Chapter 2 Monetary policy and other issues
Overview
2.1
The outlook for the Australian economy remains optimistic. The economy continues
to perform well compared with other advanced nations. The strength of the
current growth surge is expected to be sufficient to enable Australia to absorb
the effects of both the catastrophic flooding across much of Eastern Australia
and Cyclone Yasi without economy-wide difficulties.
2.2
The RBA calculates that the extreme weather conditions will reduce real
GDP growth considerably in the December quarter of 2010 and the March quarter
of 2011. The bank estimates that this will cut a full percentage point from its
November 2010 forecast for real GDP by the end of the March quarter.
2.3
The stimulus of rebuilding homes, businesses and infrastructure damaged
by either the widespread flooding or Cyclone Yasi is anticipated to contribute
to a temporary rise in CPI inflation (probably to 3 per cent) for the
forthcoming June quarter. The bank believes that this inflationary pressure will
recede in the second half of 2011 and expire by the end of the year.
2.4
The RBA does not think that the extreme weather will disrupt Australia’s
long-running expansion or that the effects on prices constitute an obstacle to
achieving the inflation target over the medium term, provided that the wider community
understands that the effects on prices are purely temporary.
2.5
There are indications that global economic growth will be strong. The IMF
forecast that global GDP probably grew by 5 per cent in 2010 and would grow by
4.4 per cent in 2011. China and India continue to grow strongly, while the rate
of growth in the United States appears to have picked up. Conditions vary
widely across Europe.
2.6
There has been a surge on global commodity prices across a range of
goods – food, fuel, minerals and metals alike. In several countries these
rises, especially in food, have caused a rise in the rate of consumer price
inflation.
2.7
The medium-term outlook for Australia remains consistent with the RBA’s
analyses and forecasts for some time, that is, Australia continues to benefit
from a terms of trade event of considerable significance, a once or twice in a
century event. This has been balanced by the emergence of a new trend of
greater caution regarding debt and enhanced rates of savings and debt repayment
by the household sector. The increased caution of householders has placed the
retail sector under distinct pressure, but the macroeconomic effect from restrained
consumption at this time has been to preserve the economy from possible instability.
The increased caution of householders may even prove salutary, as it adds a
degree of resilience to household finances, should future developments prove
unfavourable.
2.8
At its February meeting the board of the RBA decided that despite substantial
impacts in the short term, it was nonetheless best that monetary policy not
respond to either the expected stimulus from rebuilding or the expected price
effects.
2.9
For its part, the RBA remains committed to the same framework for monetary
policy that it has followed for the past two decades, keeping the growth of
demand sustainable, so as to achieve an average underlying inflation rate of
between 2 and 3 per cent.
Forecasts for the economy
2.10
Forecasts for the economy were published in the Statement on Monetary
Policy on 4 February 2011. These were soon complicated by Cyclone Yasi. During
the hearing the Governor advised that:
We had a stab at setting out some
estimates in the Statement on Monetary Policy released the other day.
That was finalised after we had seen the flooding in Central Queensland in
December and more coastal flooding in January but before Cyclone Yasi had made
landfall, so we could not assess that. I should emphasise that all these
estimates are preliminary and there is inevitably going to be a great deal of
uncertainty around them. I think that will remain the case for some months.[1]
2.11
These initial forecasts are available in Table 2.1. Growth for both the
December quarter of 2010 in particular and for 2010 as a whole is likely to
have been weaker than was previously expected. Retail spending has been subdued
and coal production started to fall as a result of the flooding. Growth is
expected to recover, as coal production returns to normal and as both households
and firms replace damaged goods and capital equipment. Rebuilding, repairs and
restoration work will all boost spending, though the effect of this will be
spread across several years. GDP is expected to be back close to pre-flood
levels by the June quarter. GDP is expected to grow by around 4¼ per cent over
2011. There is likely to be considerable variation across industries; the
mining industry is expected to experience the strongest growth. [2]
Table 2.1 RBA Output and Inflation Forecasts (a)
Per
cent, over year to quarter shown
|
|
June
2010 |
Dec
2010 |
June
2011 |
Dec
2011 |
June
2012 |
Dec
2012 |
June
2013 |
GDP |
|
3.1 |
2¾ |
3¼ |
4¼ |
3¾ |
4 |
4 |
Non-farm GDP |
|
3.2 |
2½ |
3¼ |
4¼ |
3¾ |
4 |
4 |
CPI |
|
3.1 |
2.7 |
2½ |
3 |
2¾ |
3 |
3 |
Underlying inflation |
|
2¾ |
2¼ |
2¼ |
2¾ |
2¾ |
3 |
3 |
Source Reserve
Bank of Australia, Statement on Monetary Policy, February 2011, p. 60.
