Chapter 3 Complex legislation
Measuring complexity
Bipartisan complaints
3.1
One of the common themes during the inquiry was the complexity of tax
laws and the uncertainty and costs this imposes on the community. Major
stakeholder groups, including the Taxation Institute of Australia, CPA Australia, the Institute of Chartered Accountants in Australia (ICAA), the
National Institute of Accountants and Taxpayers Australia, made this claim.[1]
The Inspector-General of Taxation and the Ombudsman also stated that complex
tax laws are imposing significant costs on taxpayers and tax agents.[2]
3.2
The Committee also received evidence that, as our economies and
financial arrangements become more complicated, our tax laws will reflect this
and become more complicated themselves. The Ombudsman noted:
Nuanced and sophisticated legislation may be required if administrators
are to be able to adequately deal with the variety of different taxpayer entities
and interactions, and to achieve government objectives of ensuring that
taxation contributes sufficient revenue to fund necessary social and community
services.[3]
3.3
The Committee accepts that complex tax laws will occasionally be
required. However, the breadth of complaints during the inquiry about
complexity, and the comments that stakeholders have made over the last 20
years, demonstrate that this complexity has exceeded necessary levels. For
example, Senators and Members across the political spectrum have complained
about or acknowledged tax complexity.[4]
3.4
For a number of years, the judiciary has also expressed concern about
the complexity of tax laws. In 1990, Justice Hill stated that one provision on
which he was ruling was drafted:
…with such obscurity that even those used to interpreting the
utterances of the Delphic oracle might falter in seeking to elicit a sensible
meaning from its terms.[5]
3.5
In 1991, a High Court Justice criticised the complexity of the capital
gains tax:
The provisions of s.160M(5), (6) and (7) of the Income Tax
Assessment Act 1936 (‘the Act’) and provisions to which they are related
are extraordinarily complex. They must be obscure, if not bewildering, both to
the taxpayer who seeks to determine his or her liability to capital gains tax by reference to them and to the lawyer who is called upon
to interpret them … successive administrations have allowed the Act to become a
legislative jungle in which even the non-specialist lawyer and accountant are
likely to lose their way.[6]
3.6
In 2000, Justice Kirby noted the Court’s long standing concern about the
complexity of tax legislation:
This appeal from the Full Court of the Federal Court of
Australia concerns the construction of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1936 (‘the
Act’). The complexity of the Act has long been the subject of comment and
complaint.[7]
3.7
In 2002, a Member of the Administrative Appeals Tribunal found that any
deficiency with the way the Australian Taxation Office (ATO) exercised the
Commissioner’s discretion was based on the complexity of the legislation:
The rules are complex and rigid. They cry out for simplification
… If blame is to be apportioned, a large part of it must rest with the
legislation provisions that dictate the result in this case. At the very least,
they are inherently difficult to explain.[8]
3.8
Based on this evidence, the Committee concludes that complexity in tax
legislation is a widely recognised problem. The broad political spectrum
recognises this complexity. Further, the judiciary has expressed concern about
complexity for at least 15 years. This suggests that there are a number of long
standing reasons that have contributed to complexity. The report considers this
issue further below.
Amount of legislation
3.9
One method of measuring the complexity of a tax system is to count the
number of pages of tax legislation. The Committee accepts that this is not a
perfect method. For example, the Ombudsman noted that the volume of rulings
also needs to be taken into account.[9] Nevertheless, the
Committee believes that the number of pages of tax legislation gives a good
initial overview of the degree of complexity.
3.10
Figure 3.1 on the next page gives time series data on the number of
pages of income tax legislation since the Parliament first passed the 1936 Act.
The first point to note from the chart is that this data has not been collected
on a systematic basis, so there is a large number of gaps in the data.
3.11
The second point to note is that, sometime after 1970, the rate at which
the tax legislation grew started to accelerate. This rate of growth in the
income tax legislation appeared to accelerate again in the late 1990s,
apparently due to A New Tax System and the plain English rewrite. The latter
commenced in 1993, with the Parliament passing the first legislation in 1997.
3.12
Since 1997, there have been two main income tax Acts: the Income Tax
Assessment Act 1936 and the Income Tax Assessment Act 1997. These
two pieces of legislation contained duplicated provisions, which partially
accounted for the increase in the volume of legislation. In November 2005, the
Treasurer released the Board of Taxation’s review of how the income tax laws
could be rationalised. The Board did not support a merger of the two Acts, particularly
because no consensus existed on the method by which it would be achieved. Instead,
the Board recommended that the Parliament repeal the duplicated or inoperative
provisions in the 1936 Act.[10]
Figure 3.1 Number of pages of income tax legislation, Australia, 1936 to 2006
Source Kobetsky M, Dirkis M, Income Tax (1997) Federation Press, p 40 and recent editions of the Income
Tax Assessment Act 1936 and Income Tax Assessment Act 1997.
3.13
The repeal of these inoperative provisions occurred in 2006. This is
shown as the drop at the end of the graph.
3.14
There has been some debate about whether this decrease in the volume of
the tax legislation has reduced complexity. In its submission, CPA Australia
argued that the tax law is effectively unchanged, so the compliance burden
remains the same:
While the Treasurer’s recent announcement that the Government
would move to reduce tax law by 30% through the removal of inoperative
provisions is necessary and useful, the impact on the overall compliance burden
on taxpayers and their advisers of such a change is unlikely to be significant
given that the provisions being removed are generally no longer relevant.[11]
3.15
The alternative view is that reducing the volume of legislation must
help taxpayers and tax agents to some degree, especially when they do not have
a large body of tax experience to draw on. As David Wallis commented, CPA
Australia’s argument:
…is based on an assumption of preconceived familiarity with
the legislation. What of those who do not know that the provisions are
inoperative; who do not know to ignore them? When even without these pages the
legislation is of considerable length, their ‘inoperative’ presence must nonetheless
operate overwhelmingly to labour, misdirect, and bemuse the reader who vainly
searches the pages in hope of assistance. For new practitioners involved in
taxation, the official declaration of inoperative provisions will no doubt
prove to be of assistance.[12]
3.16
The Committee is of the view that repealing the inoperative provisions
in the tax law has had a significant effect in reducing tax complexity. The
fact is that law is law, whether inoperative or not, and remains in force until
repealed. There is considerably more work to be done, but the reduced volume of
tax laws has been of assistance.
3.17
In 2004, PricewaterhouseCoopers and the World Bank published a
comparison of the number of pages of tax legislation of the 20 largest
economies in the world. Australia, ranked 13th, was included. The results
are displayed in Figure 3.2.
3.18
The graph shows that, by international comparisons, Australia has a highly complex tax system. In 2004, Australia was ranked third out of the
20 largest economies in the world in terms of the volume of tax legislation.
Only India and the United Kingdom had bulkier tax laws.
3.19
The figure also shows the effect of the repeal of inoperative tax laws
in 2006 with an additional entry for Australia in 2007. Assuming all other
countries stayed at their 2004 levels, the repeal means that Australia dropped one ranking to fourth, below Japan. This is consistent with the
Committee’s earlier conclusion that the repeal of inoperative provisions will
be beneficial in addressing tax complexity, but that more is required.
Figure 3.2 Number of pages of primary federal tax
legislation of the top 20 nations by GDP, 2004
Source PricewaterhouseCoopers,
The World Bank, Paying Taxes: The global picture (2006) PricewaterhouseCoopers,
p 16, viewed at http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/DB_Paying_Taxes.pdf on 31 January 2007.
3.20
Finally, the graph gives an indication of the scale of work remaining.
