Chapter 3
The wholesale funding guarantee
The introduction of the wholesale funding guarantee
3.1
The wholesale funding guarantee is available on an issue by issue basis
for securities with a term of up to 60 months. The guarantee will apply for the
full term of the relevant security even after the scheme is closed to new
issuances and can be applied to existing as well as new securities.[1]
3.2
The facility is restricted to senior unsecured debt instruments in major
currencies, whether issued domestically or offshore. There is restricted
availability for issues by foreign bank branches in Australia. (These may be
eligible for coverage from similar schemes in their home countries.)
3.3
The Treasury Secretary described the measure as prompted by similar
actions by foreign governments:
...circumstances had reached a point in Australia—particularly
because of decisions that had been taken the week earlier by the United Kingdom
government and steps that we understood might have been under consideration
more broadly in Europe and also in the United States—where a failure to act in
a timely way in Australia could have had severe implications for the ability of
Australian financial institutions to access wholesale term funding in
international markets.[2]
3.4
APRA had a comparable perspective:
...there was a great danger that Australian banks, in
particular our strongly performing banks, would struggle in global funding
markets against the competition coming from banks that were subject to a
government guarantee from their governments. Major Australian institutions fund
themselves in part through these wholesale offshore markets, and they were
turning their back on Australian banks.[3]
3.5
The measures by overseas governments are described by the Reserve Bank:
...many governments moved to provide guarantees on wholesale
funding by financial institutions. These moves followed the action taken by the
Irish Government in late September 2008 to provide a guarantee on new and
existing debt for Irish-based financial institutions. This decision had a
cascading effect, as concerns arose about the ability of financial institutions
that did not have access to guarantee arrangements to continue to access
funding. In the weeks following the Irish announcement, governments in over a
dozen countries, including Australia, followed suit with wholesale funding
guarantee schemes...[4]
3.6
A minority of witnesses opposed Australia responding to these global
actions. Professor Swan is not convinced the Australian response is warranted
given overseas events:
Australian banks are perhaps the most concentrated and most
profitable in the world, and in the present climate where major global banks
have sustained huge losses...[foreign banks] are not in the position to be
effectively competing in markets like Australia...These banks are not in a
position to put Australian banks out of business by providing very cheap,
economic or low-cost loans to Australian businesses...[5]
Monitoring and disclosure
3.7
There will be ongoing monitoring of the operation of the guarantee by
the Council of Financial Regulators.[6]
3.8
The Government publishes on www.guaranteescheme.gov.au the details of
participating institutions and the liabilities that are covered. The Government
will provide six-monthly reports to the Parliament on the Guarantee Scheme’s
operations, including:
-
the extent of the liabilities covered by the guarantees;
-
whether any calls have been made under the guarantees for
payment; and
-
payments, if any, made by the Commonwealth under the
guarantees.[7]
Setting the premia for the guarantee
3.9
The setting of the premium has been described by the Reserve Bank, APRA
and Treasury:
In setting the premiums on the guarantee the Government
considered a range of factors, including international settings and the need to
ensure that the arrangements did not continue indefinitely. The fees were set
at a level between the then current risk spreads – the product of very stressed
conditions – and spreads likely to prevail in more normal market conditions.[8]
The Guarantee Scheme fee schedule is based on the credit
ratings of the issuing institutions and is set at levels between the prices of
ADIs’ wholesale debt instruments at the height of the financial turmoil and the
prices that had prevailed in more normal market conditions. This approach
provides an incentive for ADIs and their investors to cease using the Guarantee
Scheme as market conditions normalise, helps to mitigate any impacts of the
guarantee on the markets for other financial assets, and ensures that the fee
schedule reflects market-based pricing signals and the risks borne by
taxpayers.[9]
International comparison
3.10
Placing the Australian charges in a global context, the RBA described:
The fees charged for the government guarantees on wholesale funding
are typically based on the credit rating of the issuer (Australia, Canada and
New Zealand), or credit default swap premiums (France, the Netherlands, Spain
and the United Kingdom). In contrast, in the United States the fee charged is
dependent on the term of the instrument but not the rating of the issuer. The
fee structure adopted in the Netherlands and New Zealand also depends partly on
the term of issuance. In a number of countries, including Canada, New Zealand
and the United Kingdom, the fee has been revised lower from initial settings,
while in the United States it has been revised higher.[10]
3.11
Assessing the position after these changes, the RBA and APRA comment:
Internationally, fees on comparable schemes have converged at
around 90 to 110 points, above the 70 basis point charge for AA rated
Australian banks. The Australian fee structure also has a relatively large
differential between banks with different ratings.[11]
3.12
Treasury comment:
Australia’s wholesale funding guarantee fee schedule (which
also applies to large deposits) is currently at the lower end of the
international spectrum, but is broadly consistent with international
arrangements if the cost of swapping debt raised in foreign currencies into
Australian dollars is taken into account. These swap costs have been unusually
elevated due to the impact of the crisis. Australian ADIs, along with those in
New Zealand and the UK, are in the unusual position of issuing the majority of
their debt in foreign currencies, and hence incur higher funding costs relative
to their counterparts in the US, Europe and parts of Asia.[12]
3.13
The Australian fees are compared to those overseas in Charts 3.1 and
3.2.