(a) Technical
assumptions include A$ at US$1.00, TWI at 74, and WTI crude oil price at US$96
per barrel and Tapis crude oil price at US$103 per barrel. Sources: ABS; RBA
2.12
At the 11 February hearing the Governor reported that the CPI forecast
in the most recent Statement on Monetary Policy needed revision on
account of the expected effects of Cyclone Yasi, which would compound the
effects of the earlier mass flooding. The Governor stated:
The result of that is likely to be
a temporary rise in CPI inflation to probably around three per cent, we think,
for the June quarter. That is a higher figure than was in the statement we
released the other day because we have now factored in an effect from the
cyclone that was not in that forecast. The combined contributions to that three
per cent number of all the summer flood events and the cyclone is probably half
a percentage point or maybe even slightly more. These effects should begin to
reverse in the second half of the year and should be largely gone by the end of
the year, we think. [3]
2.13
Figure 2.1 below compares the initial, pre-Yasi, forecast for CPI
inflation and the revised forecast, as advised at the hearing. The Governor did
not advise the committee of a precise figure for the slump in real GDP for the
December quarter of 2010 itself, though he did indicate that by the March
quarter the figure could be a full percentage point lower than the figure cited
at the last hearing, which was in November 2010.
Figure 2.1: RBA CPI Inflation Forecasts, pre and post Yasi
Per cent, over year to
quarter shown
|
Source Reserve
Bank of Australia, Statement on Monetary Policy, February 2011, p. 60 and Mr
Glenn Stevens, Governor of the RBA, Transcript, 11 February 2011, p.4 |
2.14
The Governor explained the forecasts thus:
...the estimates we put together
suggest that real GDP will be noticeably lower than it would have been in the
absence of these events in the December and, particularly, the March quarters.
By the March quarter, we think it could be about a percentage point lower than
the forecast we had when we were last here. As to the reasons for those
effects, it is...mainly because the economy’s capacity to supply goods and
services, particularly certain commodities, has been seriously disrupted. It is
likely that the bulk of those supply losses will be recovered in the June
quarter as production, particularly in coal mining, which is a very big swing factor
here, resumes. Nevertheless, for many businesses there has been a period of
lost income and the reduction in the level of GDP on average for the year of
about half a per cent—this is the number that the government quoted and we have
roughly the same figure...[4]
2.15
The bank’s forecasts for the global economy were not affected by the
weather disturbances in Australia, though the disruption to coal production was
of global significance. In the Statement on Monetary Policy the bank
advises that it expects that the world economy would expand over the next
couple of years just above the annual trend of 4¼ per cent. Strong growth is
expected in China and India, with steady growth elsewhere in Asia, with the
exception of Japan, where growth is expected to be slower than in 2010. The
United States and the euro area are expected to recover at a moderate pace in
the United States and in the euro area as a whole. The advanced economies will
maintain ‘considerable excess capacity...in contrast to most emerging
economies’, while uncertainties concerning the sovereign debt problems in
Europe and the response to these in much of Asia will endure.[5]
2.16
The bank expects that global growth will have a positive impact on
Australia. Commodity prices have increased since the November hearing of the
committee. Spot prices for coking and thermal coal have also increased, due in
part to significant disruptions in supply as a result of the Queensland floods