Although international comparisons must always be done cautiously, a possible
goal for Australian legislators and governments would be to place Australia at the middle of these rankings. In 2004, the middle ranked countries were Germany and the Netherlands, with 1,700 and 1,640 pages of tax laws respectively.
Therefore, a long term goal would be to reduce Australia’s tax legislation to
approximately one quarter of its current length (from 6,000 pages to 1,500
pages).
Conclusion
3.21
The Committee received evidence that, as financial arrangements become
more complex, our tax system must respond and become more complex as well. The
Ombudsman stated:
While clarity and simplicity are admirable goals in
legislation and administration, the reality of tax reform may be that the
complex nature of our modern life — especially insofar as it involves
commercial activities and financial transactions — in some senses mandates a degree
of complexity.[13]
3.22
The Committee agrees with this comment and accepts that some complexity
is inevitable in the tax system. However, the long standing and bipartisan
concerns expressed within the community, the large volume of legislation by
international standards, and the considerable amount of time spent by tax
agents on keeping up to date demonstrates that tax complexity has gone too far.
Both Parliament and the Government need to change current practices to deliver
a more practical system in the medium to long term.
Causes of complexity
Historical development of tax laws
3.23
In his 2003 paper, Professor Rick Krever gives a historical overview of
how Australia’s tax laws became so complex. The main theme in the paper is that
each participant in the tax system has acted in a logical manner from their own
perspective. No particular group has claimed responsibility for the tax system
overall, leading to the current arrangements. The groups best placed to have
taken overall responsibility for the tax system have been successive
parliaments, who must take ultimate responsibility.[14]
3.24
For example, the judiciary has taken a conservative, precedent-driven
approach to interpreting tax legislation. Although this is normal judicial
practice, it has had unintended consequences. For example, the courts have used
principles from the law of trusts to define income for tax purposes. Therefore,
some gains that have clear economic benefit are not traditionally defined as
income, such as gains from selling investment assets. Another example is the
principle of vicarious liability in tort law to decide whether a worker is an
employee or not. Vicarious liability revolves around the amount of control that
the ‘employer’ exercises over the ‘employee.’ However, this test does not
examine the economic nature of the relationship, which is probably more
relevant for tax purposes.
3.25
Although these judicial methods have made tax law more difficult to
apply, Professor Krever notes that parliaments (and implicitly governments, who
usually introduce the legislation) have authority to overturn these decisions
by legislation.[15]
3.26
Another key group is the advisers. Many pieces of tax legislation over
the years have distinguished particular entities or transactions for the
purpose of delivering a tax benefit. Often, accountants and lawyers have
changed the legal character of their clients’ affairs to obtain this benefit
for their clients. One example among many was in the 1970s, where the gains on
the sale of shares were tax free. Taxpayers, therefore, sought to extract value
from shareholdings on this basis, rather than by receiving dividends. In
economic terms, these ways of extracting value from shares are similar.
Therefore, it was not difficult to change the legal appearance of the
transaction to fit the tax law.
3.27
Some commentators have argued that advisers should exercise professional
responsibility and not devise these arrangements. However, where the
transactions are legal, the legislature must also bear responsibility for
establishing the framework within which these transactions occur.[16]
3.28
Professor Krever also expresses concern about how various public sector
groups in the political process have approached tax issues:
n legislative drafters
continue to use complex terms and structures in drafting legislation
n Treasury has tended
to take ‘stop-gap’ solutions to legislative repairs, rather than more
fundamental reforms
n elected
representatives have preferred ‘stop-gap’ solutions, partially due to the three-year
election cycle
n elected
representatives have used the tax system to achieve social and economic policy
goals, rather than efficiently collect revenue.[17]
3.29
In many cases, the combination of these factors has led to a vicious
circle where a legal distinction is enacted and then advisers seek to exploit
it:
Using, or more accurately, misusing, the income tax law as a
spending vehicle is undoubtedly one of the largest sources of complexity in the
legislation. It has proved impossible to deliberately distort investment or
consumption behaviour by lowering the tax burden on preferred activities and
not invite abuse. Tax law never specifies the intended recipients of
concessions; at best it seeks to define the types of transactions or
investments that will qualify for tax expenditures. However tightly the
boundaries of desired activities and assets are defined, it is inevitable that
they will be breached by well advised taxpayers recharacterising the
transactions and investments to qualify for the subsidies. This activity, in
turn, will lead to complex anti-avoidance measures intended to protect the
integrity of the original subsidy scheme. The new legislation will lead to
further planning which will lead to further legislation, and the cycle will
continue for many years until either the concession is abandoned or is buried
within dozens of complex anti-avoidance provisions.[18]
3.30
The idea that a large number of groups are responsible for the current
state of affairs was confirmed in evidence. The Taxation Institute of Australia stated:
I do not point the finger at anyone in particular because all
of us are in fact guilty parties in allowing the laws to get to that kind of
level in some areas.[19]
3.31
Given that many of the issues of tax complexity stem from tax policy and
legislation, addressing it probably needs to occur at a high level. There may
be scope for detailed review by a parliamentary committee in future into tax
complexity and the means by which simplification can be achieved.
3.32
The ANAO recently examined the use of the tax system to implement
spending programs in its recent audit on the tax expenditures statement. In
2006-07, tax expenditures totalled $41 billion. The audit found a number of
deficiencies in current practice, including a lack of standards to govern the
integrated reporting of outlays and tax expenditures, unreported categories of
tax expenditures, and in many cases a lack of reliable estimates for tax
expenditures. The ANAO also noted a succession of reviews of tax expenditures. The
ANAO stated, ‘few of the recommendations of these reviews have been adopted.’
This meant each review tended to make the same findings and recommendations as
the review before it.[20]
3.33
These long standing difficulties suggest that reform of tax expenditures
is overdue. Tax concessions, exemptions and allowances distort and complicate
the tax system. Equity and efficiency is often served when the system is made
simpler. In February 2008, the Minister for Finance announced a program-by-program
review of government spending and tax concessions with a focus on efficiency,
transparency and accountability.[21]
The use of exemptions
3.34
Occasionally, drafters of tax legislation have the choice between
listing specific items that will attract tax consequences, or to make the
arrangement more general and then list a number of exemptions. During the
inquiry, the Committee received evidence that the exemption approach is often
used and is much more difficult for practitioners to apply. In relation to
Fringe Benefits Tax, the Tax Institute of Australia stated:
The New Zealand model, as originally designed, was quite
simple. They asked: ‘Where are 90 per cent of the fringe benefits arising?’ They
then said: ‘Let’s go after that. Let’s make it very specific. They’re the bits
that we want to tax, and by hitting the employers we’ll try and encourage them
to cash it out.’ That is essentially what the driver was under the original
fringe benefit tax rules. The difficulty is that our approach was to go global
… and to try and capture everything within the web and then only let little
bits out.
By doing that, we have created all these very complex rules…
We have really got to the point where we need to ask: ‘Where are the big
dollars in this stuff? What are the things that we want to chase? Are the
little ones really worth it from the collection side?’[22]
3.35
Further, legislators have the choice of deciding how many exemptions to
allow for a particular arrangement. These exemptions also add to complexity.
The ICAA commented in relation to pay as you go:
The pay-as-you-go instalment system is probably another one
of those examples where we had legislation that was brought in and the effect
of it was realised after the event … At the end of the day, now you have a base
legislation with so many carve-outs that is extraordinarily complex legislation
to read. Something that was basically fairly simple for companies and for individuals
is now extraordinarily complicated.[23]
3.36
The Committee accepts that governments and legislators make the final
decision on structuring taxes. They also introduce exemptions for sound policy
reasons. However, the Committee believes that exemptions need to be more widely
recognised as a source of tax complexity.