Chart 3.1
Source: RBA & APRA, Submission
7, p 4.
Chart 3.2
Source: Reserve Bank of Australia
3.14
The Australian scheme uses a relatively simple fee structure. This may
have been a good thing. The BIS noted that in overseas countries 'the take-up
under government debt guarantee programmes was slower than expected as issuers
were deterred by the terms and the costs...the complexity of these guarantee
programmes and the varying treatment across jurisdictions deterred some
investors'.[13]
Tiering of the premia
3.15
The premia for the guarantee are tiered. ADIs with credit ratings of AAA
to AA- pay 70 basis points per annum; those with credit ratings of A+ to A- pay
100 basis points while others pay 150 basis points.
3.16
This tiering was criticised by some lenders, particularly the smaller ADIs:
This fee structure created an unlevel playing field for the
first time in the deposit space, as previously Australian retail deposits had
always been priced without regard for the credit rating of a financial
institution. It also sent a message to the public that ADI’s with lower credit
ratings are not as “safe” as those with higher credit ratings.[14]
Presumably all depositors and all ADIs are protected the same
way, and yet we have got a different risk differential premium applied to us
for deposits with us [mutuals].[15]
The Guarantee cost tiering should be more representative of
the market cost... A differential of 80 basis points between major bank costs
and ME Bank (70 basis point guarantee cost versus 150 basis points) would, in
time, force the Bank to increase the rates on its consumer products including
residential home loans.[16]
... premiums on the wholesale funding guarantee should narrow,
but there are differences of opinion amongst our banks on the extent of this
narrowing.[17]
3.17
It was also criticised by the Finance Sector Union and Professor Swan:
It is arguable that a differential pricing structure for the
deposit guarantee is not consistent with the accompanying prudential framework
which aims to give equal protection to all regulated deposits.[18]
With very big differences between the subsidy rate to more
highly rated banks and that to more lowly rated banks, it further biases the
banking system towards the larger banks. I think in the longer term, if this
continues, it will tend to further reduce competition in the Australian market.[19]
3.18
Treasury justified the tiering on the following grounds:
That fee schedule represents the recommendations of the
Council of Financial Regulators in terms of the need to maintain a risk
spectrum and to protect the Commonwealth in terms of the risks it was taking by
guaranteeing the fundraising by a wide range of institutions. We cannot escape
the fact that a BBB-rated institution will have to pay more for its funding
than an AA-rated institution.[20]
3.19
Professor Harper argued that not having the tiering would expose the
government to greater risk:
There is a risk spectrum in the financial system. The reality
is, I would have argued, that those on the margin, those further out, have a
higher probability of succumbing than those further in. That is why there is a
risk spectrum; that is why the market charges some of the non-banks and other
institutions and regional banks a higher rate than it charges the majors...[21]
3.20
Even if the magnitude of the tiering was initially appropriate, it has
been argued that it should now be reviewed:
...they should have been finetuning the level and the relative
rates for different classifications of banks over time. That would have meant,
with the lowering of risk premiums and the lowering of global rates, that they...
should have narrowed that differential...[22]
3.21
One argument against the tiering is that the smaller ADIs are still
having to pay more to raise funds, even when the government guarantee is in
place:
Operation of the Scheme has also revealed that lower rated
ADIs are in effect penalised twice, as the market has required an additional
premium from them on top of the higher fee payable to the Government even
though the debt carries the Government’s AAA rated guarantee.[23]
3.22
As well as the smaller ADIs affected, this 'double whammy' effect is
regarded as undesirable by Professor Sathye:
I would agree with a risk based sliding scale in normal
situations, but we were not dealing with a normal situation; it was an abnormal
situation, where we wanted banks to raise money in order to be able to fund
businesses and others. The sliding scale is actually acting something like a
double whammy for the smaller financial institutions.[24]
3.23
It appears this outcome was not anticipated – or at least not with any
confidence – when the scheme was being designed. The discussion with Treasury
at the hearing went as follows:
Senator BUSHBY—Was it the case that they thought by providing
the government guarantee that the market would then treat them equally and not
actually price differentially?
