this means the
regime itself is too weak, the administration of the regime is too weak or it
is a combination of both of them. Ultimately, though, it shows that Telstra is
unmanageable because it is structurally predisposed to manipulating wholesale
and retail market power in ways to disadvantage other participants in the
market.[219]
3.116
Additionally, submitters commented on the high cost of
an inefficient regulatory system. Mr Ian Slattery of Primus told the Committee:
The ACCC believes the current
regulatory regime is ineffective. Its view is that the recent accounting
separation legislation and the current access arrangements are unlikely to
improve that. It also is of the view that, as opposed to what was intended in
the 1997 Trade Practices Act amendments - when telecommunications was opened up
to full competition - we now have more regulation and increased costs on the
industry instead of less.[220]
3.117
The Committee heard from a number of witnesses about
the ineffectiveness of the current regulatory regime and cited the recent
Telstra/ACCC dispute over Telstra's lowering of ADSL retail prices to below
wholesale prices as an example of this. The Case Study below outlines the
situation.
CASE STUDY: The effectiveness of the regulatory
system
On 15 February 2004, Telstra
Bigpond announced it would offer an ADSL
256Kbps retail service for $29.95 per month. This price was claimed to be lower
than the wholesale price which Telstra was offering to some of its competitors.
Telstra defended its action by claiming that the reduction in price was to stimulate
the retail broadband market - which had been declining - and competition more
generally. In response to Telstra's new ADSL retail prices, Optus and a number
of smaller ISPs announced cuts to their broadband plans to bring them into line
with Telstra. However, smaller operators claimed that these prices were
unsustainable and Telstra's 'pricing squeeze' was an attempt to manipulate the
market.
In a submission to the
Committee on 27 February, the Competitive Carriers Coalition wrote that:
The CCC members
believe that these price changes represent a wilful and calculated attack on the integrity of the wholesale ADSL
market. It is
clear that Telstra is
engaged in manipulating the development of the
ADSL market by forcing
too-high wholesale prices on independent service providers and by favouring its own retail arm to the
detriment of other providers.[221]
Telstra's competitors
went to the ACCC claiming that Telstra was engaged in anti-competitive
behaviour. On 6 March the ACCC issued Telstra with a consultation notice. On 9
March the consultation notice was extended by two days when Telstra requested
more time to respond to the case of anti-competitive behaviour asserted by the
ACCC.
In line with requests
from the ACCC to reduce its wholesale prices to levels which were competitive,
Telstra lowered its wholesale price.
However, as Mr
Simon Hackett,
the Managing Director of Internode, argued:
It's a
myth that $29.75 is the wholesale access price
compared to the
Telstra $29.95 retail price. The $29.75
charge is EX GST.
When you remove the GST from $29.95, it
becomes $27.23
or $2.52 BELOW the tail circuit charge. Also, that tail circuit charge is only one component of the full cost
to mount a working ADSL service. When
you add the other necessary costs
in, you are up at
more like $35 as a minimum underlying cost.[222]
On 19 March the ACCC
issued a Part A Competition Notice to Telstra in relation to the pricing of
Telstra's broadband internet services. The ACCC noted that it had reason to
believe that Telstra had engaged and was engaging in at least one instant of
anti-competitive conduct and was using its substantial market power to lessen
and hinder competition.
Since
at least 15 February 2004:
a) Telstra has supplied, and
continues to supply, wholesale Broadband Services to its Wholesale Customers at
wholesale process set at a level whereby there was and is only a small positive
or negative difference between those wholesale prices and the Retail Prices;
and
b) Telstra has refused, and
continues to refuse, to supply wholesale Broadband Services to its Wholesale
Customers at prices other than wholesale prices set at a level whereby there
was and is only a small positive or negative difference between those wholesale
prices and the Retail Prices.[223]
The Part A Competition
Notice against Telstra opened the way for a Part B Competition Notice to be
issued with a possible fine of $10 million - rising by $1 million a day - and
legal action from Telstra's competitors.
On 23 March Telstra's strategy
was being commented on in the following terms:
At this stage it
appears Telstra's strategy is to defuse the
threat of the competition
notice by commercially agreeing on deals
on wholesale prices.
Presumably it believes the potential volume gains,
and the potential to migrate entry-level
customers to higher-capacity,
higher-margins plans, will
still offset the loss of wholesale margins.[224]
On 1 April Telstra
announced two new wholesale access packages aimed primarily at addressing the
ACCC's Competition Notice and the concerns of Telstra's wholesale customers.
Telstra offered its wholesale customers the following options:
'Protected Rates' Option.
This option provides
wholesale prices at a 40 per cent discount to retail access and connection prices across all plans. Wholesale prices will
be tied directly to BigPond's
pricing plans by taking BigPond's effective starting
retail prices and deducting a 40 per cent discount for retail costs and further deductions to cover
other wholesaling costs. This will suit customers
who want certainty over wholesale/retail pricing relativity.
'Growth' Option.