and unseasonably cold weather in the Northern Hemisphere. Demand from China and
tight global supply has exerted upward pressure on iron ore spot prices. Global
food prices have also started to increase significantly over recent months. The
combined impact of these has meant a further upward revision to forecasts
concerning Australia’s terms of trade over the near-term.[6]
2.17
The bank expects that the economic consequences of Cyclone Yasi are
likely to be temporary. While the cyclone has done major damage to some crops,
the bank has received intelligence that indicates that the overall damage may
not be as extensive as that of Cyclone Larry five years ago and that the rate
of recovery may be higher. Despite this, there has been a substantial impact,
with a large rise in the prices of some crops already taking place. This
compounds the price increases resulting from the earlier floods.[7]
2.18
The overall situation remains essentially positive. As the Governor
observed:
...to take the broader picture,
underlying inflation has fallen substantially from its peak in 2008. It needed
to, but it has. And I think it is worth recording that, on the latest numbers
we have, we have an unemployment rate of five per cent and an inflation rate clearly
in the twos, which is where we want it to be. That combination, when you go
back and look at recent decades, actually is a pretty favourable one compared
to many that we have had.[8]
Inflation
2.19
The Governor counselled that the medium-term inflation outlook is
largely unchanged and the RBA expects that things will remain as expected for
the forthcoming two years. The near-term picture is a little lower, because of
the history behind the low figure achieved, while the CPI is higher as a result
of the floods, which is a temporary effect.
Essentially, the ‘policy is about right’.[9]
2.20
The Governor warned the committee about the
significance of expectations about inflation:
The assumption we are making...is
that people’s expectations of the permanent inflation rate do not go up. I do
not think they will actually. We have seen these sorts of things before. People
understand that. People correctly sense that prices of fruit and vegetables and
so on are going to go higher for a while. The damaging thing would be if they
took that to mean that inflation everywhere is going to stay high permanently.
Then we have got a problem, because it is not so easy then to say that monetary
policy should not respond to that. It would have to if that turned out to be
the problem.[10]
2.21
At present the RBA is confident that the experience of Cyclone Larry will
be repeated; that the public will not develop long-term expectations of
inflation on the basis of a temporary spike in the price of fruit and
vegetables.[11]
2.22
Continuing a line of inquiry from the previous hearing, the committee
referred to comments that the Governor had made about the price increases in
utilities being linked to underinvestment and asked him what is going to retrieve
the situation. The Governor denied any great expertise in water and
electricity, but emphasised that producers ‘need to be able to get a price for
their product which covers their capital costs and returns’ and that ‘I do not
think we will get an efficient allocation or usage of those things if we do not
price them right.’[12] Dr Lowe explained the precise causes of the
price increases:
The major price increases that we
are experiencing at the moment for electricity are not coming about because of
higher generation costs. They are coming about because of the investment in the
distribution network...demand for electricity has grown but the spikiness of
electricity demand has grown as more and more people have got air conditioning.
We have not built enough transmission infrastructure to deal with those spikes.