Mr Murphy—There were wide-ranging discussions about the fee
schedule and what the appropriate schedule was. It was a dramatic and quite
innovative approach which, as has been demonstrated, was necessary. At the time
we were trying to get to a position where all institutions would have access to
wholesale funding at an appropriate price...
Senator BUSHBY—...But if the Council of Financial Regulators
decided deliberately to put a differential on, knowing full well that the
market would still differentially price the cost of funds, then that is another
thing altogether. I would like an indication of whether there was a
consideration of that before the decision was made.
Mr Murphy—Those issues were discussed, but at the time no-one
really knew...
Senator BUSHBY—Was the assessment that they thought that the
market would price the risk in the same way given that there was Commonwealth
backing for all institutions?
Mr Murphy—There was some uncertainty about that. You could
look at it in two ways. What has eventuated is that the market, in effect,
looks through the government guarantee and makes its assessment.
Senator BUSHBY—Yes, and that is what has happened. But what I
am interested in is whether the decision they made initially was in the
expectation that the market would not look through the government guarantee.
Mr Murphy—From recollection, the matters were discussed, and
realistically we did not know.[25]
3.24
The Australian Bankers' Association commented:
...at the time of that announcement perhaps no-one could have
anticipated this looking-through issue.[26]
3.25
The reason why the market is apparently not heeding the guarantees is
unclear. The ABA has suggested:
One contributory reason for this is that the current design
of the guarantee does not give investors confidence that, in the event of
default, the government will make good on the guarantee within an acceptable
timeframe.[27]
3.26
It is also argued that basing the fees on credit ratings is inconsistent
with the performance of the ratings agencies. Abacus acidly notes:
Local councils trusted the opinions of credit rating agencies
rather than Australia’s prudential regulatory system and chose to invest in
AAA-rated exotic securities when they would have been better off depositing
funds in an unrated mutual ADI.[28]
3.27
The Bank of Queensland is also unimpressed by the rigour of the rating
agencies:
the regional banks in Australia are actually safer institutions
and the credit rating that they have is more a function of size than true risk.[29]
3.28
The ABA and Abacus argued that the differential between the fees for
large and small banks is wider in Australia than overseas.[30]
Comparing with overseas schemes, Treasury observes:
Most countries’ fee schedules differentiate between
institutions on the basis of risk, with more risky institutions paying a higher
fee. However, there are different approaches to calculating the fee
differential, with countries such as Australia, Canada and New Zealand using
credit ratings, while countries such as the UK, France and Germany are using
market-based benchmarks such as credit default swaps. The US, Ireland and Korea
charge the same fee regardless of the riskiness of the institution. Most
nations’ fee schedules charge a higher fee for longer-term issuance, whereas
Australia’s fee schedule does not differentiate between securities with
different term structures.[31]
3.29
An alternative suggestion is that as risk increases with the size of
exposure, so should the premium charged:
... for the first $50 billion you are only going to pay half of
a per cent; for the next $50 billion you are going to pay one per cent; for the
next $50 billion you are going to pay 1½ per cent; and for the next $50 billion
you will pay two per cent. It is all available to you but the call is yours as
to how much of the guarantee you want....This would both look after the smaller
banks and also give encouragement to the bigger banks to move out.[32]
3.30
The Bank of Queensland saw some merit in such a modification:
...the majors would lose the advantage of the large deposit
bases and the advertising capabilities et cetera that they have. I think that
would effectively level the playing field of the large and small banks.[33]
3.31
Professor Sathye said that as all ADIs are subject to the same
supervision by APRA they should be charged the same rate:
...all institutions are APRA regulated, so on that front they
are all equal, and if they are all equal, then why is there a discrimination on
the risk basis at a time when risk was pretty high?[34]
3.32
On the contrary, Professor Hogan has argued that the differential may be
too small:
From top to bottom the range is only 80 basis points. This is
much less than the spreads often witnessed in international capital markets
between the highly-rated and the lesser-rated...[35]
Committee view
3.33
While Treasury is coy about the extent to which the market was
anticipated to 'look through' the guarantees, the lack of clear explanations
for this behaviour suggest it was probably not expected. The Committee
therefore regards it as a reason to review the extent of tiering of the premia
to ensure that lower-rated ADIs are not 'paying twice'.
Recommendation 1
3.34
The Committee recommends that, in view of the experience of markets not
pricing all guaranteed debt identically, the Government review the need to
apply differential premia for ADIs with different ratings for the wholesale
funding guarantee (and hence also that applying to deposits over $1 million).
The contingent liability from the guarantees
3.35
Symptomatic of the confused approach of the Government in its response
to the financial crisis, initially it had been thought legislation would not be
required but in November 2008, the Guarantee Scheme for Large Deposits and
Wholesale Funding Appropriation Bill 2008 was passed through the parliament to
provide an appropriation in the unlikely event this is required.