Frequency of changes
3.37
The Committee also received evidence that the rate of changes to the tax
laws have added to complexity. In its 2004 pre-election survey, the Australian
Chamber of Commerce and Industry asked businesses what are their most critical
issues generally. The overall complexity of the tax system was ranked second.
The frequency of changes to tax laws and rules was ranked fifth.[24]
3.38
The National Institute of Accountants also argued that the frequency of
legislative change has made it harder for the ATO to effectively administer the
law, with consequences for taxpayers and tax agents:
The NIA [National Institute of Accountants], however, believe
that the problem lies in the number of new measures introduced at any one time.
While this appears contradictory to the NIA’s position on supporting personal
tax reform, it does however highlight the capacity of taxpayers, tax agents and
the ATO to continue to adopt reforms. In other words, for taxpayers and their
representative to have certainty in self-assessment, there needs to be a degree
of stability in the law.[25]
3.39
Once again, the Committee accepts that governments and legislators are
required to meet the needs of the community as they arise and that, on
occasions, this may involve large scale or frequent tax changes. However, the
Committee believes that there is value in governments and parliaments recognising
that such changes significantly add to the compliance burden for taxpayers and
tax agents.
Perspective of tax agents
3.40
In November 2004, Dr Margaret McKerchar from the Australian School of Taxation (Atax) at the University of New South Wales conducted a survey on
the complexity of the tax system. She sent an electronic link to the survey to
tax agents through the ATO’s electronic newsletter, E-link.[26]
At the time, over 20,000 tax agents received E-link. Atax received
221 responses. Although this may not be a statistically valid sample, the
results give a useful indication of tax agent experiences.
3.41
The survey included questions about what aspects of the tax system
caused the most complexity to them. The results are shown in figure 3.3.
Figure 3.3 Causes of complexity experienced by tax agents,
2004 (%)
Source McKerchar M, ‘The Impact of Income Tax Complexity on Practitioners in Australia’ Australian Tax
Forum (2005) vol 20, p 538.
3.42
This survey confirms the earlier discussion. The most commonly cited
cause of complexity is the high number of exceptions, closely followed by
frequent changes to the tax law.
3.43
The next most common cause of complexity is ambiguity in tax law and
rulings. Uncertainty is a particular risk under the self assessment system.
Taxpayers are responsible for correctly lodging their return, typically with
the assistance of a tax agent. Where taxpayers make an error, they face the
prospect of paying penalties and interest if the ATO issues an amended
assessment.
3.44
This resulting complexity has a number of consequences on taxpayers, tax
agents, the wider community and the Government. These consequences are
discussed next.
Consequences of complexity
Compliance costs
3.45
One of the disadvantages of a complex tax system is that compliance
costs increase. One approach in measuring compliance costs is to quantify the
time and money spent by taxpayers in meeting their tax obligations and offset
this amount by the tax benefits and cash flow effects attached to tax
compliance.
3.46
It appears that Atax was the last group to conduct such research (in
1997), funded by the ATO. For the 1994-95 income year, Atax found that net
taxpayer compliance costs (that is, excluding the ATO) was $6.2 billion,
comprising 7.0% of relevant tax revenue and 1.36% of GDP.[27]
3.47
Extrapolating this result to the present is difficult. On one hand, the
tax system has probably become more complicated through growth in tax
legislation. On the other hand, the ATO has implemented a number of
technological innovations such as e-tax, electronic portals and pre-populated
returns that reduce complexity from the taxpayer’s perspective. Assuming a
pro-rata increase compared with GDP, net taxpayer compliance costs would be
$14.2 billion in 2006-07.[28] This is a considerable
sum.
Integrity of self assessment
3.48
The system of self assessment places responsibility on taxpayers to
ensure their tax returns are correct. However, this principle breaks down when
tax law is too complex for taxpayers to understand and imposes prohibitive
research costs on tax agents. It is inherently unfair for the ATO to issue an amended assessment with penalties and interest when taxpayers were unable to
initially comply.
Integrity of the legal system
3.49
The legal principle, ‘ignorance of the law is no excuse,’ dates from Roman times. The rationale for the principle is to prevent parties subject to legal proceedings
from avoiding responsibility by stating they were unaware of the relevant law.
The traditional assumption underlying the rule is that legislation is properly
published and distributed.[29] In the context of this
inquiry, however, the assumption now becomes that the law cannot be too
complex.
3.50
The Taxation Institute of Australia stated in evidence:
…one has to query: is it appropriate to have laws that have
been criticised by the courts as being horrendously complex and beyond the
comprehension of the ordinary taxpayer? …We cannot expect people to comply when
it can be nigh impossible to understand the law, and it makes a mockery of the
principle that ignorance of the law is no excuse.[30]
Tax agents
3.51
In its submission, the National Institute of Accountants stated that a
major cause of complexity in the tax system is the rate at which new provisions
are introduced.[31] One measure of the cost
of complexity is to assess how much time tax agents spend keeping up to date.
3.52
Margaret McKerchar’s 2004 survey of tax agents, discussed earlier,
included a question on this. Respondents stated that they spent an average of
six hours per week keeping up to date with income tax matters. The survey asked
tax agents why they did not spend more time on this activity. The main response
(79%) was that they had other work commitments to attend to. Only 7% stated
they were fully up to date.[32]
3.53
The Committee accepts that tax agents need to stay up to date with tax
laws and that it is something they should do regularly. However, the Committee
believes that six hours a week, or 15% of a 40 hour week, places too great a
burden on tax agents.
3.54
The Inspector-General of Taxation expressed concern about the
sustainability of this compliance burden on tax agents. His submission gives a
number of reasons why tax agents find the work unattractive:
Practitioners are frustrated by the amount of
non-value-adding work that they are required to do for the Tax Office and other
agencies such as ASIC. Duplication of information gathering across agencies
compounds this.
Practitioners are leaving the tax industry for more lucrative
fields such as financial planning and valuations.
Practitioners are, as a group, an ageing population. This is compounding
the gradual exodus.
Tax practitioner numbers are not replenishing due to
overwhelmingly more attractive opportunities and remuneration. People with
accounting and related skills are in great demand. Smaller tax practices cannot
attract new professional staff and few practitioners have succession plans for
their businesses.[33]
3.55
This burden may have been affecting tax agent numbers. The ATO presented data on the age profile of tax agents to the Committee. Figure 3.4 on the next
page compares the age of tax agents against the age profile of the working
population. It shows that, on average, tax agents are older than the general
population of employed workers. In particular, the main employment ages across
the economy are from 20 to 54. For tax agents, this age group is from 40 to 64.
Admittedly, the educational requirements for tax agents mean they are unlikely
to be fully qualified by the age of 25. However, one would expect significant
representation among the 30 to 34 and 35 to 39 age groups.
3.56
The ATO advised the Committee that, over the past few years, the total
number of tax agents has stayed constant. This occurred even though many agents
have indicated that they would like to retire in the near future. In 2003, 13%
of tax agents stated they would like to retire in the next two to three years.
This figure increased to 17% in 2005 and 19% in 2007.[34]
Figure 3.4 Age profile comparison: employed workers and
registered tax agents, July 2006 (%)
Source ATO, sub 50.3, p 41, Australian Bureau of Statistics, ‘Labour Force, Australia, Detailed -
Electronic Delivery, July 2007,’ Cat No 6291.0.55.001, viewed at http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@.nsf/DetailsPage/6291.0.55.001Jul%202006?OpenDocument.
