Chapter 2 Monetary policy and other issues
Overview
2.1
The current upward trend in inflation has prompted the Reserve Bank of
Australia (RBA) to increase the official cash rate to 7.25 ‑ up 75 basis
points since the former committee met with the Bank in August 2007. The RBA has
now increased the cash rate 12 times since 2001; with a total of a 100 basis point increase from 8 August 2007. The April 2008 hearing, therefore, provided
a timely opportunity to scrutinise the RBA’s conduct of monetary policy.
2.2
The year 2007 was yet another strong year for the Australian economy, with growth of more than 4 per cent over the year to the December quarter. In
particular, domestic demand expanded by 5.5 per cent ‘well in excess of the
trend growth in the economy’s productive capacity.’[1]
The rate of unemployment declined further, to record its lowest level since the
mid-1970s.[2]
2.3
The Governor noted that ‘indicators of capacity utilisation reached
their highest levels for two decades’, resulting in challenges for expanding
operations due to shortages of suitable staff.
[3]
2.4
In contrast to increasing capacity constraints, the RBA noted that the
‘deterioration in financial market sentiment has been associated with a
weakening in the outlook for global economic growth.’[4]
The US has posted only moderate growth with many observers forecasting a
recession. Growth in the Euro area also appears to be moderating although not to the same extent as in the US. Japan’s economy is also weakening, yet in other
parts of Asia economic conditions remain solid.[5]
2.5
The Governor noted that demand growth ‘well and truly exceeded any
plausible estimate of the rate of growth of the economy’s supply potential’ causing inflation to increase.[6] Mr Stevens reported that the
year end Consumer Price Index (CPI) was 3 per cent, but was expected to rise.
The March quarter CPI, released after the hearing, showed that both the
headline and underlying rates of inflation had increased to 4.2 per cent. [7]
2.6
Domestic capital spending was pronounced in the resources sector, but robust
growth has not been confined to this sector. Public financial spending rose in response to demand for upgrades to infrastructure, rising at twice its trend
over 2007.[8] In addition, the Governor
noted that consumer demand rose at a pace well above average, ‘fed by a rate of
growth of real household disposable income as high as anything seen in the past
20 years.’[9]
2.7
Indicators of domestic performance have largely remained strong over
early 2008. Demand growth, however, is in the process of moderating and credit
demand for households is weakening. The RBA explained that the businesses they
survey are experiencing tightened financial conditions, lower share prices and
heightened concerns over global finance.[10] Mr Stevens noted that
while there is evidence of a slowing in demand, ‘there remain powerful conflicting
forces at work’ which will be closely monitored.[11]
Forecasts for 2007-2008
2.8
The US economy showed ‘only modest growth in the December quarter, and
most observers have revised down their expectations for 2008’[12];
while ‘growth in the euro area and Japan is also slowing.’[13]
2.9
Growth in the domestic economy remains strong. The latest national accounts show growth of more than 4 per cent over the year to the December quarter in the
Australian economy, with domestic demand expanding by 5.5 per cent.’[14]
2.10
The RBA reported that ‘global commodity prices have generally stayed high in the recent period, and this continues to boost incomes and spending in Australia.’[15]
The RBA noted that ‘based on these developments, the prospects are that Australia’s terms of trade will rise further this year, after the sharp increases already seen over the past four years.’[16]
2.11
The CPI rose by 1.3 per cent in the 2008 March quarter,
lifting the year-ended rate to 4.2 per cent. The RBA’s measure of underlying
inflation seeks to remove temporary influences from the data. Underlying
inflation increased by 1.2 per cent in the March quarter taking the year
ended rate to 4.2 per cent - identical to the year ended CPI.
2.12
In relation to monetary policy, the RBA board is of the view that
current policy settings should remain unchanged. The Governor stated that there
exists some evidence that a moderation in demand is occurring, which should, in
due course, slow price growth.[17]
2.13
Mr Stevens noted that the goal of monetary policy going forward will be
to secure a gradual reduction in inflation by restraining demand, thereby
protecting Australia’s good macroeconomic performance over the past decade and
a half, and creating an avenue for sustainable growth into the future.[18]
Inflation targeting and monetary policy
2.14
The Fourth Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy, agreed on
7 December 2007 between the Treasurer and the Governor of the Reserve
Bank, outlines the objective of monetary policy and provides an inflation
target.
