Chapter 1 Introduction
Referral of the bills
1.1
On 2 November 2011 the Hon Wayne Swan MP, referred a suite of bills (the
Minerals Resource Rent Tax Bill 2011 and related draft legislation) to the
Standing Committee on Economics for inquiry and report. The Bills are:
n Minerals Resource
Rent Tax Bill 2011
n Minerals Resource
Rent Tax (Consequential Amendments and Transitional Provisions) Bill 2011
n Minerals Resource
Rent Tax (Imposition—General) Bill 2011
n Minerals Resource
Rent Tax (Imposition—Customs) Bill 2011
n Minerals Resource
Rent Tax (Imposition—Excise) Bill 2011
n Petroleum Resource
Rent Tax Assessment Amendment Bill 2011
n Petroleum Resource
Rent Tax (Imposition—General) Bill 2011
n Petroleum Resource
Rent Tax (Imposition—Customs) Bill 2011
n Petroleum Resource Rent
Tax (Imposition—Excise) Bill 2011
n Tax Laws Amendment
(Stronger, Fairer, Simpler and Other Measures) Bill 2011
n Superannuation
Guarantee (Administration) Amendment Bill 2011.
Origins and purpose of the bills
1.2
The package of Bills covers a range of measures aimed at sharing the
benefits of the mining boom across the economy and into the future including:
n applying a 22.5 per
cent Mineral Resource Rent Tax (MRRT) on the profits that mining companies make
on iron ore and coal on their mining activities only (excluding value adding
activities such as transportation and concentration);
n extending the
Petroleum Resource Rent Tax to all offshore and onshore gas and oil projects,
including coal seam methane;
n increasing the
superannuation guarantee from 9 per cent to 12 per cent;
n increasing the age
limit for the superannuation guarantee; and
n improving asset-based
deductions for small business.
Minerals rent taxation
1.3
The main piece of legislation, the Minerals Resource Rent Tax Bill, establishes
a tax on the economic rents miners make from taxable resources (mainly iron ore
and coal). ‘Economic rent’ is the return in excess of what is needed to
attract and retain factors of production in the production process. The tax
applies to that part of the profits made by miners that relates to the minerals
as they are extracted from the ground but before they undergo any significant
processing or value add.
1.4
The MRRT is a project-based tax, so a liability is worked out separately
for each project the miner has at the end of each MRRT year. A miner has a project
when it is entitled to iron ore or coal extracted under a mining lease. The
miner’s liability for a year is the sum of its projects’ liabilities.
1.5
A project liability is worked out by multiplying mining profits (less allowances)
by the tax rate of 22.5 per cent (that is, a nominal tax rate of 30 per
cent, reduced by 25 per cent to recognise the miner’s specialist
skills in extracting minerals).[1]
1.6
Mining profit consists of mining revenue less mining expenditure. Mining
revenue is mainly that part of the proceeds the miner receives from selling
taxable resources that reasonably relates to the resources in the form and at
the place they were in at their valuation point (usually when leaving the run‑of‑mine
stockpile).[2]
1.7
Mining expenditure is principally the costs of finding and extracting
the taxable resources and getting them to their valuation point.[3]
1.8
Mining profit may be reduced by allowances for past losses, for the
miner’s existing investments at 2 May 2010 (called a starting base
allowance), and for the miner’s Commonwealth, State and Territory mining
royalty amounts. Some allowances can be transferred to other projects to reduce
their mining profits.[4]
1.9
If a miner’s total mining profit from all its projects comes to less than
$50 million in a year, there is a low-profit offset that reduces the miner’s
liability for MRRT to nil. The offset phases out for mining profits between $50
million and $100 million.
1.10
The Bills are linked in their commencement dates to the passage of other
legislation, including the Bills for the MRRT.
Background
Royalties
1.11
Throughout Australia, State and Territory governments tax non-renewable
resources by applying a royalty to production. Royalties are generally applied
on the basis of volume or value and do not take into account how profitable a
mining operation is.[5]
1.12
Royalties therefore will only recover a small portion of mining rents
when mining profits are high, but will also tax mining operations where no
economic rent is present.
Australia’s Future Tax System review
1.13
The Minerals Resource Rent Tax has its origins in the recommendations of
the Australia’s Future Tax System (AFTS) review.
1.14
The AFTS review was charged with reviewing Australia's tax system to
examine and make recommendations to create a tax structure that will position
Australia to deal with the demographic, social, economic and environmental
challenges of the 21st century and enhance Australia's economic and social outcomes.[6]
1.15
The AFTS review found that the royalty regimes applied by the States and
Territories are among the most distorting taxes in the Federation and are not
particularly flexible.
1.16
As a consequence of being distorting and relatively inflexible,
royalties tend to be set at rates low enough for the mining industry to
continue to operate in periods of low to average commodity prices. However,
this means that royalties will fail to provide an adequate return to the
community when commodity prices are high.