So the electricity authorities are having to spend a huge amount of money
building the transmission or rebuilding and repairing and expanding the
transmission network. We have not seen, at least to date, large increases in
utility prices come primarily from generation costs. In time I think we will,
but at the moment it is really about the networking, the distribution expansion
that is going on.[13]
Queensland and capacity constraints
2.23
The committee sought the Governor’s advice about the impact that the
floods in Queensland, plus Cyclone Yasi, would have on the economy, in
particular what pressures they would add to emerging capacity constraints. The
Governor stated that he expected that the rebuilding would
slow down alternative areas of spending, while the construction of new
dwellings would utilise existing spare capacity, of which there was plenty in
South-East Queensland.[14]
2.24
The bank believes that the damage inflicted by the extreme weather
conditions needs to be understood within the context of the size of the economy
as a whole. Dr Lowe referred to the most recent edition of the Statement
of Monetary Policy in which the RBA forecast an additional $8 billion
of spending for repairs and infrastructure rebuilding and counselled that this
figure contrasts with one of $1.4 trillion for the entire economy.[15]
Global economy
2.25
The Governor advised that the global economy appears to be stronger than
when he last testified before the committee, that China and India continue to
expand at a strong rate and the United States appears to have increased its
rate of growth. However, problems remain: conditions across Europe are varied
and the relationship between sovereign and bank creditworthiness has not been
resolved.[16]
2.26
The Governor noted that the IMF now estimates that world GDP growth was
about five per cent in 2010. This exceeds the 30-year average. The IMF
forecasts global growth of 4.4 per cent in 2011. This is significantly above
the average pace of growth. In addition, global commodity prices such as metals,
minerals, energy and food have all risen. Inflation is likely to become a major
issue in international economic policy.[17]
2.27
The recent surge in global coal prices was, at least partially, a
reflection of Australia’s significance as an exporter; the recent floods in
Queensland appear to have reduced national production by about 15 per cent, and
that has a material impact on the global supply of traded coal. The price of
iron ore has risen above the highs of 2008, though in this case the principal driver
was strong demand.[18]
2.28
The net result of all this is that Australia’s terms of trade are higher
than previously assumed and the RBA expects that they will peak both higher and
later than was previously expected. Capacity in the production of iron ore,
natural gas and coal is scheduled to expand in the near-term. A number of new
proposed projects (especially in the natural gas sector) have received
permission to proceed.[19]
2.29
The Governor confirmed that Australia is ‘experiencing a terms of trade
event of a very large size, of the type that happens only once or twice in a
century’. The key task for policy makers is to avoid the instability that has typically
accompanied such episodes before.[20]
2.30
In discussion with the committee about the global economy, the Governor teased
out a key question: ‘how does Australian monetary policy handle something that
has a global origin?’ The Governor answered this by stating that:
... as a country that in the long
run has an independent monetary policy with its own currency and a floating
exchange rate, we are able to generally chart our long-run destiny ourselves
but, of course, we have to let the exchange rate move to do that...We have our
own currency area, our own monetary policy and our own inflation target. It
makes it harder to contain inflation when you are getting these global shocks...but
we do a lot better than we would otherwise by allowing our currency to go up if
it wants to and keeping the focus on controlling inflation over the medium
term...It is not perfect but it is the best model there is that I know of.[21]
Exchange rate
2.31
The Governor notified the committee that the exchange rate is very high,
indeed is now ‘at a peak level for the floating era, since 1983’.[22]
Given the terms of trade, this is unsurprising, but, the Governor warned that,
‘it is exerting a dampening pressure on the traded sector of the economy
outside the resource sector.’[23]
2.32
The committee asked about the underlying philosophy of the RBA’s foreign
exchange transactions. The Governor replied that the philosophy is to intervene
only in moments of exchange rate extremes or in very disorderly markets. Such
conditions are not common and once they are over the RBA seeks to return the
reserve balance to normal. According to the Governor, ‘we are not frequent
interveners and we are not fine-tuners of the exchange rate, but if we think
that there is a significant misalignment and disorderly markets we are prepared
to act quite aggressively on those occasions’.[24]
Multispeed economy
2.33
The committee was concerned about the existence of a multispeed economy
and the differential impact of interest rates on the various areas of the
economy, some of which were not faring as well as the mining sector. The
committee asked the Governor if interest rates were a blunt policy instrument
on an economy-wide basis. The Governor agreed that they were, but advised that there
were ‘not very many sharp instruments of macroeconomic policy...when you think
about it.’[25] In addition, monetary
policy is inevitably developed with regard to the economy-wide average. There
is no alternative to this.