3.57
The ATO also presented to the Committee some of its research into tax
agents’ job satisfaction. In 2005, 65% of tax agents reported that they were
either very satisfied or fairly satisfied with their work, which rose to 73% in
2007. Only 16% and 13% respectively stated they were either fairly dissatisfied
or very dissatisfied.[35] This data, combined with
the stable number of tax agents overall, suggests that the problem is
attracting new personnel to the industry, rather than encouraging tax agents
not to leave the industry.
3.58
In evidence, the ATO stated that it has been developing a strategy along
these lines:
There is a focus, which the commissioner has been working
through with CEOs [of the accounting and tax professional bodies], on
attracting young people to tax work. I am not sure whether there is an issue
about attracting people to the accounting profession or the legal profession.
The versatility of those degrees these days means that they are very attractive
to graduates for a range of opportunities … attracting them to tax compliance
work is certainly something we want to engage in.[36]
3.59
Tax agents are important to the tax system for a number of reasons.
Firstly, 97% of businesses and 74% of individuals use them,[37]
partially due to reasons of complexity. A shortage of tax agents will lead to
higher error rates as more taxpayers complete and lodge their own tax returns.
Tax agents also encourage an attitude of compliance among taxpayers.[38]
A significant drop in the number of tax agents will have a corresponding effect
on the integrity of the tax system.
3.60
The Committee is concerned that, if tax work remains relatively
unattractive for too long, the industry will eventually lose significant
numbers of staff.
3.61
Shortages may increase tax agent rates and attract some people to the
industry. However, the Committee is concerned that the unattractiveness of tax
work, compared with other work available to law and accounting graduates, means
this will only be a partial solution. Reducing the complexity of the tax system
will allow practitioners to focus on the core business and financial issues
facing their clients, which will make the work more attractive. How governments
and future parliaments might achieve this is discussed below.
Addressing complexity
Regulation impact statements
3.62
In An Assessment of Tax in 1993, the Joint Committee on Public
Accounts (JCPA) expressed concern about the high compliance costs of the
Australian tax system compared with the United Kingdom (UK). There, the JCPA
estimated that compliance costs in Australia were five to 11 times higher than
in the UK. The JCPA recommended that all future tax legislation be supported by
a Taxation Impact Statement, which would include compliance costs and an
assessment of simplification effects.[39]
3.63
The ATO implemented this recommendation in 1996. Later that year, the
previous Government announced a requirement for regulation impact statements
for any regulatory proposal affecting business. Although the process for tax
measures is roughly the same as for other proposals, they have been given some
exemptions from processes due to their commercial sensitivity.[40]
3.64
In January 2006, the Taskforce on Reducing Regulatory Burdens on
Business finalised its report, Rethinking Regulation. The Taskforce
noted a number of reasons affecting the quality of regulations. One
particularly relevant to this inquiry is that the costs of regulation are
diffuse and ‘off-budget.’ In other words, a large number of individuals and
businesses incur a relatively small amount of compliance costs each, but which
add up to a large sum across the economy.[41] The Atax compliance cost
study in 1997 demonstrates this has occurred in the tax industry.
3.65
Further, the move to self assessment made taxpayers responsible for
accurately complying with tax legislation. This meant that taxpayers bore many
of the costs of following complicated tax laws. Moving this responsibility
‘off-budget’ reduced the incentive for governments and parliaments to enact
simple legislation. Because the ATO does not need to initially assess each
return, it does not use the tax laws in the same way as taxpayers who
experience the full costs of complexity. One commentator has likened the ATO’s role to being, ‘an armchair critic.’[42]
3.66
The Taskforce concluded that systems such as regulation impact
statements have not delivered the benefits initially anticipated. Further, this
is common across the country:
… most governments in Australia have introduced disciplines
to limit the effect of these and other influences on the extent and quality of
regulation, most notably the Regulation Impact Statement requirements. However,
… while sound in principle, the requirements have often been circumvented or
treated as an afterthought in practice. The upshot is that they have often not
realised their potential to improve the quality of regulation.[43]
3.67
This assessment is consistent with submissions made to the inquiry. Both
the Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry and the Taxation Institute of Australia argued there should be better regulation impact statement processes. Instead of
trying to address individual complexity issues the Chamber preferred a systemic
approach through improved consultation and regulation assessments.[44]
3.68
The Taskforce made a number of recommendations to strengthen regulation
impact statements and regulation in general, including:
n mandating a compliance
costing tool in assessing proposed regulations
n tightening
‘gate-keeping’ requirements for regulatory proposals
n developing broader
performance indicators for regulators
n improving
consultation with stakeholders, such as establishing consultative bodies and
protocols on consultations.[45]
3.69
The previous Government agreed to most of the recommendations, including
all those listed above.[46] The Office of Best
Practice Regulation (OBPR) has released a range of material that builds on
these documents, including the Best Practice Regulation Handbook.
3.70
The OBPR, which is now part of the Finance and Deregulation portfolio,
has become Government’s internal advisor on compliance with the new
requirements for regulatory impact statements and associated processes.
Generally, they now comprise:
n decision makers such
as ministers receive OBPR advice on whether the assessment requirements have
been met before making decisions
n the Department of
Prime Minister and Cabinet needs the Prime Minister’s permission to circulate
Cabinet material that does not comply with the assessment processes
n where a measure is
implemented that has not complied with the assessment requirements, any
relevant explanatory material should include reference to this non-compliance
n non-compliant
measures should be subject to a post-implementation review within one to two
years of implementation
n OBPR reports publicly
about compliance with the requirements in its Best Practice Regulation
Report.[47]
3.71
The Committee appreciates that governments have introduced a number of
reforms in regulation assessment. However, the Committee is concerned that many
of the incentives to over regulate and to move risks ‘off-budget’ will remain.
The Handbook’s status as a policy, rather than legislation, means that
compliance is placed at greater risk.
3.72
The Committee accepts that converting the Handbook’s requirements
into legislation is excessive. From time to time, the community expects
governments to move quickly in addressing important issues. What is important
is that governments are accountable to the community when they decide to
override regulatory assessment processes. Section 39 of the Legislative
Instruments Act 2003 requires explanatory statements to be tabled with
legislative instruments. If this does not occur, the relevant minister is to
table an explanation for non-compliance. A similar approach can be taken here.
Recommendation 3
|
3.73
|
The Government introduce legislation to require:
n the
reporting of compliance with the Best Practice Regulation Handbook in
all explanatory material accompanying a regulatory proposal
n a
summary of the requirements of the Best Practice Regulation Handbook in
all explanatory material accompanying a regulatory proposal
n the
relevant minister to table an explanation with the relevant Bill or Legislative Instrument in either House of Parliament if this reporting of compliance
does not occur.
|
3.74
As Professor Krever noted, Parliament is ultimately responsible for the
tax law, and by implication the law overall. In the view of the Committee, the
individual Houses of Parliament can improve their own processes in examining
legislation. When Bills are referred for committee review, the standard terms
of reference are broad. That is, that the provisions of the bill are referred
and any other relevant matters. Therefore, regulatory impacts often do not get
considered.
3.75
Some Parliamentary review of regulatory proposals already exists, such
as the Senate Standing Committee on Regulations and Ordinances. However, this
tends to focus more on the status of the provisions as delegated legislation,
rather than the Parliament being a gate-keeper.[48]
The Committee would like to see Bills and other regulatory proposals being
subject to regulatory impact analysis by the Parliament, even if in the early
stages it covers more basic topics, such as the consultation process,
compliance with the Best Practice Regulation Handbook and the robustness
of any cost-benefit analysis.
3.76
Therefore, without limiting the right of the two chambers to set terms
of reference for Bill inquiries as they determine, the Committee makes the
following recommendation.