2.15
The goals of monetary policy as set out in the Reserve Bank Act 1959 require
the Reserve Bank Board to conduct monetary policy in a way that, in the Board’s
opinion, will best contribute to:
n the stability of the
currency of Australia;
n the maintenance of
full employment in Australia; and
n the economic
prosperity and welfare of the people of Australia.
2.16
The Fourth Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy also states that:
In pursuing the goal of medium-term price stability, both the Reserve Bank and the Government agree on the
objective of keeping consumer price inflation between 2 and 3 per cent, on
average, over the cycle. This formulation allows for the natural short-run variation in inflation over the cycle while preserving a clearly identifiable
performance benchmark over time.[19]
2.17
The RBA in its February 2008 Statement on Monetary Policy (SMP) stated:
The inflation forecasts have been
revised upwards following the high December quarter outcome. Underlying
inflation is forecast to be around 3.5 per cent over the year to the December
quarter 2008. The forecast of a continuing high level of underlying inflation
reflects the expectation that pressures on capacity will remain for some time.
Indeed, in the near term, it is likely that the year-end rates of underlying
and headline inflation will rise somewhat from current levels, reflecting the
succession of large quarterly increases in the three last quarters.[20]
2.18
During the hearing the committee asked for the RBA’s assumptions behind recent
inflation forecasts. In forecasting an underlying inflation rate of 3.5 percent
at 2008 end, and trending down, the RBA answered that it relied on exchange
rate, oil price and cash rate movement assumptions.[21]
The Bank had factored in a cash rate of seven percent, which was the rate at
the time the forecasts were made, before the March rate rise.[22]
2.19
The Governor stated an expectation of seeing forecasts for growth and
inflation go down in the RBA’s next SMP in early May—which was the intention of
the rate rise made in March.[23]
2.20
When asked what the average inflation rate over the current cycle might
be, the Governor stated that looking back since 1993 the average has been
roughly 2.5 per cent; hence to get the same average over the coming 10 years
or so, ‘we need tight policy to put some downward pressure on inflation.’[24]
2.21
The committee further put to the Governor the question of what would
happen to the economy and interest rates if inflation was ignored. The
Governor’s response was that if inflation is not controlled ‘then ultimately
you end up with higher interest rates.’[25] Further, by keeping a
‘stable trend inflation rate, nominal interest rates cycle around a stable mean
as well.’[26] Hence it is important to
act promptly to contain inflation and preserve the nominal interest rate
structure Australia has had since the 1990s.
2.22
In relation to the ‘lag’ effect between when a decision is made on rates
and when it takes effect in the marketplace, the committee asked the Governor
what he believed to be the right time to reduce interest rates before the
economy dips. The Governor responded
that often the effects of earlier decisions are still affecting the economy,
which is why he is ‘keen to move in relatively small increments.’[27]
The current level of rates is on the high side, however, ‘when they have done
the job, they can come down.’ In particular, Mr Stevens noted that ‘we do not
wait to conclude that the job is done to the point where inflation itself has
actually gone all the way back down to the target.’[28]
2.23
The committee sought clarification on the measurement of underlying
inflation and, in particular, the use of trimmed mean and the weighted mean.