2.34
The Governor acknowledged the reality of varying levels of advantage and
disadvantage by region and industry, but asserted that:
If we want to address regional
differences or industry differences it has to be other policies that do that,
and they are going to be in the preserve of governments in terms of spending measures...It
is going to be important though...that those sorts of measures have a strong
focus on helping people adjust rather than trying to prevent adjustment,
because we are not going to be able to prevent at least some adjustment in the
structure of the economy...Those instruments of course are not in our
hands—they are in the parliament’s hands, really.[26]
2.35
The committee proposed a hypothetical situation in which the states maintained
their own monetary policies and reseve banks. The Governor acknowledged that
this was an issue and referred to a speech that he had given in Shepparton on
the subject.[27] The Governor then maintained
that the underlying issue was not really a conflict of interest between
different states at all:
But the essence of the problem is
that it is not just Queensland versus other bits of Australia. It is bits of
Queensland versus other bits of Queensland, and ditto in Western Australia...[28]
2.36
The Governor reassured the committee that he was aware of the disparate
distributional effects of changes to the cash rate and interest rates and that
he receives substantial communications directly from Australians on this matter.[29]
Capex and other stimuli
2.37
The committee noted that private sector capex (capital expenditure) is
forecast to be around $780 billion and that this is the largest capital
expenditure the Australian economy has experienced for some time. The committee
asked the Governor if the RBA would have to manage the combined effects of state,
public and private sector spending by raising interest rates. The Governor advised
that the fiscal stimulus from the federal government was easing and that:
The announced plans for federal
fiscal policy are that the stimuluses that were put in place as a result of the
decisions back in late 2008 and early 2009 have come through and are now
tailing off, so, strictly speaking, I think the fiscal impacts as
conventionally measured would be going negative in the current fiscal year or,
if not, very soon.[30]
2.38
When the committee sought to explore a possible link between previous
interest rate rises and the federal fiscal stimulus of recent years, the
Governor stated that:
What they are tied to is that we
had a very expansionary setting of monetary policy, the lowest cash rate in 50
years, to meet what was at that time perceived—and I think rightly—as a huge
threat given the global situation, and then the worst did not come to pass. We
had a modest downturn. We were into recovery quite quickly. And we said, ‘Well,
monetary policy should go back to normal once the economy is clearly on its way
back to normal,’ which it was, so we normalised. And now, of course, we are a
little bit on the tight side of normal, looking forward to the forces that we
think are already building up. Demand turned out to be, in the private sector,
stronger than we had feared it would. We feared it would be weaker.[31]
2.39
The Governor advised that the eventual result of this approach was an
incredibly good one. During further discussion on interest rates the Governor
analysed comments by the committee and teased out the question: ‘would rates
have been lower if the fiscal policy had been tighter?’ The Governor responded
by stating that this question had been asked many times before and that the
answer was that they would have been lower, but that this would not necessarily
have been a better outcome.[32]
Household debt
2.40
The Governor reported that the ratio of household debt to income
appeared to have stopped rising, after having risen for about 20 years.[33]
A similar trend is apparent in a number of other countries. The Governor stated
that Australians have the good fortune to consolidate their finances while incomes
are rising (largely due to the terms of trade). This is not the case with many
other countries.
2.41
The committee sought advice from the Governor on how Australia sits with
respect to household debt and interest payments against disposable income,
especially compared with households in America, Canada and the United Kingdom.