Recommendation 4
|
3.77
|
The Senate and House of Representatives Procedure Committees
examine whether to incorporate regulatory impacts as part of the standard
terms of reference for bills inquiries. The Procedure Committees can consider
whether to develop a checklist to assist Parliamentary Committees in
assessing regulatory impacts.
|
3.78
The Committee also wishes to ensure that agencies respond to regulatory
assessment requirements by improving their processes at an early stage in
policy and legislative development. The earlier agencies enhance their
processes, the more likely they are to deliver results.
3.79
The Committee would like to confirm that agencies make these changes to
their internal processes, preferably through reporting by an external
scrutineer. It appears that the best agency to make such assessments would need
direct access to agency records. The agency that has both expertise in relation
to public sector processes and can access agency records is the Australian
National Audit Office (ANAO). The ANAO may wish to consider whether this would
be a suitable topic for a performance audit in future.
Drafting styles
3.80
A large part of the tax debate has revolved around whether drafting
styles can improve tax laws. In 1990, the then Government investigated whether
the tax laws could be simplified through drafting alone. A joint ATO and Treasury taskforce concluded that this would not be effective without first simplifying
tax policy. The Government deferred the matter.[49]
3.81
In 1993, the JCPA’s report, An Assessment of Tax, recommended
redrafting the Income Tax Assessment Act 1936. This led to the Tax Law
Improvement Project (TLIP), commencing in 1993, which developed a radically new
way of drafting tax legislation. The Income Tax Assessment Act 1997
features plain English, diagrams, flow charts, cross references, and examples.
The Taxation Administration Act 1953 also now includes some of these
features.[50]
3.82
However, there have been a number of issues in relation to this rewrite.
Firstly, a number of parties have argued that, where tax policy is complex,
plain English legislation does not reduce this complexity. Rather, it tends to
show more clearly the complexity of the tax system. [51]
Sir Anthony Mason, a previous Chief Justice of the High Court, has stated,
‘plain language on its own is a passport to nowhere.’[52]
3.83
In response, Treasury argued as follows:
When you say that plain English has not helped, the Tax Law
Improvement Project, which resulted in the 1997 act, I think is
universally—even by the practitioners—regarded as clearer law to understand
than its predecessor in the 1936 act.
When I was a law student it was often said that certain
paragraphs of the 1936 act were incomprehensible. They may have been shorter in
the sense that they were of fewer pages in length, but it is very difficult
when you have paragraphs that go without a comma for half a page or a page.[53]
3.84
Perhaps the best way to resolve this debate is to recognise that plain
language drafting is a necessary, but not sufficient step in tax law
simplification. Deleting inoperative provisions made tax laws clearer but still
left much work to be done. The Committee views plain language drafting the same
way.
3.85
The second issue is that in 1993 the JCPA did not support a plain
English rewrite. Rather, the JCPA supported a tax policy review, which would
result in simpler tax policy and then be reflected in legislation. The report
states:
The Committee is of the view, that any attempt to redraft the
Act must necessarily look at broader, structural issues within the total
taxation system. Simplification, in this context, should concentrate on
achieving a tax system which is fair, equitable and economical. The objective
must be to reduce the total cost of the taxation system. Consequently a redraft
of the Act, while crucial, cannot be successfully achieved in the absence of a
fundamental review of the administrative, political and social implications of
changes in the Act.
The Committee received evidence concerning a proposal to
redraft a particular Division of the Act in a plain English style. The
Committee noted the merits of such an attempt but was also cognisant of the
significant difficulties raised by such an exercise. In particular, evidence
from the Commonwealth's First Parliamentary Counsel highlighted the
difficulties of major redrafting, particularly the importance of establishing
the underlying policy of the Act and the need to maintain, where necessary,
precision.
Consequently, in performing a redraft, the Committee believes
the fundamental assumptions underlying the Act, including the basis on which
the Act is to be administered and the policy decisions inherent in the Act,
should be evaluated, discussed and clarified.[54]
3.86
Earlier in the chapter, the Committee noted the high level of concern in
submissions and in evidence about the complexity of tax laws. It is not
surprising that the plain language rewrite of the tax laws, occurring under
successive governments, has not addressed the bulk of the problem. In a
comparative analysis of tax reform in the United States, United Kingdom, Australia and New Zealand, Margaret McKerchar from Atax stated:
In terms of drafting legislation, the experiences of the US, Australia and the UK… clearly demonstrate that improving the readability of the tax
laws per se is largely ineffective or at best superficial where the underlying
policies are not also reviewed. That is, complex policy, or policy where the
objectives are not well articulated, impede the drafting of simple and less
voluminous legislation.[55]
3.87
Sir Anthony Mason has taken the view that a number of factors are
necessary for tax simplification. He argued that, in New Zealand, successful
tax legislation is developed through the following:
…coherent and consistent policy formulation, transparent
consultation, drafting by a drafting unit within the Policy and Advice Division
of the Tax Office (not by Parliamentary Counsel or Treasury), purposive clauses
and extra-statutory references, general rules to overarch more specific rules
and a commitment to modern drafting techniques and to plain language.[56]
3.88
The Committee accepts that principles-based (or purposive) drafting will
have a role to play in simplifying tax laws. However, a number of factors are
also required. Perhaps the most important of these is consultation on tax
policy.
Consultation in legislation
3.89
In An Assessment of Tax, the JCPA expressed a strong desire that
any legislative rewrite should be done in a spirit of consensus:
During the Inquiry the Committee noted proposals for the
establishment of a specialist committee to oversee a redraft of the Act. The
Committee considered such a committee to be too limited given the fundamental
significance of the proposal for a redraft. The Committee has concluded that a
broadly based task force drawing upon a wide cross-section of skills,
experience and the professions, would represent a suitable vehicle for the
performance of this significant duty…
Such a rewrite however, would only be possible with the
absolute commitment of all political parties, the bureaucracy, the taxation
industry, business and taxpayers generally.[57]
3.90
The current Committee agrees with these sentiments. The best way for
government to develop a consensus is to engage with stakeholders and the
community. In other words, governments should consult on tax proposals.
3.91
In 2002, the Board of Taxation finalised a report on consultation, which
included some recommended principles. These included government:
n committing to consult
on developing all substantive tax legislation, unless exceptional circumstances
apply
n obtaining early
external input in identifying and assessing overall policy and implementation
options (before publicly announcing the policy)
n obtaining input from
external stakeholders in developing policy and legislative detail
n clearly articulating
the policy intent of each new measure at the initial announcement
n releasing a
consultation plan for each new tax measure.[58]
3.92
In the Rethinking Regulation report, the Taskforce noted that the
previous Government adopted the Board’s recommendations and this had led to
significant improvements in consultation. However, the Taskforce also noted
that more needed to be done:
Nevertheless, based on industry feedback, the Taskforce
believes that there is scope to further improve the tax consultation process
and to apply more rigorously the Board of Taxation’s recommendations.
For example, business has advised that some tax legislation
is still being introduced into Parliament with little effective consultation.
Any amendments subsequently required can be costly for business to implement
and costly for government in terms of the resource-intensive parliamentary
processes.
Other amendments are often made ‘just in time’, which creates
difficulties for businesses developing information technology systems and for
business planning and advice.[59]
3.93
Consistent with the Taskforce’s findings, the Committee received mixed
reports on how Treasury was consulting on new tax measures. The National Institute
of Accountants wished to, ‘publicly acknowledge the good work the Treasury is
doing.’[60] CPA Australia stated in
evidence:
With some exceptions we have written to the board of tax on
separately as part of their review of consultation, generally speaking we have
quite a healthy consultative environment on a suite of things…[61]
3.94
The Taxation Institute of Australia and ICAA put a different view. In
particular, they were concerned that the Government’s announcements were too
detailed at an early stage. They argued that the Government’s initial statement
should be more general and that consultation should be used to fill in the
policy details. The ICAA stated in evidence:
One of the problems is maybe even a bit earlier in the piece.