The Governor noted that both measures seek to accurately measure the ‘central tendency of the inflation rate that distils out some of the noise we can get’ and added that
‘CPIs can often be affected by large but temporary movements’, to which
monetary policy should not be responding.[29] Hence, in order to
compute the central tendency, you can and should ‘exclude certain things from
the basket on a consistent basis’.[30]
2.24
Further questions sought to clarify how many measures of inflation are
looked at, and whether this process equated to looking at CPI ex volatiles. The
Governor responded that ‘CPI ex volatiles takes out more than just food and
energy which is what is commonly done in other countries.[31]
2.25
The Governor was asked a series of questions focusing on possible
factors influencing inflationary expectations. In 2007 the Governor, as part of
a speech to the Sydney Institute, stated:
Even more important are
expectations of future inflation. When people expect prices to rise rapidly,
they bring forward purchases, put up their own prices, demand higher wages and
so on. That helps to create the very inflation they expect.[32]
2.26
The Governor responded that outcomes play a role, and what is currently
needed is for the RBA to have a ‘credible story…as to why inflation…is going to
come down.’[33] Secondly, he stated that
over the long run a monetary policy framework is required which
(a) has a demonstrated track
record and (b) has a measure of public confidence that the central bank is serious about containing inflation.[34]
2.27
In response to the latter question of inflationary expectations and
monetary policy, the Governor reiterated that high expectations do make it
harder to bring inflation down, however, the impact these should have on
interest rates is not always clear cut. He added that what is generally required is to manage these expectations, which the RBA is currently trying to do.[35]
2.28
In relation to concerns that inflation may be ‘out of control’, Mr Stevens stated:
…what we have said is inflation
has risen and that is a problem. It has to be dealt with and we are dealing with it. We will contain it and it will come down. Is it out of control? No, I have never
said that. I have tried, if you like, to make balanced comments that one cannot
say that there is not a problem. There is a problem, but I do not think it is
out of control. I think it will be controlled, and that is why we are doing
what we are doing. So, there is a problem, a response is needed, it is being
made and it will work. [36]
2.29
In respect to competition in the lending market, the Governor stated
that lenders relying on wholesale funding have had to slow down as ‘profitability
of that business model changed’, adding that what has happened is ‘that the
larger banks have basically made up for that, so the market shares have swung
around.’[37]
2.30
The Governor added that he does not see any short-term implications of
bank market share growth on RBA policies. Though in the longer term, there
emerges an issue of competitiveness of the mortgage market, and that at some
stage, stronger competition should come back to the Australian mortgage market. [38]
2.31
The role of fiscal policy as a complementary tool for helping to reduce
overall demand was examined. The Governor stated:
I would not argue against some
role for fiscal policy at all. It is not my place to give advice on it. If
people propose particular fiscal initiatives that are complementary, well and
good, that is just fine with me, provided that we remember that even fiscal measures are going to have to produce a slowing in demand—the same size slowing in demand as
what we are looking at. There are no two ways around that issue. It will
probably prove pretty difficult to have really finely calibrated fiscal measures, but I could be wrong there; I would be happy to be proved wrong. [39]
2.32
The committee sought clarification on the impact of a loose fiscal policy on inflation. The Governor explained that:
In an economy like ours, where we
have no debt and the budget is continually in surplus, it seems to me there is
an obvious structural case that can be made for lower taxes. At the same time,
in the current environment an obvious cyclical case can be made for fiscal policy to be tighter.
So you have a structural case to
lower taxes and a cyclical case not to, or even to raise taxes if you are
really serious. Where to strike the balance is not an easy judgement for any
government to make.[40]
2.33
The committee sought further clarification on what level of fiscal tightening would be required to take pressure off inflation. Mr Stevens stated:
We are talking quite big amounts
here. It will take very major changes in fiscal policy to completely obviate
the need for what we are doing. I do not think it is realistic to expect that
it can be obviated completely, but every little bit helps. I will be happy to
see any support from fiscal policy we can get, but I think we have to be realistic about how much any government will be able to do in the environment we face. When all is said and done, containing inflation is mainly the central bank’s job.[41]
Wages growth and a deregulated labour market
2.34
In relation to the role of the deregulated labour market in the
containment of inflation over the last decade, Mr Stevens stated that in
response to the recent terms-of-trade shock, initially ‘productive resources,
labour and capital flowed to the areas and industries where they were needed.
Relative wages have changed, in effect, ‘relative prices adjust to the shock we
have had, but you contain the aggregate.’[42]
2.35
Whilst the RBA is monitoring for signs of wages pressure, Mr Stevens stated that the ‘labour market has performed very well in adjusting to the nature of
the shock. He added, ‘I do not have any doubt that a long series of liberalising changes by both sides—by governments of different persuasions—over probably 15-plus
years has made a big difference to that outcome.’[43]
2.36
The Governor stated that fostering labour productivity plays a role in
how the labour market is regulated. He agreed with the committee that
‘flexibility and freedom in the labour market is good in terms of being able to
operate to contain inflation in a period of expansion.’[44]
In addition, the Governor agreed with the proposition that productivity
increases are best gained when employers and employees have a broader range of
issues to bargain about. He commented that you ‘have fairness considerations to
keep in mind here as well, as everyone knows.’[45]
2.37
Commenting on the relationship between demand growth and unemployment,
Mr Stevens stated that ‘five percent plus demand growth cannot be sustained.
That has to slow down. GDP growth will slow, and that is our forecast.