The Governor explained that twenty years ago the debt to income ratio in
Australia was low by the standards of developed countries and that now it is
high. The Governor stated that there were reasons ‘why we should not always
assume that really low rates are good, because that is one of the things that
can prompt people to build up much more debt than maybe they really should’.[34]
In addition, he noted that in some peoples’ view it was precisely the
accessibility of cheap money that prompted so many American households to get
into trouble.[35]
2.42
Asked about how the costs of servicing debt in Australia compared to other
countries, the Governor replied that:
Our interest rates are relatively
normal, whereas in a number of other countries their cash rates are certainly
extremely low. Their actual borrowing rates are not as low because the long
rates drive the borrowing rates. We have rates of servicing costs that have
gone up materially in a trend sense over time, reflecting the amount of debt people have taken on.[36]
2.43
The Governor also reported that there was a trend towards greater
caution concerning household debt in Australia. He noted that the rate of
saving out of current income has risen for several years past, though he warned
that the measurement of saving is not necessarily an entirely accurate figure,
‘being the residual between two very large aggregates’.[37]
Yet it would appear that Australians are increasingly seeking to reduce their
debts.
2.44
The committee was anxious to clarify why Australian patterns of debt
were changing. The Governor advised that Australians may have become more
cautious as a result of the experience of debtors in other economies. The
Governor suggested that ‘in the long run we might be
moving to a structure of household finances and saving that is a lot more
robust to adverse shocks to income, which one day will hit us from somewhere.’[38] The Governor was at pains to explain that he was not describing any
fully-developed hypotheses, but was simply giving his impressions. He explained
that data was only available for recent years.
2.45
Dr Lowe advised that the use of credit cards has slowed down, while the
rate of payments on housing loans has sped up. He also noted that various
consumer surveys have exposed changing attitudes to spending and buying. This
is consistent with increases in bank deposits. According to Dr Lowe there is
sufficient circumstantial evidence to conclude ‘that there is something
fundamental going on’.[39]
It is unclear, however, if this trend will continue.
2.46
The committee asked the Governor if the RBA had a preferred level
of savings or a preferred attitude to debt. The Governor expressed his
reluctance to identify a specific target for savings, explaining that for a
while the rate of saving was so low that the ABS (which takes depreciation into
account) calculated that it was actually negative and that:
...we were collectively saving
nothing out of the current income. We were gearing up balance sheets to own
houses, basically, and spending all of our current income. Historically, that
is very unusual.[40]
2.47
The Governor elaborated by stating that he did not believe that debt was
inevitably a bad thing, but that the volume of debt accrued by Australians was
quite high and that a disproportionate part of it was accrued by high income earners,
rather than low income earners. The rate of saving out of current income is at 9
or 10 per cent. The Governor thought that this was not necessarily optimal, but
is nonetheless closer to where the bank would expect it to be over the long run
and certainly preferable to a rate of zero savings.[41]
Cash rate
2.48
The committee asked the Governor whether interest rates were on hold for
the foreseeable future. The Governor replied by asking, rhetorically, ‘how long
is the foreseeable future; how long is a piece of string?’[42]
The Governor insisted that the RBA did not anticipate any change in the cash
rate for some time. However, circumstances may well change, requiring changes to
interest rates.
2.49
The committee was interested if there were any arguments for
easing rates, given the RBA’s inflation forecast and the Governor’s statement
about interest rates being a bit above average. The Governor explained that:
I think it is about right for them
to be where they are, given that we have a once-in-a-century terms of trade
event that is very expansionary and all the things that flow from that. It
would be surprising if you did not have to have policy a bit on the tight side
of normal in that event, taking account of the fact that the exchange rate is
doing a fair bit of work for us. I think there would only be an argument for an
easing if that strength looked like it was significantly dissipating or if we
had some other very important piece of news that was quite view changing.
2.50
The committee sought the Governor’s comments on the spread between the
RBA cash rate and the variable mortgage rate, since the 10-year average was
around 180 and is now about 300. The Governor explained that:
We are talking about a rise of a
hundred points or a little more, give or take, depending on which exact product
you are talking about over the three years since about the middle of 2007. That
reflects the fact that the market funding costs across a range of sources have
moved up materially compared to the overnight cash rate, which is why the
overnight cash rate is considerably lower today than it would normally have
been in these sorts of circumstances. It is to take account of that difference.