1.17
The company tax is a profits-based tax, which generally applies to
incorporated businesses and will tend to raise more revenue from mining
operations when profits are high. However, the AFTS review found that there
would be benefits to the economy more broadly through lowering the company tax
rate to assist in attracting internationally mobile capital investment.
1.18
The AFTS review concluded that a lower company tax rate was desirable
for Australia but only if a specific profits-based tax was extended to mining
operations to ensure a sufficient return to the community in periods of high
commodity prices.[7]
1.19
In response to the AFTS review, the Government decided that, from
1 July 2012, the Minerals Resource Rent Tax (MRRT) will apply to
profits from coal and iron ore operations, while the Petroleum Resource Rent
Tax (PRRT) will be extended to all offshore and onshore gas and oil projects,
including coal-seam methane. These commodities account for the bulk of
Australia’s mineral wealth.
Consultation in the development of the MRRT
1.20
In May 2010, the Government announced that it would introduce a
Resources Super Profits Tax (RSPT). The design of the RSPT was largely rejected
by the mining industry and the Government began consultation and negotiation
with the three largest members of the Australian resources industry and
developed a heads of agreement for the Minerals Resource Rent Tax (MRRT). There
followed what the Government described as one of the most comprehensive
stakeholder consultation processes ever conducted by an Australian government.[8]
1.21
The consultation on the MRRT was driven by the Policy Transition Group
(PTG) and the Resource Tax Implementation Group.
1.22
The design of the MRRT is based on the recommendations of the PTG. The
PTG was chaired by Mr Don Argus AC and the Hon Mr Martin Ferguson AM MP, Minister
for Resources, Energy and Tourism. The PTG consulted extensively across
Australia on the new resource tax arrangements and reported to the Government
in December 2010, making 94 recommendations.[9]
1.23
In accepting all of the PTG’s recommendations, the Government further
established the Resource Tax Implementation Group, which comprised
representatives from industry and the tax profession, to work closely with the
Treasury, the Australian Taxation Office and the Department of Resources,
Energy and Tourism to develop the legislation for introduction to Parliament.[10]
This represented a cooperative approach between industry and government in the
process of tax reform.
1.24
The committee heard widespread criticism from many who were not
consulted on the original RSPT or on the MRRT Heads of Agreement with the three
large companies. However, the committee heard wide support and satisfaction
with the consultation processes that followed.[11] For example, ICAA stated
that much of these consultations were a template for the future:
The fact that the government gave the Policy Transition
Group, who were drawn largely from experts in the relevant mining and resources
sectors, the opportunity to examine the issues, to go through a consultative
process across the country, to talk to stakeholders to hear their concerns and
to deliberate and make recommendations about those issues and solutions to
those issues demonstrates a very sound way to go about resolving some of the
complexities in the policy-making process.
Turning to the Resource Tax Implementation Group, features of
the RTIG process that I believe would be standout indicators for how we could
do things better in other areas of policy design across the tax system would be
the fact that you had a combination of experts from within the resources
industry, experts from within the tax profession, who typically are engaged on
a quite frequent basis with government, Treasury and the tax office in the
design and development of policy and law. Certainly, there was the contribution
that flowed from the involvement of senior officials from the Australian
Taxation Office who could provide a perspective around how they would
ultimately want to potentially administer the law once it is in place. Of
course, the officials from the Treasury promoting the policy objectives of the
government meant that you had quite a well rounded constructive process that
did, I believe, deliver a better outcome than might otherwise have been the
case had you not employed a consultative process like that.[12]
Policy drivers
Minerals Resource Rent Tax
1.25
The strategic thinking that drives the Bills was summed up by the
Treasurer, the Hon. Mr Wayne Swan MP, in a speech that he delivered in Western
Australia in mid 2010. In this speech, the Treasurer explained that:
We are on the cusp of something special here. Our future is
looking so much more promising than one year ago. It is about maximising our
opportunities – keeping Australia ahead of the pack, just as we were ahead of
the pack in dealing with the global recession. It is about managing our
resource wealth sustainably, capturing a fairer share for all Australians and
turning it into other forms of wealth that last. It is about reinvesting the
proceeds of the resources boom to strengthen the resources sector and to
broaden the whole economy, invest in capacity and boost national savings.[13]
1.26
The challenges to which such thinking responded were described by the
Treasurer in some detail in a ministerial statement to the parliament delivered
shortly after the speech above. In the words of the Treasurer:
The Australian people own 100 per cent of Australia's natural
resources and they deserve a fairer share of the super profits mining companies
make, particularly during this boom. As these profits have risen in recent
years the Australian people's share of those profits has fallen.
Before the last boom, the country got $1 in every $3 of
mining profits through royalties and resource charges but at the end of that
boom, that was down to just $1 in $7. It is impossible to justify a system
where Australians pay proportionately more tax as their income goes up, while
mining companies pay proportionately less as their profits go up. The companies
have been unable to justify this, and I cannot let the situation stand.