3.36
In theory the contingent liability arising from the guarantees would be
the total size of deposits under $1 million and larger deposits and wholesale
funding for which the guarantee fee has been paid. This currently amounts to
around $770 billion. This liability would be realised if all the banking
system's assets became worthless.
3.37
However, Treasury explained that even in the remote possibility of a
bank collapsing the cost to the government would be much less than the size of
the bank's deposits:
...you then need to think through some other important
safeguards. One in particular I will mention is the fact that all ADIs are
required under the Banking Act to hold sufficient assets to cover their deposit
liabilities. So if, for example, there was a collapse of a bank and the
appropriate action was that the institution be wound up then while amounts
might be paid out under the Financial Claims Scheme upfront, because the whole
purpose of that is to ensure that depositors can get their money quickly, the
assets, as required under the Banking Act, will more than offset the deposit
liability. So if that was the course of action that was decided, APRA would
step in—and the institution would be wound up and over time the assets would be
extinguished. They would all come back to the government. In that situation I
would argue that the actual contingent liability if it eventuated, whilst it is
unquantifiable, if you had to try to quantify it, would be incredibly small...And
the other important feature announced by the government at the time was that if
there is a shortfall then the government of the day has the option to introduce
a levy on the rest of the industry to make up that difference.[36]
3.38
The Treasury Secretary commented:
...my present understanding is that we were likely to refer to
the contingent liability in the statement of risks in the budget, and in
talking about the contingent liability we would describe it as ‘a remote and
unquantifiable liability’. I would imagine that people who are responsible for
rating sovereign debt would take the same view.[37]
3.39
The Reserve Bank agreed:
..the circumstances in which an amount of that scale would be
called upon to be honoured is so remote as to be completely unrealistic. It is
not just me saying that; the markets and rating agencies are all keeping a
close eye on this stuff. Neither of those has raised concerns about it. Other
countries are doing the same thing.[38]
3.40
The risk to the taxpayer from the wholesale funding guarantee is limited
by it being restricted to APRA‑supervised entities (who are required to
have adequate capital and risk management procedures) and standard 'plain
vanilla' bonds.[39]
Nonetheless, the Committee notes that the insistence that any risks are
miniscule appears inconsistent with the tiered fees that are justified as
reflecting differences in risks.
3.41
The Australian Bankers' Association questions whether the contingent
liability is anywhere near $770 billion. They argue the government/taxpayer is
only exposed to $110 billion of it, as the deposit guarantee is
underwritten by the banks collectively.[40]
This is presumably a reference to the industry levy proposed for the original
financial claims scheme with the $20,000 cap.
3.42
It has been suggested that the Government could not possibly meet the $770 billion
cost of this guarantee if fully called upon and so this is a fraudulent
representation. However, it is hard to envisage circumstances short of the
country being annihilated in a nuclear war where the value of every Australian
bank loan – and the houses and business assets which are mortgaged to support
them – falls to zero and all the capital of the banks is wiped out. (It is
equivalent to saying that the insurance companies could not deliver on their
promises if every insured house burnt down at once or every insured person died
at once; or that the banks could not deliver on their promises if every
depositor unexpectedly wanted to withdraw their deposits in cash on one day.)
3.43
If this extremely hypothetical event were to occur, and the government met
the guarantee by borrowing $770 billion, this would add an amount equivalent to
64 per cent of GDP to government debt.
3.44
Reflecting the prudent fiscal policies adopted over the previous decade,
which saw Australia enter the financial crisis with a strong positive net asset
and cash position, Australia has a much smaller government debt than most other
countries. Indeed, despite the Labor Government taking us back into a net debt
position, because of past Coalition policies, Australia's fiscal position is so
strong that even adding debt worth over 60 per cent of GDP would still leave
gross government debt a smaller proportion of GDP than it is in many other
countries which continue to readily borrow in international markets (Table
3.2).
Table 3.2: General
government financial liabilities
Per cent to GDP, 2009
|
gross |
net |
|
|
gross |
net |
Australia |
16 |
-5 |
|
Netherlands |
70 |
31 |
Austria |
73 |
38 |
|
New Zealand |
27 |
-14 |
Belgium |
100 |
81 |
|
Norway |
63 |
-137 |
Canada |
78 |
27 |
|
Sweden |
53 |
-11 |
France |
86 |
50 |
|
Switzerland |
46 |
12 |
Germany |
78 |
51 |
|
United Kingdom |
75 |
48 |
Japan |
190 |
97 |
|
United States |
87 |
59 |
Source: OECD Economic Outlook,
June 2009.
3.45
The above discussion has focused on risks from providing the guarantee.
It also needs to be noted that in exchange for taking on the contingent
liability the Government has so far earned about $½ billion in fees.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page