Employment growth will slow as well.’[46] However, he noted that
the ‘extent to which unemployment would rise depends on a range of other
factors, not least of which is how flexibly and quickly the labour market
responds to the slower growth in output.’[47]
2.38
The Governor added that ‘where you have a mid-cycle pause in the growth
trend, which is what we are talking about here, the unemployment rate goes up a
bit for a while and then it starts to go down again’[48],
and that he is working with a ‘framework where there is no long-run trade-off
between unemployment and inflation.’[49]
Exchange rates and external trade
2.39
The Australian dollar has traded in a large range in the proceeding
months. The RBA reported that looking through ‘recent fluctuations, the Australian dollar has appreciated in trade-weighted terms over the past year and is still well above
its post-float average.’[50] The Australian dollar traded at 91.2 US cents as at the hearing date.[51]
2.40
Commodity prices generally remain at very high levels. Over the three
months to February 2008, the RBA’s index of commodity prices changed very little,
‘as weaker base metals prices have been offset by higher prices for rural commodities and gold.’[52]
2.41
In particular gold prices have increased by more than 30 per cent over
the past year to around US$900 and are at their highest level in real terms in more than 20 years.[53]
2.42
Rural commodity prices increased by four per cent over the three months
to January, with further strength in wheat prices. Crops used in the production
of biodiesel and ethanol, such as canola and sugar, also rose in price over
recent months, partly reflecting high oil prices.[54]
2.43
The RBA reported that despite the slowing in the world economy, Australia’s terms of trade are expected to rise in the near term. This forecast is largely
driven by expected ongoing commodity demand, suggesting that terms of trade
will reach fresh highs in mid 2008, before declining as the market responds to
current high commodity prices.[55]
United States, China and the global economy
2.44
The US economy is subdued, and deleveraging continues as lenders retreat
from risk. In conjunction with this, US financial markets became more volatile.
Credit concerns have kept capital markets from functioning normally, and forecasters have been revising down for 2008.[56] In response, interest
rates have declined sharply, and a fiscal stimulus package is being delivered
as of late April.[57]
2.45
To a lesser extent, growth in the Euro area is also moderating, as is Japan’s economy. In contrast, economic conditions in the rest of Asia have proven to remain
solid, with growth in industrial production and strong exports overall.[58]
The Chinese economy exhibits strong growth, with continuing demand for natural resources. Asian banks continue to act on a capacity to extend credit, and domestic financial conditions remain expansionary. This all leads to strength in domestic demand in Asia, with inflation remaining a concern.[59]
Housing and household debt
2.46
The March 2007 Financial Stability Review referred to ‘pockets of
financial stress’, and identified Western Sydney as one such area. Since then,
there have been four increases in the cash rate. The committee asked the
Governor whether the bank is concerned about the latest cycle of tightening and
its financial impact on families struggling to pay their mortgages. In
particular, the committee sought detail on data relating to mortgage defaults,
arrears and home repossessions.
2.47
The Governor stated that the RBA is ‘certainly conscious that, when we
raise interest rates that is not sufficiently precisely targeted to not impact
others.’[60] He added that they ‘have
an aggregate instrument that has to be geared to aggregate conditions’ and that
‘arrears rates on mortgages in Australia are very low and, indeed, they have fallen a bit in the second half of 2007.’[61]
2.48
The committee raised the question of whether the RBA had done any research
in relation to mortgage stress. The Governor noted that the term ‘stress’ has
become more loosely defined. The original definition was if ‘you were in the
bottom 40 per cent of the income distribution and you spent more than 30 per
cent of your income on housing’[62], whereas now it is often
referred to just as people who ‘spend more than 30 per cent of their income on
housing.’[63] Mr. Stevens further
commented that there has ‘been a trend for the community as a whole to be more
affluent’ and with that ‘a decision to spend a higher proportion of income on
housing.’[64]
2.49
Dr Edey added that the RBA has ‘published various bits of analysis on
the question of who has the housing debt and how that correlates with different
levels of income and household characteristics’. This research shows that ‘at a
very broad level, the people who have the debt are mostly the people who you
would expect, would be able to afford to service it – that is to say, people
with high incomes.’[65]
2.50
Dr Edey also stated that household debt has been going up for two
decades. He commented that ‘it is now about 160 per cent of household income in
aggregate and still rising, and that does mean that any given interest rate
move has a bigger net effect on the amount of income available to households
after interest.’[66] However, he added that
due to the last year being a period of very rapid growth in household incomes
overall, ‘you still have a very high level of real income growth for the
household sector as a whole.’[67]
2.51
The committee also examined home loan lending practices and it
relationship to mortgage stress. The committee asked if the RBA has any view in
relation to a current range of lending practices that were dubious, in terms of
the pressures that they put on particular groups of people.