Profits were over $80 billion higher in 2008-09 than in 1999‑2000
yet governments only collected an additional $9 billion in revenue. The
Government simply wants to take the Australian people's share of mining profits
back to around where it was in the early 2000s. The Howard Government was not
overtaxing the resource sector then, and this Government won't either. In fact,
we will get the same share with a more pro-investment tax structure.[14]
1.27
The Treasurer elaborated by stating that the existing arbitrary and
ever-changing state royalty regimes result in less mining investment, fewer
mining jobs and less mining production. Worse still, royalties tax production
and ignore the costs involved in generating that output. This results in too
many Australian mines shutting down before they have exhausted the resources
available, while suppressing the establishment of other mines. As a result, too
many commercially viable resources are left to waste in the ground, for no
better reason than that state royalties have made their exploitation uneconomic.
1.28
The committee heard from the Minerals Council of Australia (MCA), which
does not agree that resource taxes have failed to keep pace with the boom and
have declined as a share of profits. While the MCA supports the concept of a
profits based tax, it argues that this needs to involve fundamental reform of
state royalty arrangements. However, the MCA accepts the final design of the
MRRT as a workable outcome.[15]
1.29
According to the Treasurer, the Government’s objective was to ensure
that Australia would have something of enduring public benefit to show from the
sale of our non-renewable resources, that Australia would not squander the
advantages of record global mineral prices.
1.30
The Government has settled on an increased level of national savings as
its preferred legacy of the mineral boom. To do this, the Government aims to
deliver a package of measures, including boosting savings through an increased
Superannuation Guarantee, phased in over ten years, as well as by boosting
savings by making superannuation concessions fairer for low income earners.
1.31
This strategic thinking also addresses the demographic challenge of an
aging society. Over the next 40 years, Australia’s population will age rapidly,
as an increasing proportion of the population will be older due to falling
rates of mortality and lower rates of birth. There will be increasing numbers
of older people to support, and fewer people of workforce age to provide that
support.
Superannuation
1.32
Superannuation provides working people with the means to save for their
retirement.
1.33
Because superannuation works to reduce welfare dependency, it has been
the policy of successive Australian governments to make superannuation
available to as many Australians as possible, so that they are able to save for
their retirement in a prudentially supervised and concessionally taxed
environment.
1.34
The adequacy of retirement incomes is typically assessed using the
concept of the replacement rate, defined as the ratio of an individual’s income
or spending power after retirement to that before retirement. There is no
specific target set for the replacement rate, however, a worker on AWOTE might
be expected to have a replacement rate of about 63 per cent.[16]
1.35
Related to the adequacy of retirement incomes is the level of household
savings. Australia’s net household savings was negative from 2002-03 until very
recently, which means that households have been borrowing to spend more on
goods and services than they could afford based purely on their income. Against
this measure, net household wealth has been increasing due to the housing
property market, but much of this increase is in the form of unrealised gains
that are often not utilised until well after retirement. Individuals retiring
while still carrying significant debt (home mortgages and consumer finance) are
unlikely to find their retirement incomes to be adequate. Households that do
not save while earning pre-retirement incomes will find retirement difficult.
1.36
To some extent the superannuation regime defers income into a compulsory
retirement saving arrangement that might otherwise have been spent on
consumption.
1.37
The Superannuation Guarantee was introduced in 1992 with a long
term ambition to achieve a contribution rate of 15 per cent.[17]
A ten-year phase in period followed and the Superannuation Guarantee minimum
contribution rate was completed on 1 July 2002 with a rate of 9 per cent. The
coverage of superannuation in Australia has grown significantly as a result of
the introduction of the Superannuation Guarantee system.[18]
1.38
The Superannuation Guarantee directs some of an employee’s current
remuneration into improving their standard of living in retirement.
1.39
The previous Government contended that at nine percent there was a
balance between employees forgoing current consumption for increases in living
standards after retirement. On this basis the previous Government was not
inclined to increase the superannuation guarantee rate.
Objectives and scope of the inquiry
1.40
The objective of the inquiry is to investigate the adequacy of the suite
of Bills in achieving their various policy objectives and, where possible,
identify any unintended consequences.
Conduct of the inquiry
1.41
Details of the inquiry were placed on the committee’s website. A media
release announcing the inquiry and seeking submissions was issued on Thursday 3
November 2011.
1.42
Nine submissions and three exhibits were received. These are listed at
Appendix A.
1.43
Public hearings were held in Canberra on Tuesday 8 and Wednesday 9 November
2011. A list of the witnesses who appeared at the hearing is available at
Appendix B. The submissions and transcript of evidence were placed on the
committee’s website at
http://www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/House_of_Representatives_Committees?url=economics/index.htm.