We do not get consulted at the pre-policy setting stage, so by the time we get
involved the policy has already been set… I think that probably the most
important one is that pre-policy setting stage, because once the policy is set
your hands are a bit tied. For example, one of the things that were introduced
last year … was the loss recoupment measure and the introduction of a $100 million
ceiling on whether you can pass the same business test. We do not believe that
that measure was properly thought through. The policy behind it is not clear. A
review was then ordered of how they can improve the same business test. As I
say, sometimes you almost need to go a couple of steps back to the policy
setting stage to make sure that what follows is appropriate.[62]
3.95
The Taxation Institute agreed:
At an earlier stage ministers often come out and make a
statement about a change to the tax law and then give a whole lot of detail in
relation to it, rather than saying, ‘Hang on. The principle or the response to
a problem that we are trying to achieve is X. Let us then announce that and go
away.’[63]
3.96
The Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry also supported improved
consultation.[64]
3.97
Another practice the Committee noted during the inquiry was confidential
negotiations between professional associations and Treasury. This occurred in
relation to the new legislation regulating tax agents. The Committee
understands that Treasury has been conducting confidential negotiations with
these groups for two years.[65] Confidential
consultations can only represent the views of the individuals that work for the
associations and not the views of the members that the associations are meant
to represent.
3.98
In evidence, Treasury argued that the particular nature of tax laws
means there cannot always be as much consultation as some stakeholders may wish
for. In particular:
Consultation cannot be mandated for every change to the tax
system, particularly in cases where there is commercial or market sensitivity,
or revenue risk due to tax avoidance. Also, the flexibility government requires
in managing the timing of policy change will at times determine the extent and
form of consultation that can be undertaken.[66]
3.99
The Committee is concerned that this view might remove an important
discipline on Treasury and the Government when developing tax legislation. One
of the by-products of consultation is that Treasury is obliged to defend the
Government’s proposals. The Committee would much prefer this occurred before a Bill enters Parliament. Addressing errors and making adjustments is much easier to achieve
during initial development, rather than after a proposal becomes law.
3.100
During the inquiry, the Board of Taxation released a further report on
consultation, Improving Australia’s Tax Consultation System. This report
originated in recommendation 7.1 in the Report of Aspects of Income Tax
Assessment (RoSA). The recommendation was that the Board, in conjunction
with Treasury, review international practices with a view to suggesting
improvements to the Australian system.[67]
3.101
The Board’s 2007 report is different to the 2002 report because it
represents an agreed position between Treasury and the Board. The 2002 report
stated the Board’s views alone. The new report places less emphasis on
consultation before announcing the policy intent. The 2002 report stated that
government should consult generally unless there are compelling reasons not to
do so and that one component of this would be to consult before announcing the
policy intent. In contrast, the 2007 report states that government should
consult on the detail of tax policy unless there are compelling reasons not to
do so. It then adds that government should ‘consider whether consultation may
be appropriate’ prior to announcing the policy intent.[68]
In light of the evidence to the inquiry, the Committee prefers the Board’s 2002
report on this issue.
3.102
The 2007 report gives some data on confidential consultations. Given the
inherently public nature of the tax system, the Committee expects a significant
level of public consultation to occur on tax measures. However, of the 58
measures legislated in 2005 on which consultation took place, the Board of
Taxation reports there was:
n targeted confidential
consultation for 33 measures
n a combination of both
open public consultation and targeted confidential consultation or targeted
public consultation for 18 measures
n targeted public
consultation for five measures
n open public
consultation for two measures.[69]
3.103
In other words, 57% of tax consultations in Australia are confidential.
The Committee regards this figure as too high. The report itself makes a cogent
argument for reducing the number of confidential consultations:
In recent years a significant proportion of consultations
have been conducted as targeted confidential consultations, as distinct from
public consultations. While this is appropriate in some cases, there are
substantial advantages in public consultations wherever possible. Public
consultation ensures that everyone in the community has the maximum opportunity
to provide information for government consideration. This potentially improves
the quality of the information available to government.[70]
3.104
The Committee agrees with these sentiments. The recommendation in the
2007 report, that consultations be public ‘wherever appropriate,’ is not
sufficient.[71] Treasury and the
Government need to take positive steps to conduct tax consultations in public
more regularly.
3.105
The Government is aware of these concerns. On 8 February 2008, it announced the appointment of a tax design review panel to investigate these issues, in
particular:
n reducing the delay
between policy announcement and introducing legislation
n increasing
consultation, in particular during the earlier policy development phase
n increasing
consultation in prioritising changes.[72]
3.106
The panel is chaired by Mr Neil Wilson of PriceWaterhouseCoopers. It was
scheduled to report to government on 30 April 2008.
3.107
This Committee also has its own views of the consultation process for
tax laws from the perspective of its members’ roles as Senators and MPs. Parliamentarians,
including ministers, are not professionally trained in tax law and need help in
assessing these laws. Therefore, in addition to devices like Explanatory
Memoranda and Bills Digests, the Parliament's committee review system is very important
in exposing potential problems with proposed law. However, it appears to the Committee
that once Cabinet approves tax proposals, governments expect they will be implemented
by all parties, without Parliamentary change. Indeed, much tax law is rushed or
waved through. The Committee believes that a more considered and measured approach
in Parliament is necessary, including the use of exposure drafts where
appropriate.
3.108
In order to improve the consultation process throughout the full
development phase of tax laws, and to increase the longevity and stability of
legislation, the Committee makes the following recommendation.
Recommendation 5
|
3.109
|
The Government and Treasury improve consultation on tax
measures by:
n increasing
the number of public consultations compared with confidential consultations
n increasing
the number of consultations conducted prior to the announcement of the policy
intent
n increasing
the use of exposure drafts of legislation, where practicable.
|
The review, Australia’s Future Tax System
3.110
On 11 May 2008, the Government announced a wide ranging review into the
tax system. It will be chaired by the Secretary to the Treasury, Dr Ken Henry and other external members. The terms of reference for the review cover topics
relevant to this inquiry, in particular ‘simplifying the tax system’ (3.5) and
‘reducing tax system complexity and compliance costs’ (4.4).[73]
3.111
In An Assessment of Tax, the JCPA argued that a wide-ranging
debate on tax policy fundamentals was a necessary foundation to addressing tax
complexity.[74] Australia’s Future Tax
System has the potential to provide this sort of debate and give effect to
the JCPA’s recommendations from 15 years ago.
3.112
During the inquiry, a number of topics were raised which had a bearing
on tax complexity and administration but were not directly within the terms of
reference. Given that the Committee received limited evidence on them, the best
way forward would be further consultation. The new review is an ideal vehicle
for this.
Reflecting the economics of a transaction in tax legislation
3.113
As Professor Krever has noted, much tax legislation has established
differing tax consequences based on legal distinctions. Tax lawyers and
accountants have often been able to change the legal form of transactions to
generate a tax benefit. Professor Krever argues that insufficient policy
development leads to a reliance on legal forms over economic substance, which
leads to avoidance opportunities.[75] On the other hand,
Treasury has stated that commercially sensitive and avoidance measures should
not be subject to public consultation.[76] It appears that, in some
cases at least, Treasury is concerned that an earlier release of a policy may
facilitate avoidance opportunities.
3.114
In the view of the Committee, a more robust policy underlying a tax
proposal is less likely to present such avoidance opportunities. In other
words, Treasury in the past may have been seeking to protect the revenue from
insufficiently developed policy.