This package will assist
broadband ISPs to drive profitable growth across
the spectrum of retail pricing. It
will offer attractive price reductions for
higher speed plans, on the basis that sustainable industry outcomes can be achieved via migration of retail end-users
from lower value plans. It will suit
those ISPs who see the commercial opportunity to upgrade their customers to higher-speed plans; and
who want full flexibility over their retail
pricing options.[225]
It was reported that
Telstra's price reductions appeased the ACCC's current concerns with ACCC Chairman,
Mr Graeme
Samuel, stating that Telstra's new offer 'appears
to be a victory for commonsense'.[226] However,
while the ACCC was apparently satisfied with the outcome, many of Telstra's
competitors were critical, with a number of Telstra's largest wholesale
customers claiming that Telstra had not consulted with them on the new pricing
arrangements and that they had heard of the new pricing arrangements via the
media. Additionally, it was claimed that the options available to Telstra's
wholesale customers tied them into Telstra's retail structure. It was argued
that the 'Protected Rates' Option introduced a third variable cost for ISPs and
the 'Growth' Option had not dropped the cost of 256k port pricing despite the
fact that this was the area in which the current price squeeze existed.[227]
Commentators
noted that the new pricing structure was largely an attempt to deflect ACCC
intervention:
Telstra
appears to have attempted to move focus away from that by introducing bizarre wholesale offerings on
the side, which appear to
be ultimately unattractive to their customers.[228]
On
9 June it was reported that the Competition Notice was still alive and as of that
date Telstra had accumulated $91 million in possible fines. The Australian indicated a seeming hesitancy
from Mr Samuel
to act and Telstra's propensity to:
Fight
the case in court, but the fabulously paranoid telco never ever makes
it past the courthouse steps, preferring
always to let a large sack of shareholders'
cash do the talking.[229]
Reported
on 12 June, Mr Bruce
Akhurst, Telstra's group managing director
for wholesale defended Telstra's action as merely stimulating the market and
providing broadband at affordable prices. The discounting had led, over a five-month
period, to a 46% increase in broadband subscriptions. The action led Telstra to
forecast that it would sign up its millionth broadband customer by July 2004,
six months ahead of earlier forecasts.[230]
On
25 June, the ACCC warned that the Competition Notice still remained in force
and that a number of potential options were open to the Commission in relation
to the notice.[231]
On
19 July 2004 the ACCC
issued a further media release stating that it still had reason to believe that
Telstra was engaged in anti-competitive conduct of a kind described in the
Competition Notice. Consequently, the ACCC had decided to keep the notice in
force.[232]
This
situation prevailed at the time of the Committee's finalisation of this report.
3.118
The Committee heard a substantial amount of evidence
that claimed that the current regulatory framework which relies on sanctions by
the ACCC was largely ineffectual against Telstra's considerable market dominance.
The Competitive Carriers' Coalition argued that Telstra engaged in
anti-competitive behaviour with little concern for sanctions that the ACCC may
bring against it:
In other words, the ACCC has already used the most powerful and
direct weapon in its regulatory armoury for dealing with anti-competitive
activity in precisely this market. That Telstra has been willing to
deliberately pursue a course of action that would result in the spectre of the
same sanction being applied again shows that Telstra has no fear of competition
notices.[233]
3.119
The ACCC has recently argued there was not necessarily
a contradiction between access or service-based competition on the one hand and
facilities-based competition on the other. And there remained the need for a
combination of wholesale, access-based and facilities-based competition under
the current regulatory regime in recognition that full-based competition is not
viable in all areas and, for more remote areas, may not be viable for some time
to come. In seeking to obtain the right regulatory balance, Commissioner
Ed Willett
said:
The Commission has been cautious of regulating end-to-end
wholesale broadband services under the telecommunications access regime
contained in the Trade Practices Act.
We are mindful that doing so could result in long-term
regulatory dependence that may stifle or delay the move towards more
sustainable long-term competition. Rather, the Commission has relied on the
competition provisions of the Act to address anti-competitive concerns in wholesale
broadband markets as they have arisen. We will continue to monitor the effectiveness
of this approach in light of any future industry developments in this area and
cannot rule out the need for a more direct regulatory approach to this service.[234]
Conclusions
3.120
The Committee has identified a number of impediments to
the uptake of broadband services in this chapter. These include issues of
network capability, cost and customer knowledge. The Committee also examined the
current impediments to competition in broadband services. Significant amounts
of evidence suggest that Telstra's monopoly position and control over the
telecommunications infrastructure and its vertically integrated structure was a
point at which broadband competition broke down. It is apparent that in light
of the barriers to competition the current regulatory regime will need to be
reviewed. As Dr Michael
Bourk from SETEL told the Committee:
The problem remains the incredible incumbent strength of Telstra.
That really does need to be addressed. It is a complex issue; we make no bones
about that. But when you still have one carrier making over 90 per cent of the
profits in the entire industry that is an issue that needs to be addressed.[235]
3.121
The following chapter outlines a variety of proposals that
may address the issues raised in the evidence.