2.52
Mr Stevens responded that ‘when you have got a highly competitive
mortgage market and you have got fringe lenders coming in, you will get some
practices that should not occur.’[68] Mr Battelino stated that
in ‘the current system the onus is more now on the individuals to be careful about accessing finance.’[69] Notwithstanding these
concerns, the RBA noted that of the total number of home borrowers there are
only ‘15,000 people in the whole of Australia who are running 90 days overdue
on their housing loans.’[70]
2.53
The RBA noted that the current turmoil going on in the market is actually cutting back on some of the practices that were growing. Mr Battelino stated:
One of the practices that I think
is quite dangerous is that lenders have started using agents to market loans.
There is no doubt that the agent does not have the same incentives to maintain
high standards as the bank itself. I think it is very important for banks to
maintain a direct relationship with their clients and not to use agents. I
think it is very important that individuals who are licensed to be agents meet
very strict criteria and are highly qualified, because they can do a lot of
damage by inappropriate selling. [71]
2.54
The committee in the previous parliament conducted an inquiry into home
loan lending practices and the processes used to deal with people in financial
difficulty.[72] In particular, the
committee recommended that the Commonwealth Government regulate credit products
and credit including the regulation of mortgage brokers and non-bank lenders.
2.55
In relation to the committee’s recommendations on the regulation of
credit products, the RBA reported that at the ‘recent COAG meeting, it was
agreed that that would be taken over at the Commonwealth level, which seems
like a very sensible thing to do. Uniform national regulation of mortgage
broking would address the licensing requirements and provide a dispute
resolution mechanism.’[73]
2.56
In relation to housing affordability it was noted that since the late
1980s housing prices have decoupled from CPI, and have gone up. It was also noted that the US experienced asset inflation in house prices but is now experiencing a big
fall. In response, Mr Stevens stated:
I do not think there is any doubt
that the big problem of affordability is not that interest rates are too high.
They are above average at the moment, but that will be for a while until the
job is done and then they will be normal again. The big problem is that the
prices are very high. We have very high prices in Australia relative to income.
I think there are probably both demand and supply elements to that story, if
you take a 15- to 20-year view. The availability of finance and the big decline
in nominal interest rates when inflation came down meant that people who would
have liked to have afforded better quality housing than they could have, now
could. So demand rises and, in any short period, there is a finite stock, so
the prices rise.
On the comparison you made with
some other housing markets in other countries, it is important to remember that
a big difference between ourselves and the US is that they have got a very
large stock overhang—they built too many. [74]
2.57
In relation to the previous point, the committee examined the connection
between rising property prices and increasing rental stress. Mr Stevens stated:
What we have observed is that
asset values in the property market rose a lot in the period from about 1996 to
around about the end of 2003. They have slowed down and fluctuated a bit since
then, but that was a big rise. So the yields to the investor in rental property
fell.
They were too low (yields) and
either the price had to decline, which did happen to some extent in some areas,
or the rents had to rise, and that is what we are seeing.[75]
Climate change and its economic impact
2.58
During the hearing, the committee also focused on climate change and the
implications of an emissions-trading scheme. In particular, the RBA Governor
was asked to comment on a statement by Professor Ross Garnaut that the impact
of an ‘ETS (Emissions Trading Scheme) is large enough to have implications for
macroeconomic stability’ and ‘the direct price effects will be substantial.‘[76]
2.59
Mr Stevens noted that the RBA is not currently involved in policy
advice or formulation on this matter. However, he did comment on the possible
price impact of any changes on CPI. Mr Stevens stated:
But let us suppose, for the sake
of argument, that there is at some point a set of policies which increase the
price of energy. At a first pass, I would expect that the way we would think
about that from the point of view of the inflation target would be roughly the
same as the way we thought about the GST when it came in. In that episode,
there was a quite large one-time rise in the price level. Some prices rose,
others fell, but the net effect was positive and the CPI inflation rate went to
six per cent. But it was a one-time level shift; it was not an ongoing
inflation effect, provided there were no second rounds—which, of course, we
have to watch for.[77]
2.60
The Governor cautioned that where the situation becomes more difficult
is when there are ‘small increases over a whole run of years’ – as the economic
effects of this are harder to distil out. [78]
2.61
The committee further inquired whether this was the more likely
scenario, and whether the RBA had done any modelling around this issue, and
what action the RBA would take if people had to pay higher energy prices due to
inflationary pressures. The Governor agreed firstly that having a series of small inflation rate rises was the more likely outcome, and did not specify that the RBA had any
extensive modelling around this issue. Mr Stevens stated:
Presumably the intention of these
policies is to shift relative prices in order to affect behaviour to reduce
consumption of energy—or at least those forms of energy.