3.115
The Committee notes that Treasury has recognised the problems caused by
basing the tax law on legal forms rather than economic effect.[77]
Further, the previous Government made a concerted effort to introduce this type
of reform through the tax value method after the Ralph Review. Professor Krever notes that the drawbacks of the tax value method were that some of its internal
definitions were not consistent, it retained all existing concessions, and the
scale of change was too large to be achieved in a single round of reform.[78]
3.116
The reduction in compliance costs from successfully introducing this
type of reform will be billions of dollars annually. Given these potential
benefits, the Committee is of the view that it should be canvassed in the
discussion paper. If all parties draw on the experience of the tax value
method, then the chances of successful reform on this occasion will be
increased.
Recommendation 6
|
3.117
|
In the discussion paper for the review, Australia’s Future
Tax System, Treasury and the review panel include the topic of basing the
tax system on financial relationships and economic outcomes, ahead of legal
forms.
|
The requirement to lodge a tax return
3.118
In Australia, almost 100% of individual taxpayers lodge tax returns.
This is high by international standards. For example, in the United Kingdom, the rate is 37%. In New Zealand it is 31%.[79] In approximately half of
OECD countries, the vast majority of taxpayers are not required to lodge
returns.[80]
3.119
Because lodging tax returns occurs across the economy, reducing the
number of taxpayers who do this is likely to generate large reductions in
compliance costs. There is scope for Australia’s Future Tax System, to
inform and stimulate debate on reducing the number of taxpayers who need to
lodge tax returns.
3.120
The OECD reports that a number of revenue bodies are assisting taxpayers
by pre-populating tax returns so that much of the information is already filled
in.[81] The ATO has also commenced this practice. The tax system is not necessarily simpler, but it masks
complexity from the taxpayer’s perspective. Although it is addressing the
symptoms of complexity, rather than the causes, this is the most the ATO can do as the implementer of tax legislation.
3.121
In order to remove the need for taxpayers to lodge returns, the key
requirement is that there should be no end of year ‘squaring-up.’ In other
words, the amounts withheld throughout the year should equal the amount that
the revenue authority would issue as a tax assessment following the lodgement
of a return.
3.122
Professor Chris Evans at Atax has listed the four main requirements to
achieve this result:
n a simple rate
structure, such as a low number of tax rates
n a comprehensive and
accurate withholding regime
n no work-related
deductions or, as the OECD, the Australian Financial Review and others
have suggested, a standard amount for this[82]
n a limited interaction
between the tax and social security systems.[83]
3.123
The Committee received a number of submissions that supported reducing
the number of taxpayers who needed to lodge returns.[84]
In evidence, Taxpayers Australia and the National Institute of Accountants gave
in principle support to reducing the requirement to lodge.[85]
In the past, CPA Australia has also supported this view.[86]
3.124
The first of the four requirements is an extension of what traditionally
occurs at most Budgets, namely an adjustment of income tax rates. Professor Evans at Atax has conducted research that demonstrates it is possible to generate
community support for these changes by setting the rates at the appropriate
level and having a low income tax offset.[87] Adjusting rates will
also be relevant to the workforce participation goals of Australia ’s Future Tax System.[88] For example, the
Committee for Economic Development of Australia (CEDA) has commissioned
research showing that increasing the tax free threshold raises workforce participation
across the economy.[89]
3.125
Changing the withholding regime is administrative in nature. Simplifying
tax rates (while maintaining a progressive system) and improving the
withholding regime appear to be matters of implementation.
3.126
The remaining two requirements, however, have more difficulties. For
example, work-related deductions are very popular because taxpayers see them as
delivering a sizeable tax refund each year. In 2000, the ATO commissioned research on this topic. The researchers concluded:
Refunds are what the personal tax system is all about for
most taxpayers. Maximizing one’s deductions is the only thing that makes the
system ‘work’ for ordinary PAYEs because this is the only way to maximize their
refund. Certainly, a personal income tax system without refunds would be
unpopular. Individual taxpayers are keen to preserve access to refunds because
it helps them to preserve a sense of control and a feeling that they have at
least a chance to get their ‘fair share back’ in the form of a refund.[90]
3.127
This view was confirmed in evidence. Taxpayers Australia stated:
Studies have been done. As far as taking that away from the
public is concerned, I think you will get a lot of objections, because it
brings closure to the year. They find out how much tax they have actually paid
and there is the opportunity to claim work deductions.[91]
3.128
On the other hand, there is a number of significant, valid reasons to
discontinue them. Firstly, it will reduce compliance costs through fewer
taxpayers lodging returns.
3.129
Secondly, they present a risk to the revenue in the longer term. These
deductions have been growing faster than incomes for a considerable period.[92]
For example, taxpayers now claim over $10 billion in work related deductions
annually. Recent annual increases have been of the order of 9%.[93]
If unabated, governments may need to change the rules to support the integrity
of the tax system.
3.130
Thirdly, they are the largest deduction claim for individuals and cost
the ATO significant resources in the compliance work needed to monitor them.[94]
3.131
Finally, if any such measure is revenue neutral, taxpayers will be
better off because they will have a wider choice of items on which to spend the
extra amounts of after tax income, rather than being limited to work expenses.
Although there is community support for work-related deductions at present, the
advantages of removing them should be debated. Australia’s Future Tax System,
is an ideal place to do this.
3.132
The final requirement to reduce the number of taxpayers who lodge tax
returns is to limit the interactions between the tax system and government
benefits, including social support payments. In Australia, the interactions
happen in two ways. Firstly, family tax benefits and other similar payments use
the tax system to check each recipient’s income estimate so that the Government
may apply a means test. The Committee received evidence from Taxpayers
Australia that this income test pulls a large number of low income people into
the tax system:
One problem that I see is that the interaction between
Centrelink and the tax system complicates everything. People are required to
lodge returns because of their Centrelink benefits yet they are well below the
tax threshold.[95]
Every time that we get something like a childcare tax offset
it increases the complexity of returns and it means that those people under
$20,000 are firmly entrenched, because the only way that they can recover it is
to lodge a tax return.[96]
3.133
The other way in which government payments complicate the tax system is
through tax offsets and credits. In 2005-06, these amounted to $16 billion
for individual taxpayers, out of total net tax payable for this group of $108.7
billion.[97] Examples of the policy
areas are private health insurance, seniors, low income, spouses, and medical
expenses. Non-personal taxpayers are also entitled to tax offsets and credits.
One example is the research and development tax offset.
3.134
Professor Evans has stated that Australia has a large number of tax
offsets and credits, particularly in comparison with New Zealand, which has low
rates of mandatory lodgement of tax returns:
… modern tax systems are often used, not merely as the
revenue collecting vehicles for which they were primarily designed, but also as
agencies for the achievement of the social and political goals for which they
were not designed. This inevitably causes greater complexity than would
otherwise be the case. New Zealand has not escaped this ‘modern’ trend, but it
is less prevalent than is the case with Australia … there is less evidence of
the tax offsets, rebates and all manner of other tax expenditures designed to
deliver political or social advantage to particular groups that characterise
the Australian tax system.[98]
3.135
In its submission, CPA Australia noted the complexity these arrangements
impose on taxpayers. It suggested that the Government review its strategy of
using the tax system as a delivery vehicle for these payments and benefits.[99]
3.136
In its Rethinking Regulation report, the Regulation Taskforce
listed a number of design principles for tax legislation. One of these was that
direct expenditure, rather than adjusting tax rates, should be used to achieve
policy objectives. The Taskforce explained its reasoning as follows:
Tax is a relatively blunt instrument and is often less efficient
in achieving equity objectives than direct expenditures and grants. For
example, individual taxable income can be a crude method of identifying taxpayer
need, as there are many low-income taxpayers in high-income households. On the
other hand, the social security system and payment of grants can use broader
eligibility criteria than taxable income, such as family income and assets, to
better target those in need.