I think we have said that pretty clearly many times.[43]
Labour market and wages
2.51
The committee wished to determine if the relationship between vacancies
and unemployment was deteriorating or improving. The Governor stated that:
The vacancy rate as a share of the
labour force is on the way up...One might say as a result of all that that we
are pretty close to full employment. At one level that is good, isn’t it? We
are supposed to try to have full employment. We do not want to be over full, so
we do not want to have serious pressure on wages and inflation. We do not want
to have serious skill mismatch, which might be another issue to talk about. [44]
2.52
The Governor also advised that the RBA liaison indicates that while the
labour market in the resource sector was tightening up ‘employers are not
really finding serious problems just yet’.[45] Dr Lowe confirmed this, stating
that ‘when we talk to firms we are not detecting that
they are having to compete incredibly aggressively to get workers to fill those
jobs...firms do not seem to be saying that it is particularly hard to find
workers at the moment.’ [46]
2.53
The committee also sought to find out about wage pressures, especially
in the resources sector. The Governor stated:
There is pressure on wages there.
You would expect that... I do not think it is especially worrying in itself.
The macro question really is: does that engender pressure right across the
economy in due course that is too great or not? At the moment, I think we are
travelling okay.[47]
2.54
The committee also inquired about the possibility of a wages break out
as a result of changes to industrial relations regulation. The Governor
insisted that the evidence was not yet available to give an answer to that
question and that we would only find out in the next two to three years. [48]
Bank competition
2.55
The commitee sought to take stock of banking competition, noting constituency
feedback that there appears to be less banking competition than before and that
bank priofits are at record levels. The committee explored this matter in connection
with the near doubling of the spread between the cash
rate and the standard home loan variable rate. The Governor responded that the
important indicator is the banks’ overall interest margins, because the
long-run story is that while they were 500 points in the early nineties, they
are now between 2¼ and 2½ per cent. According to the Governor, ‘the long-run
big story is that those margins are actually much skinnier today than they were
historically.’[49]
2.56
The Governor elaborated, stating that the change was a consequence of more
transparent pricing and the reduction in banks’ costs. The Governor went on to
note that while bank competition in the mortgage market is not as intense as it
was two or three years ago, there remains a great deal of competition in the
banking sector. This competition is most evident when it comes to raising money
in deposits. When funding was readily available in the past, there was pressure
to lend. One result of global developments is a greater degree of competition
from banks competing with other banks for deposits. Essentially the locus of
competition has shifted from lending activity to attracting deposits. [50]
2.57
This advice was endorsed by Mr Battellino, who pointed out that there
are all sorts of other factors affecting cost of funds to banks. According to
Mr Battellino, the key point is that net interest margins have not really
changed in five or six years: the banks move their lending rates in line with
their cost of funds. [51]
2.58
Committee members stated that they had difficulty in reconciling lower volumes
of commercial activity with record bank profits. Mr Battellino responded by explaining
that one ‘cannot look at things in terms of dollars because everything is
rising in dollar terms’ and that the return on equity of banks is actually
lower than it was several years ago.[52]
Conclusions
2.59
Australia continues to have good reasons for considering itself ‘the
lucky country’. Despite the significant, unquantifiable, human costs of the recent
natural disasters, the material costs are readily manageable, given the size of
the economy and the vigour and duration of the various drivers of growth.
2.60
Australia continues to benefit from exceptional terms of trade, the
likes of which we appear to experience once or twice in a century. While we
must be cautious about the development of capacity constraints and other
possible inflationary pressures, at this stage there is no pressing need for
concern.
2.61
Monetary policy remains on track to meet the goals of its long-standing
policy of maintaining inflation within the 2 to 3 per cent band over the
medium-term.
2.62
The next public hearing is scheduled for 26 August 2011 in Canberra.
Craig
Thomson MP
Chair
23
March 2010