So our job is to preserve price
stability over the medium term…and watch for second-round impacts. (One of the
things the community will have to accept) is that this is a reduction in living
standards insofar as our purchasing power over energy-intensive things is
concerned.
If we were to try to collectively
push up our wages to get that back, that…would defeat the intention of the
policy. Obviously that would present a second-round problem for us if that
occurred. If the policy is well explained, then that need not occur.[79]
2.62
The committee sought information on whether the economic impacts of
climate change form part of the discussion at the RBA. The Governor responded
that it does not, but has on its board Mr Warwick McKibbin who is an expert in
the field. Furthermore, the Governor stated that climate change is essentially a volatility question, in which case the RBA would look through temporary shocks and use
underlying measures to get to ongoing trends. He noted that the ‘real economic implications of climate change are probably not in the monetary policy area.’[80]
2.63
Mr. Stevens added that ‘listing the price mechanism as part of the
solution will be critical.’ [81]
Capacity constraints
2.64
The committee has at previous hearings examined the issue of increasing
capacity constraints and the implications this has for inflation and monetary
policy. The economy has been growing for 17 years and capacity utilisation is
close to full. The Governor stated:
Indicators of capacity utilisation
reached their highest levels for two decades, and firms continue to report
considerable difficulty in expanding operations due to shortages of suitable
staff. These outcomes for demand and output growth exceeded those in either of
the two preceding years and are stronger than was expected a year ago,
particularly in the case of domestic demand.[82]
2.65
The committee discussed a statement made by the RBA on 4 March 2008 which referred to shortages of suitable labour persisting. In responding, the
Governor noted that this issue refers not only to skilled labour, but shortages
of labour generally.[83]
2.66
Mr Stevens added that the ‘economy has for a few years now been
approaching a point where the level of utilisation of labour and capital is
very high’, and that we ‘are as fully employed as we have been for 30 years’[84],
making this an issue that the RBA has to ‘watch very carefully from an
inflation point of view.’[85]
Transparency and accountability
2.67
The Governor was asked for his view on recent transparency measures
implemented by the RBA. In relation to Board minutes, he clarified that the
nature of the RBA Board is unique in that it is comprised of people who are not
full-time central bankers, and hence it is not always appropriate to disclose
votes. Lastly, he added that the RBA now endeavours to announce decisions as
soon as statements can be prepared. All in all, he views this new system as
working well.[86]
2.68
On 7 December 2007, the Fourth Statement on the Conduct of Monetary
Policy was agreed between the Treasurer and the Governor. It provides details
on the transparency and accountability framework applying to the RBA and is
reproduced at Appendix C.
2.69
In August 1996 the first statement was agreed between the then
Treasurer, the Hon Peter Costello, MP and the then Governor Mr Ian Macfarlane. In particular, this agreement provided for the Governor to be available to
report on the conduct of monetary policy twice a year to the then House of
Representatives Standing Committee on Financial Institutions and Public
Administration. This commitment has been agreed to in all subsequent Statements
on the Conduct of Monetary Policy.
2.70
Since 1997 previous committees have been conducting two public hearings
a year with the Reserve Bank of Australia. By all accounts these hearings have
proved to be very effective and are eagerly anticipated by the community and
financial sector. In particular, no previous committee has sought to change
this aspect of the accountability framework.
2.71
During the current hearing, the committee examined whether there would
be any advantages to be gained by increasing the frequency of hearings so that
there was one hearing every quarter. In response to this proposal, Mr Stevens stated:
I have been to almost all of these
hearings since they started in this form in 1997. I think I have missed two. I
think they have worked well. It seems to me, generally speaking, the frequency
is about right. I think we would probably find that for large stretches of time
there would not be enough new to say to come quarterly.[87]
2.72
The committee’s past and current scrutiny of the RBA has been and
continues to be strong and effective. The two hearings a year focusing on
monetary policy and other hearings as required provide a sound base from which
to hold the RBA to account.
Craig Thomson,
MP
Chair
15 May 2008