The tax system is only likely to be preferable when seeking
to achieve relatively broad equity outcomes (for example, the use of
progressive marginal income tax rates).[100]
3.137
The Committee supports these arguments. Another reason put forward for
these changes is that most of these benefits are effectively payments. If they
are payments, they should be paid under an appropriation Act. The Committee
accepts that there are transparency measures in place for revenue measures such
as the budget papers and the ATO’s taxation statistics. Revenue measures also
usually have a legislative base. However, if an arrangement is essentially a
payment made under certain circumstances, then it may be preferable for it to
be managed as a special appropriation.
3.138
The final reason why the Committee supports extracting benefits and
offsets from the tax system is that, for many of these items, Centrelink
already has this role. Using the tax system to deliver them raises questions of
duplication.
3.139
The Committee accepts that there are a number of reasons why governments
have used the tax system to deliver these benefits and offsets. Firstly, the ATO holds reasonably accurate information about taxpayers’ incomes. It is administratively
efficient to use this information when verifying income amounts for applying a
means test. Further, the Government can administer many different benefits and offsets
from one location. In other words, the ATO has become a ‘one
stop shop’ for government benefits.
3.140
The price of these efficiencies, however, has been to shift considerable
costs on to tax agents. The Committee is concerned that governments have taken
these decisions with reference only to their own costs and benefits, without
considering the impact on tax agents. The Committee reiterates the earlier
point that successive governments and parliaments have not taken responsibility
for the tax system overall. Rather, they have made decisions on what best suits
them and allowed the compliance burden in the community to grow. The profession
of tax agent has become less attractive and is attracting fewer entrants. Australia’s
Future Tax System needs to take these issues into account.
3.141
A matter incidental to reducing the number of taxpayers who need to
lodge returns is the future of the tax agent industry. During the inquiry, the
National Institute of Accountants supported reducing the number of taxpayers
required to lodge returns. However, the Institute also suggested that, if this
occurred, there should be a structural adjustment package to compensate tax
agents for the reduced business.[101]
3.142
The Committee recognises this argument. Successive governments have
created the tax agent industry by making their services tax deductible and
creating a tax system that requires them. The other view is that tax agents
would be well placed to adapt to such a change due to their education and
commercial experience.
3.143
On balance, any such structural adjustment would depend on how demand
changes for tax agent services, and this depends on how many taxpayers are no
longer required to lodge returns. At this stage, it would be sufficient for Australia’s
Future Tax System to recognise this issue.
Recommendation 7
|
3.144
|
In the discussion paper for the review, Australia’s Future
Tax System, Treasury and the review panel include the topic of reducing
the number of taxpayers who need to lodge a return, and simplifying the
experience for those who need to lodge, in particular:
n the
costs and benefits of making work related expenses deductible
n whether
tax offsets, rebates and benefits should be delivered as direct payments,
rather than tax measures
n examining
the number of tax rates and the tax free threshold
n improving
the coverage and accuracy of the withholding system
n whether,
if large numbers of taxpayers were no longer required to lodge returns, it
would be appropriate to provide structural adjustment assistance to tax agents.
|
Harmonising with New Zealand’s simpler business tax system
3.145
In evidence, the Taxation Institute of Australia advised the Committee
of the different rationales behind the Australian and New Zealand fringe benefits tax systems. In New Zealand, the tax is aimed at the areas
likely to generate the most revenue. These include motor vehicles, low interest
loans, free or subsidised goods and services, and employer contributions to
sickness funds, insurance and superannuation schemes. The Australian approach
is to have a global tax and then to make a number of exemptions or ‘carve-outs’
from this. In practice, the Australian approach is more complicated and imposes
more compliance costs.[102]
3.146
A similar outcome occurred with the GST. Australia based its legislation
on the New Zealand model but included a much greater number of exceptions. In
2001, the relevant New Zealand legislation totalled 200 pages, but its
Australian equivalent ran to 800. This increased volume of legislation
increased complexity.[103]
3.147
Data on compliance costs suggests that New Zealand has more success than
Australia in managing tax complexity. In an OECD comparison of tax systems,
the New Zealand authorities overall spent $0.81 to collect $100 of revenue. In Australia, the cost was $1.05.[104] PricewaterhouseCoopers
and the World Bank published some compliance indices for national tax systems
(a lower score indicating reduced compliance costs). It gave Australia an index of 107 and New Zealand an index of 70 for hours per year compliance
time. New Zealand performed significantly better in relation to GST and company
tax.[105]
3.148
The Committee believes that there are a number of benefits to examining
whether to harmonise aspects of Australia’s tax system with New Zealand’s. Firstly, there is the potential to reduce compliance costs. Secondly, it
will help foster trade between the two countries. Thirdly, it may encourage the
development of uniform business taxes in the South Pacific more generally.
Although the GST has been excluded from Australia’s Future Tax System,
other taxes could be harmonised with New Zealand’s. These points should be
raised in the review’s discussion paper.
Recommendation 8
|
3.149
|
The discussion paper for the review, Australia’s Future Tax
System, consider the benefits of harmonising with New Zealand’s tax system, even if just for particular taxes like fringe benefits tax, or
for particular classes of tax.
|
3.150
At the very minimum, it should be possible for the Australian and New
Zealand Governments to arrange for their Treasuries and tax authorities to
exchange staff so that both countries may benefit from each others’ experiences
in tax law and administration.
Conclusion
3.151
Among developed economies, Australia’s tax system is one of the most
complex. This has occurred because each set of interest groups have approached
the tax system from their own particular perspective, instead of viewing it as
a way of efficiently collecting revenue. Tax advisors have sought to minimise
their clients’ liabilities and the judiciary have applied established legal
definitions from other parts of the law to it. Parliaments have sought to
implement spending programs through the tax system and introduced stop-gap
approaches as remedial measures.
3.152
While political expediency affects policy decisions, a global
perspective would have been more appropriate. The need to take a global view is
why many tasks are placed with the public sector. The ATO has responsibility
for tax measures that operate in a similar way to the social spending programs
that Centrelink is specifically designed to administer. This raises questions
of duplication and inefficiency. It has also transferred much of the compliance
work to tax agents and taxpayers.
3.153
Another problem with this approach is that Australia has a system of self
assessment. Taxpayers accept a certain amount of risk that the ATO may amend their assessments and apply interest and penalties at a later point. A complex
system increases the chance of taxpayer error and increases taxpayer risk. The
tax system’s complexity undermines its own integrity.
3.154
In An Assessment of Tax, the JCPA recommended a wide ranging tax
review to develop widely agreed policies on tax, which would then form the
foundation for tax simplification. Without articulating clear policies, tax simplification
is very difficult. The Government’s review, Australia’s Future Tax System,
could be the type of review that the JCPA called for in 1993. It could be the
most important development in tax simplification.
3.155
Regardless of the outcome of Australia’s Future Tax System, the
tax system will be subject to change in the years ahead. Therefore, the
Committee has made a number of recommendations to improve the development of
tax policy and legislation. Again following An Assessment of Tax,
perhaps the most important of these is to improve consultations on specific
measures. This includes government consulting before the announcement of the
policy intent and increasing the proportion of consultations that are conducted
publicly. These changes should help reduce the amount of stop gap measures and
help stop the vicious circle of amendment and taxpayer reaction.